29.08.2013 Views

of the implementation of the Village Land Act

of the implementation of the Village Land Act

of the implementation of the Village Land Act

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

FASTIGHETSVETENSKAP<br />

EX-06-160<br />

EXAMENSARBETE<br />

The Challenging Tanzanian<br />

<strong>Land</strong> Law Reform<br />

A study <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong><br />

Per Larsson<br />

Examinator and Supervisor: Leif Eidenstedt<br />

Conceptual Coordinator: Fidelis K Mutakyamilwa<br />

Logistic Coordinator: Niklas Herrmann<br />

STOCKHOLM 2006


This study has been carried out within <strong>the</strong> framework <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Minor Field Studies<br />

Scholarship Programme, MFS, which is funded by <strong>the</strong> Swedish International<br />

Development Cooperation Agency, Sida.<br />

The MFS Scholarship Programme <strong>of</strong>fers Swedish university students an opportunity to<br />

carry out two months’ field work, usually <strong>the</strong> student’s final degree project, in a Third<br />

World country. The results <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> work are presented in an MFS report which is also <strong>the</strong><br />

student’s Master <strong>of</strong> Science Thesis. Minor Field Studies are primarily conducted within<br />

subject areas <strong>of</strong> importance from a development perspective and in a country where<br />

Swedish international cooperation is ongoing.<br />

The main purpose <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> MFS Programme is to enhance Swedish university students’<br />

knowledge and understanding <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se countries and <strong>the</strong>ir problems and opportunities.<br />

MFS should provide <strong>the</strong> student with initial experience <strong>of</strong> conditions in such a country. The<br />

overall goals are to widen <strong>the</strong> Swedish human resources cadre for engagement in<br />

international development cooperation as well as to promote scientific exchange between<br />

unversities, research institutes and similar authorities as well as NGOs in developing<br />

countries and in Sweden.<br />

The International Office at KTH, <strong>the</strong> Royal Institute <strong>of</strong> Technology, Stockholm,<br />

administers <strong>the</strong> MFS Programme for <strong>the</strong> faculties <strong>of</strong> engineering and natural sciences in<br />

Sweden.<br />

Sigrun Santesson<br />

Programme Officer<br />

MFS Programme<br />

International Office, MFS<br />

KTH, SE-100 44 Stockholm. Phone: +46 8 790 6000. Fax: +46 8 790 8192. E-mail: sigrun@kth.se<br />

www.kth.se/student/utlandsstudier/examensarbete/mfs<br />

2


Abstract<br />

In this <strong>the</strong>sis, <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> and its present <strong>implementation</strong> process is<br />

studied. Through interviews with people from <strong>the</strong> academic sphere in Dar es Salaam, as<br />

well as field-interviews with leaders in countryside villages, opinions are ga<strong>the</strong>red about<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> process so far, and <strong>the</strong> prevalent expectations on its future<br />

development.<br />

The new Tanzanian land legislation seeks to empower <strong>the</strong> customary right <strong>of</strong> occupancy<br />

titles, in order to stimulate <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> very many small-holding farms<br />

throughout <strong>the</strong> country. The customary land rights are given legal recognition, meaning<br />

increased land security for <strong>the</strong> land-holders. O<strong>the</strong>r provisions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new land acts are:<br />

registering activities aiming at enabling mortgaging <strong>of</strong> village land, increased equality<br />

between men and women, and a decentralised, and hopefully more efficient, disputeresolution<br />

process.<br />

Having passed <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian parliament in 1999, two land acts came into force in 2001:<br />

<strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> 1999 and <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> 1999. They are now processing an initial phase <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>implementation</strong>. Critics maintain that <strong>the</strong> legislation preserves a centralised state-control,<br />

which will hamper <strong>the</strong> rural development. Proponents argue that regulations are needed<br />

in order to protect <strong>the</strong> generally poor rural population against being ruthlessly exploited<br />

by financially strong potential buyers.<br />

The <strong>implementation</strong> is far-reaching and will likely demand considerable resources in <strong>the</strong><br />

course <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> coming few years. Never<strong>the</strong>less, as <strong>the</strong> former legislation collapsed in <strong>the</strong><br />

mid-90s, <strong>the</strong>re is no o<strong>the</strong>r choice for Tanzania than to continue <strong>the</strong> process. Although<br />

<strong>the</strong>re are quite a few obstacles in sight, <strong>the</strong> land acts do have <strong>the</strong> potentials to succeed to<br />

substantially improve <strong>the</strong> land situation in <strong>the</strong> rural areas <strong>of</strong> Tanzania.<br />

Keywords: Customary law, informal land rights, customary land tenure, leasehold<br />

tenure, property rights, land politics, land policy, land legislation, Tanzanian land law,<br />

<strong>implementation</strong> process, Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy, <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> 1999, <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> 1999<br />

3


Preface<br />

The study originated in a dialogue with Mr Öckerman, former Chief Technical Adviser at<br />

<strong>the</strong> Orgut headquarter in Dar es Salaam. Before my arrival to Tanzania, Mr Öckerman’s<br />

successor, Mr Herrmann, agreed to act as logistic coordinator for <strong>the</strong> field study. Mr<br />

Herrmann put me in contact with Mr Mutakyamilwa, chairman <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong><br />

Implementation Task Force at <strong>the</strong> Ministry <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong>s, who generously supported me as<br />

conceptual coordinator, involving me in <strong>the</strong> work <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> task force. All in all, <strong>the</strong> field<br />

study in Tanzania lasted three months, from November 4 th 2004 through February 2 nd<br />

2005.<br />

Acknowledgements<br />

I want to direct my deepest thankfulness to Mr Mutakyamilwa and <strong>the</strong> entire task force,<br />

who patiently answered my questions and in all ways helped me to gain knowledge about<br />

<strong>the</strong> land acts. Among <strong>the</strong>m, special thanks to Mr Kami, who generously invited me to<br />

visit his farm, <strong>of</strong> which I was deeply impressed. Many thanks also to pr<strong>of</strong>essor Ndjovu<br />

for his encouraging cheerfulness, and for arranging an interview tour at <strong>the</strong> UCLAS.<br />

Thank you, Mr Simba, Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kombe and Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kironde for taking time to give<br />

interviews.<br />

I also want to direct very special thanks to Mr Sichone in Vwawa, who not only patiently<br />

awaited my twelve hours delayed train arrival at <strong>the</strong> Mbeya train station, but in all ways<br />

showed great hospitality and true generosity, <strong>of</strong> which I was deeply moved.<br />

Thank you, Mr Herrmann for your administrational help, without which <strong>the</strong> journey<br />

would never have been accomplished. While addressing Scandinavians in Tanzania, I<br />

also send thankful greetings to Mrs Ulla-Maj Järn in Babati, who arranged a few extra<br />

interviews and village visits, as well as <strong>the</strong> relaxing fellowship during my final days in<br />

Tanzania.<br />

Finally, my gratefulness goes to my precious Lord, Jesus Christ for, <strong>of</strong> which I am<br />

convinced, having provided protection in dangerous situations, encouragement in times<br />

<strong>of</strong> anguish and joyful, precious fellowship in early morning prayer-walks.<br />

Executive summary<br />

The Tanzanian right <strong>of</strong> occupancy is <strong>the</strong> institute <strong>of</strong> land-holding in a society where <strong>the</strong><br />

whole land-tenure system is based on leasehold tenure. Introduced by <strong>the</strong> British colonial<br />

authority, <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy system was maintained basically unaltered into <strong>the</strong> land<br />

policy <strong>of</strong> independent Tanzania. The basic idea <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy system was to<br />

build upon a traditional African way <strong>of</strong> land-holding. For villagers in <strong>the</strong> countryside,<br />

only deemed rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy were available, whereas statutory rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy<br />

were meant for urban dwellers and settlers. It was only <strong>the</strong> statutory title that was given<br />

formal security <strong>of</strong> tenure. This weakness <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> customary titles became severely evident<br />

during <strong>the</strong> land reform and villagisation process <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1970s. During this process, land<br />

was used as an important tool to increase equity, productivity and efficiency in <strong>the</strong> nation.<br />

However, having <strong>the</strong> contrary effect, <strong>the</strong> land reform instead led to widespread legal<br />

confusion and countless land conflicts. Trying to bring order in <strong>the</strong> subsequent economic<br />

crisis, <strong>the</strong> World Bank tried to promote individualisation <strong>of</strong> all land in Tanzania. The<br />

western-style ownership tenure, enabling a free land market and a mortgaging system,<br />

was held up as a smooth and rapid solution. Now, experience has shown that such<br />

4


systems may well function in western societies, where it has been built up over a long<br />

time. Inevitably, though, it will bring implications when brought to developing countries.<br />

It will disturb <strong>the</strong> crucial but vulnerable social network that is built up around landholding.<br />

The new land legislation, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> and <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> <strong>of</strong> 1999, conserves <strong>the</strong><br />

leasehold tenure through <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy system, but aims to provide facilities that<br />

enable an increased land security for villagers and pastoralists, as well as possibilities for<br />

investments in small-holding farms. The <strong>implementation</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land acts are making<br />

progress, albeit slowly, and <strong>the</strong> main concern seems to be <strong>the</strong> question <strong>of</strong> financing.<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r critical issues are, whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> banks are going to respond to <strong>the</strong> mortgaging<br />

possibilities and <strong>the</strong>reby fulfil <strong>the</strong> strategic visions <strong>of</strong> investments in <strong>the</strong> agriculture;<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> conditions concerning acquisition <strong>of</strong> village land is going to prevent a free<br />

land market, that will not only enable poor people to sell <strong>of</strong>f <strong>the</strong>ir land, but ra<strong>the</strong>r force<br />

<strong>the</strong>m to sell; whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> upcoming land markets and <strong>the</strong> dependence on <strong>the</strong> local<br />

customary laws are going to subdivide <strong>the</strong> country into two, or more, geographical<br />

fractions, separating popular areas with high and stable land values from those <strong>of</strong> lower<br />

land value.<br />

The final discussion draws conclusions from a comparison between a freehold-tenure<br />

system, on <strong>the</strong> one hand, and <strong>the</strong> modernised right <strong>of</strong> occupancy system, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r.<br />

Here, <strong>the</strong> strong power <strong>of</strong> state control turns out to be a distinctive feature for <strong>the</strong> latter.<br />

Finally, different challenges for <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> process are being discussed, and two<br />

future scenarios are being sketched.<br />

5


Summary in Swedish / Svensk sammanfattning<br />

I Tanzania hanteras nyttjandet av mark inte genom äganderätt, utan genom ett system<br />

med nyttjanderätter; Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy. Dessa rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy innebär ett<br />

nyttjanderättsförhållande med staten som ger äganderättsliknande rättigheter till mark<br />

med upp till 99 års löptid. Historiskt sett har rights <strong>of</strong> occupacy sitt ursprung i den senare<br />

koloniala epoken under brittisk överhöghet, men bibehölls i det närmaste <strong>of</strong>örändrad in i<br />

den självständiga nationens marklagstiftning. En grundtanke med rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy var<br />

bland annat att erkänna och kunna hantera stammarnas och byarnas egna traditioner kring<br />

markfrågor. <strong>Land</strong>sbygdsbefolkningen gavs dock inget formellt rättsligt skydd för sina<br />

markrättigheter, vilket gjorde dem ytterst sårbara, inte bara gentemot europeiska<br />

nybyggare under den koloniala tiden, utan i än större omfattning under den omvälvande<br />

landreform som senare drog fram över landet. Reformen medförde under 70-talet<br />

villkorslösa tvångsförflyttningar och skapandet av tusentals nya byar, vilket inte minst<br />

resulterade i ändlösa markkonflikter och total förvirring i frågor om gällande<br />

markrättigheter.<br />

I syfte att ställa till rätta efter den nationella ekonomiska kollaps som följde,<br />

liberaliserades landets tidigare planekonomi och världsbanken tryckte på för att införa<br />

äganderätt till fast egendom efter västerländsk modell. De långsiktiga följderna av<br />

världsbankens biståndsmetoder hade emellertid börjat debatteras internationellt, varför<br />

Tanzania inte lät böja sig, utan övervägde att behålla sitt nyttjanderättssystem. I kritiken<br />

emot världsbankens utvecklingsprogram poängterades de negativa sociala<br />

följdverkningarna av att utifrån vilja påtvinga färdiga koncept på samhällen som saknar<br />

såväl den erforderliga infrastrukturen som finansiella genomföranderesurser.<br />

Efter tio års förarbete antogs år 1999 den nya marklagstiftningen: <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> och <strong>Village</strong><br />

<strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>. <strong>Land</strong>sbygdsbefolkningens hävdade markområden skulle nu garanteras juridiskt<br />

skydd och de lokala stammarnas traditionella marklagar skulle respekteras. Alltsedan<br />

lagstiftningen trädde i kraft, år 2001, har implementeringen fortgått, men det synliga<br />

genomförandet tog fart först i och med tillsättandet av en expertgrupp i början av 2004.<br />

Senare samma år påbörjades distribuering av registreringsmaterial inom det första av en<br />

rad planerade pilotdistrikt. Man gav där också konkret undervisning i hur lagarna skulle<br />

tillämpas. Införandet av den nya lagstiftningen har sedan dess långsamt gjort framsteg,<br />

men är beroende av att utlovade medel skjuts till. Stor osäkerhet råder ännu kring<br />

tillgången på adekvata resurser, bland annat finansiering och tillräcklig tillgång på<br />

kompetent personal. Det är också tveksamt om det kommersiella bankväsendet kommer<br />

att godta den utlovade inteckningsmöjligheten för markägare till små marklotter.<br />

Ytterligare frågetecken reser sig kring huruvida de statliga restriktionerna för köp av<br />

mark inom byarna verkligen kommer att motverka en marknadsmässig, men osund,<br />

snedfördelning av ägandet till förmån för de välbärgade.<br />

I uppsatsens avslutande diskussion dras slutsatser av den tidigare gjorda jämförelsen<br />

mellan Tanzanias moderniserade right <strong>of</strong> occupancy system och ett system med<br />

äganderätt till mark. Skillnaden visar sig bland annat bestå i det inflytande och kontroll<br />

som staten fortfarande förfogar över i Tanzania. Avslutningsvis skisseras två olika<br />

framtida scenarier med avseende på de utmaningar som implementeringsprocessen och<br />

den nya lagstiftningen står inför.<br />

6


Table <strong>of</strong> contents<br />

Abstract 3<br />

Preface 4<br />

Acknowledgements 4<br />

Executive summary 4<br />

Summary in Swedish 6<br />

Table <strong>of</strong> contents 7<br />

1. Introduction 8<br />

1.1 Background and purpose <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> study 8<br />

1.2 Objective and limitations 8<br />

1.3 Methodology 9<br />

1.4 Organisation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> paper 9<br />

1.5 Abbreviations 10<br />

2. <strong>Land</strong> politics 11<br />

2.1 The development <strong>of</strong> Tanzanian land politics 11<br />

2.2 Customary law 18<br />

2.3 The Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy System 20<br />

2.4 Tanzanian land ideology 22<br />

3. Conceptual basics 24<br />

3.1 Property rights <strong>the</strong>ory 24<br />

3.2 Comparison <strong>of</strong> rights 30<br />

3.2.1 The Freehold System 33<br />

3.2.2 The Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy System 34<br />

4. <strong>Land</strong>-political challenges 37<br />

5. The new land legislation 43<br />

5.1 Presenting <strong>the</strong> land acts 43<br />

5.1.1 <strong>Land</strong> categories 44<br />

5.1.2 <strong>Land</strong> titles according to <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> 46<br />

5.1.3 <strong>Land</strong> titles according to <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> 46<br />

5.1.4 <strong>Land</strong> management 46<br />

5.2 The process <strong>of</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> 48<br />

6. Piloting <strong>the</strong> legislation 51<br />

6.1 Initial pilot area, <strong>the</strong> Mbozi district, Mbeya region 51<br />

6.2 Analysing <strong>the</strong> future impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> legislation 52<br />

6.3 Interviews from <strong>the</strong> pilot area 56<br />

7. Final Discussion 61<br />

7.1 Right <strong>of</strong> occupancy versus freehold tenure 61<br />

7.2 Criticising <strong>the</strong> land acts 62<br />

7.3 Discussing <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> 63<br />

8. References 69<br />

7


1. Introduction<br />

1.1 Background and purpose <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> study<br />

The year 1999 marked a point <strong>of</strong> crucial importance in <strong>the</strong> making <strong>of</strong> Tanzanian<br />

legislation; <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> and <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> were passed in <strong>the</strong> parliament. The<br />

previous strong reliance on <strong>the</strong> British influenced <strong>Land</strong> Ordinance from 1923 was finally<br />

done away with.<br />

For <strong>the</strong> villagers, <strong>the</strong> new legislation promises far-reaching acknowledgement <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

customary land rights. It also grants legal protection to <strong>the</strong> land rights <strong>of</strong> different<br />

vulnerable groups. The highly interesting question is, whe<strong>the</strong>r this legislative reform will<br />

succeed in overcoming some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> burdensome land-related inequalities and conflicts<br />

that to such a large extent hinder development in <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian countryside today. If so,<br />

<strong>the</strong> land acts and its <strong>implementation</strong> process might represent a break-through in rural<br />

development for Sub-Saharan Africa. Then an example will be given for o<strong>the</strong>r on-going<br />

land-reform processes in Africa. For <strong>the</strong> moment, though, <strong>the</strong> government <strong>of</strong> Tanzania is<br />

deeply involved in what might be <strong>the</strong> most crucial phase <strong>of</strong> all, <strong>the</strong> pilot-<strong>implementation</strong><br />

phase. The outcome <strong>of</strong> this process is nei<strong>the</strong>r secure, nor easily predicted.<br />

The law was preceded by pr<strong>of</strong>ound research through a presidential commission <strong>of</strong> inquiry<br />

submitting its report in 1992. Also <strong>the</strong> following National <strong>Land</strong> Policy from 1995 gave<br />

directions for <strong>the</strong> making <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> law. The final legislation comprising <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> and<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> <strong>of</strong> 1999 came into force in May 2001.<br />

In her publication, Wily (2003) gives an excellent introduction into <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>,<br />

a guide in how to handle <strong>the</strong> legislation in <strong>the</strong> villages. She maintains an essentially<br />

positive approach towards <strong>the</strong> potential <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> legislation and its upcoming<br />

<strong>implementation</strong> process.<br />

Throughout <strong>the</strong> process <strong>of</strong> formulating <strong>the</strong> land bill, <strong>the</strong>re has been a living debate on <strong>the</strong><br />

content <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> legislation and, in <strong>the</strong> wider scope, <strong>the</strong> influence <strong>of</strong> state control over<br />

adjudicative and administrative issues. Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Issa Shivji, scholar and former chairman<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land commission, has since been one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> leading critics, and has through<br />

publications, articles and as speaker at conferences and sessions helped to keep <strong>the</strong> debate<br />

alive. Critique has also been directed from domestic CSOs such as, Haki Ardhi, TAWLA,<br />

LHRC, VOLIT and PINGO, as well as international NGOs, such as Oxfam and REPOA.<br />

1.2 Objective and limitations<br />

The objective <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> field study has been to scrutinise land rights in <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian Right<br />

<strong>of</strong> Occupancy system, study <strong>the</strong> on-going <strong>implementation</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> and<br />

conclude by making a brief prognosis on <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> process, and a probable<br />

future development <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian village land. The scope <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> study is limited to <strong>the</strong><br />

land rights in <strong>the</strong> rural areas where <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> is applicable. As <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong><br />

<strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> repeatedly refers to <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> for different provisions, <strong>the</strong> neglect in this<br />

<strong>the</strong>sis to mention both documents everywhere is a conscious decision, in order to simplify<br />

things for <strong>the</strong> reader.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> important topic <strong>of</strong> land-dispute resolution is deliberately omitted. As it<br />

has shown formidable to beforehand measure and limit <strong>the</strong> scope <strong>of</strong> this kind <strong>of</strong> topic, <strong>the</strong><br />

8


objective <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> study has undergone quite a few amendments and reassessments.<br />

Never<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> content <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> final report is a condensation <strong>of</strong> economic as well as<br />

social implications <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>, without any<br />

pretensions <strong>of</strong> being complete.<br />

1.3 Methodology<br />

The main reason to perform <strong>the</strong> study on spot in Tanzania was to get hold <strong>of</strong> information<br />

through observations, interviews and literature. In order to gain experience from <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>implementation</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>, I joined <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> Implementation<br />

Task Force, which was chaired by my conceptual coordinator, Mr Mutakyamilwa. The<br />

task force invited me to attend a week long seminar in <strong>the</strong> Bariadi district in November.<br />

I also paid visits to <strong>the</strong> University College <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong> and Architectural Studies, UCLAS, in<br />

Dar es Salaam, where valuable literature suggestions were given, as well as possibilities<br />

to make interviews concerning <strong>the</strong> new legislation and its <strong>implementation</strong>.<br />

In January 2005, an interview journey to <strong>the</strong> Mbozi district was carried out. In this pilot<br />

district, <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> had proceed <strong>the</strong> most, and was <strong>the</strong>refore an interesting area<br />

in which to make field interviews with district-level staff as well as village leaders.<br />

Large parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> report are based on written sources. Ranging from <strong>of</strong>ficial documents,<br />

such as <strong>the</strong> report <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> presidential commission, <strong>the</strong> land policy and <strong>the</strong> land acts,<br />

through academically acknowledged literature, such as James and Fimbo’s research on<br />

customary law and Tanzanian land tenure, into conference-summaries on <strong>the</strong> topic, and<br />

various published and unpublished articles.<br />

The sequence describing Tanzanian land ideology (See chapter 2.4) is mainly based on<br />

material written by <strong>the</strong> former president <strong>of</strong> Tanzania, <strong>the</strong> late Julius Nyerere. When<br />

covering <strong>the</strong> debate on land matters, <strong>the</strong> Internet has shown to be a useful source. Being<br />

an initiated actor in <strong>the</strong> debate, <strong>the</strong> Oxfam UK has provided much space on <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

homepage covering articles, written both by <strong>the</strong>ir own staff, and by external sources.<br />

Summaries from proceedings <strong>of</strong> different land-related symposia and conferences have<br />

also been available this way.<br />

1.4 Organisation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> paper<br />

The report follows a chronological order, starting with a historical review in <strong>the</strong> second<br />

chapter where special attention is given to <strong>the</strong> three important land-political components:<br />

customary law, <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy system and <strong>the</strong> land ideology <strong>of</strong> independent<br />

Tanzania.<br />

Having covered this background to <strong>the</strong> specific Tanzanian circumstances, chapter three<br />

briefly surveys <strong>the</strong> contemporary <strong>the</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> property rights in order to establish a<br />

foundation for <strong>the</strong> following discussion; comparing <strong>the</strong> freehold system with <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong><br />

occupancy system. Before entering into <strong>the</strong> present Tanzanian land legislation, a wider<br />

perspective is taken when surveying different land-political challenges in <strong>the</strong> fourth<br />

chapter. The topics chosen for this chapter are extracted from <strong>the</strong> general African landpolitical<br />

debate. Certainly, <strong>the</strong>se subjects have also been on <strong>the</strong> agenda <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian<br />

national land debate. Chapter five overviews <strong>the</strong> land legislation and describes <strong>the</strong><br />

process <strong>of</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> as it has developed until <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> conference 1 in<br />

early March 2005. Chapter six is based on <strong>the</strong> interview material and aims at inviting<br />

1 The Symposium on Implementation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1999 <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>, 1-2 nd March 2005, Courtyard Hotel, Dar es Salaam<br />

9


different opinions to be heard on <strong>the</strong> content <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new land laws, as well as on <strong>the</strong><br />

probable outcome <strong>of</strong> its intentions. In <strong>the</strong> final chapter, a concluding discussion is taking<br />

place, where forecasts <strong>of</strong> possible future scenarios are sketched.<br />

1.5 Abbreviations<br />

DFID United Kingdom Department for International Development<br />

IIED International Institute for Environment and Development<br />

MLHSD Ministry <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong>s and Human Settlements Development<br />

NGO Non Governmental Organisation<br />

CSO Civil Society Organisation<br />

JOLIT Joint Livelihoods Initiative Tanzania<br />

LHRC Legal and Human Rights Centre<br />

PINGO Pastoralists Indigenous NGOs Forum<br />

REPOA Research and Poverty Alleviation<br />

TAWLA Tanzania Women Lawyers’ Association<br />

DLO District <strong>Land</strong> Officer<br />

VEO <strong>Village</strong> Executive Officer<br />

VLO <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> Officer<br />

VC <strong>Village</strong> Chairman<br />

UCLAS University College <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong> and Architectural Studies, Dar es<br />

Salaam<br />

10


2. <strong>Land</strong> politics<br />

Introduction<br />

In order to fully understand <strong>the</strong> principles and probable impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> present land<br />

legislation, it is necessary to have knowledge in <strong>the</strong> domestic political and philosophical<br />

values, as well as in <strong>the</strong> history <strong>of</strong> land politics. This chapter gives a survey <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> landrelated<br />

political development in Tanzania, and adds topical features <strong>of</strong> customary law, <strong>the</strong><br />

right <strong>of</strong> occupancy system and Nyereres ideological vision concerning land.<br />

2.1 The development <strong>of</strong> Tanzanian land politics<br />

Early immigration waves<br />

Through several migration waves from <strong>the</strong> nor<strong>the</strong>rn and <strong>the</strong> western parts <strong>of</strong> Africa,<br />

people with different languages and cultures melted toge<strong>the</strong>r and added influence to<br />

eastern Africa. Bantu-speaking peoples immigrated during <strong>the</strong> centuries before Christ<br />

from <strong>the</strong> distant Niger Delta in West Africa. They outstripped <strong>the</strong> inhabitants by bringing<br />

advanced skills in agriculture, ironworks and steel production. In <strong>the</strong> 15 th century, a final<br />

wave <strong>of</strong> migration began when Nilotic peoples arrived from <strong>the</strong> region <strong>of</strong> sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Sudan. These mainly nomadic peoples continued <strong>the</strong>ir influx on <strong>the</strong> interior parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

region through to <strong>the</strong> 18 th century. As <strong>the</strong>ir traditions and customs deviated from <strong>the</strong><br />

resident Bantu tribes, clashes made <strong>the</strong>m live separately, nurturing <strong>the</strong>ir own culture. The<br />

pastoral Maasai tribes <strong>of</strong> today are descendants from <strong>the</strong>se Nilotic peoples.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> meantime, <strong>the</strong> much more accessible coastal regions faced a quite different<br />

development. Along <strong>the</strong> East African coast, permanent trade settlements started to<br />

establish around 1000 AD. In this way, Mediterranean influx, and later, influence from<br />

Arabia and Persia, mixed with <strong>the</strong> indigenous Bantu culture to form <strong>the</strong> evolving Swahili<br />

culture. During <strong>the</strong> following centuries, Arabic traders established outposts all along <strong>the</strong><br />

coast, with its centre on <strong>the</strong> island <strong>of</strong> Zanzibar. These settlements flourished between <strong>the</strong><br />

13 th and <strong>the</strong> 15 th centuries, with trade <strong>of</strong> ivory and gold, reaching as far as India and<br />

China. (Fitzpatrick, 2002:11f)<br />

The pre-colonial era<br />

As <strong>the</strong> first European explorer, <strong>the</strong> Portuguese Vasco da Gama reached East Africa in<br />

1498. A good two decades later, <strong>the</strong> Portuguese had subdued <strong>the</strong> entire coastline and had<br />

built forts at strategic locations. The Portuguese were in <strong>the</strong> early 18 th century displaced<br />

by Arabs from Oman, whom succeeded to penetrate <strong>the</strong> interior regions, establishing<br />

powerful trade routes. The commerce, including slave trade, grew to such importance that<br />

in <strong>the</strong> 1840s, <strong>the</strong> powerful sultan <strong>of</strong> Oman moved his capital to Zanzibar. Simultaneously,<br />

different European interests, primarily missionaries and explorers, began to penetrate <strong>the</strong><br />

Tanzanian mainland. In 1868 Catholic priests established <strong>the</strong> first mainland mission<br />

station at Bagamoyo, as a refuge for ransomed slaves. The European explorers made<br />

several expeditions to <strong>the</strong> inland by following <strong>the</strong> Arabic caravan routes, discovering and<br />

mapping portions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> African continent. (Fitzpatrick, 2002:12f) One <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m was <strong>the</strong><br />

German adventurer and explorer Dr Karl Peters. Through dubious agreements with local<br />

11


chiefs in 1884, he was granted large tracts <strong>of</strong> land, to be held for all times. Peters<br />

established The German East Africa Company, which rapidly acquired imperial<br />

protection. This marked <strong>the</strong> beginning <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> German influence in East Africa. (James,<br />

1971:13)<br />

Colonisation<br />

Until <strong>the</strong> 1870s, <strong>the</strong> concern for Africa by <strong>the</strong> European powers had remained marginal.<br />

Not more than ten per cent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> continent had been colonised. Beginning in <strong>the</strong> late<br />

1870s, Belgium, France, and increasingly Germany and Britain, showed competing<br />

interest in <strong>the</strong> remaining parts <strong>of</strong> Africa. During <strong>the</strong> Berlin Conferences <strong>of</strong> 1884-85 some<br />

ground rules for <strong>the</strong> South-Saharan development <strong>of</strong> Africa were laid out, determining<br />

how to go about territorial claims et cetera. Governed by a mix <strong>of</strong> political and<br />

commercial interests, armed expeditions rushed to <strong>the</strong> interior <strong>of</strong> Africa, ignoring existing<br />

natural and cultural frontiers in <strong>the</strong>ir claiming <strong>of</strong> land. (Perry, 1997:459ff)<br />

This activity, known as <strong>the</strong> scramble for Africa, resulted in that most <strong>of</strong> what now counts<br />

as mainland Tanzania toge<strong>the</strong>r with Rwanda and Burundi came under <strong>the</strong> control <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

German Empire, as German East Africa. Britain, as <strong>the</strong> competitor in this part <strong>of</strong> Africa,<br />

acquired what later became Kenya and Uganda, and also established a protectorate over<br />

<strong>the</strong> Zanzibar archipelago. (Commission report, 1994:8ff)<br />

<strong>Land</strong> policy in German East Africa<br />

Imperial Germany showed a great interest in land resources, not only by ruling <strong>the</strong><br />

territory, but also by owning it. The state acted as landlord by having <strong>the</strong> radical titles<br />

ultimately vested in <strong>the</strong> state. A German imperial decree from 1895, proclaimed all land<br />

to be un-owned Crown land, vested in <strong>the</strong> German Empire. The only exceptions were<br />

land where pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> ownership could be shown, <strong>Land</strong> alienation was made in accordance<br />

with German law, following <strong>the</strong> German tradition <strong>of</strong> land tenure. As indigenous African<br />

land tenure systems were based on informal documentation and oral tradition, <strong>the</strong> land <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> African inhabitants was regularly treated as unowned land and, hence, left with only<br />

permissive rights <strong>of</strong> occupation. Settlers in general, had acquired <strong>of</strong>ficially recognised<br />

documents <strong>of</strong> freehold, and were <strong>the</strong>refore treated as formal landowners. Although <strong>the</strong><br />

German land policy required <strong>the</strong> settlers to respect <strong>the</strong> African habitations, allowing <strong>the</strong>m<br />

at least four times <strong>the</strong> existing cultivated area for future expansion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village, <strong>the</strong><br />

German administration wanted to promote productivity, and was in reality generous in<br />

alienating land to settlers. <strong>Land</strong> was also alienated to foreigners in <strong>the</strong> townships.<br />

Notwithstanding <strong>the</strong> favouring <strong>of</strong> foreign settlers, grants <strong>of</strong> freeholds were not given<br />

unconditionally. The main practice was to alienate land for a term <strong>of</strong> years, with an<br />

option to convert to freehold, only after having successfully met <strong>the</strong> stated development<br />

conditions. This system <strong>of</strong> land tenure reflected both a desire to prevent speculation, as it<br />

encouraged land usage. (James, 1971:13f), (Commission report, 1994:9), (Okoth-<br />

Ogendo, 1999)<br />

Following imperialistic ideas, <strong>the</strong> colonial production structure was streamlined to meet<br />

<strong>the</strong> demands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> European industry. This meant a focus on export <strong>of</strong> minerals and<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r raw materials. A number <strong>of</strong> export crops were introduced and large-scale<br />

plantations established, producing c<strong>of</strong>fee, tea, sisal and cotton. (Lunden, 1990:3),<br />

(Commission report, 1994:8)<br />

12


The British land policy<br />

Through <strong>the</strong> Versailles Treaty in 1919, Germany had to renounce all its rights in German<br />

East Africa. Freeholds held by German settlers, were considered enemy property, and<br />

were, as such, sold to settlers <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r nationalities, mainly British. (Commission report,<br />

1994:9), (James, 1971:15) From 1922 <strong>the</strong> area, renamed Tanganyika, became<br />

administered by Britain; first as a mandate from <strong>the</strong> League <strong>of</strong> Nations and, after Second<br />

World War, as a United Nations Trust Territory. (Fitzpatrick, 2002:12) Rwanda and<br />

Burundi came under <strong>the</strong> control <strong>of</strong> Belgium.<br />

Under <strong>the</strong> British, all rights in relation to any public land were vested in, and became<br />

exercisable by <strong>the</strong> governor in trust for <strong>the</strong> monarch. The first land tenure statute<br />

applying to Tanganyika was <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> Ordinance, enacted in 1923. This land act declared<br />

all land in <strong>the</strong> territory, except freeholds acquired before <strong>the</strong> passage <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> law, as being<br />

public land. All rights <strong>of</strong> this public land were placed under <strong>the</strong> governor <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> territory,<br />

to be held as rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy for certain duration. (See chapter 2.3) Freehold titles<br />

and leases, once granted by <strong>the</strong> German administration, were inherited by <strong>the</strong> British and<br />

continued to exist. During <strong>the</strong> 42 years <strong>of</strong> British administration, not many new freeholds<br />

were granted. One reason for this was <strong>the</strong> policy <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> trusteeship agreement, which<br />

Britain had signed with <strong>the</strong> League <strong>of</strong> Nations when accepting <strong>the</strong> mandate. It called for<br />

<strong>the</strong> administering authority to respect <strong>the</strong> rights, and safeguard <strong>the</strong> interests <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

indigenous population. Native laws and customs, including <strong>the</strong>ir rights to land, should be<br />

acknowledged. (James, 1971:17) James asserts that “Although…<strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> Ordinance<br />

accepted <strong>the</strong> principle <strong>of</strong> protecting native rights in land, it failed to establish a<br />

procedure to safeguard that principle”. (James, 1971:19) Despite <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong>se<br />

rights were being expressed in preambles, documents and statements <strong>of</strong> different kinds,<br />

<strong>the</strong>y were by no means incorporated into <strong>the</strong> written legislation. (Commission report,<br />

1994:11ff) In addition, extensive power was given to <strong>the</strong> governor to decide upon land<br />

use and alienation in public land. It is assumable that <strong>the</strong> system was purposely made<br />

flexible in order to adjust to <strong>the</strong> shifting administrative policies adopted by <strong>the</strong><br />

government from time to time. (Commission report, 1994:13)<br />

Independence<br />

Already in 1929, a political organisation called African Association (AA) was formed in<br />

Dar es Salaam. Being a forum for <strong>the</strong> revived nationalistic consciousness, <strong>the</strong> party<br />

responded to <strong>the</strong> demands for political action that was growing throughout <strong>the</strong> country.<br />

When, in 1958, <strong>the</strong> British government raised <strong>the</strong> question <strong>of</strong> introducing a proper<br />

freehold system in Tanganyika, <strong>the</strong> young leader <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> nationalistic party, Julius<br />

Nyerere, opposed <strong>the</strong>ir arguments in an article entitled Mali ya Taifa (National Property).<br />

In this article, he outlines an ideological opinion on national property that is going to<br />

strongly influence <strong>the</strong> future land politics <strong>of</strong> independent Tanzania. (See also chapter 2.4)<br />

African Association was renamed TAA, that soon became TANU, Tanganyika Africa<br />

National Union, in 1959. Under <strong>the</strong> leadership <strong>of</strong> Julius Nyerere, TANU was quickly<br />

transformed into an efficient political organisation with national independence as its<br />

political top priority. The same year, 1959, Britain agreed on <strong>the</strong> establishment <strong>of</strong> internal<br />

self-government in Tanganyika. On <strong>the</strong> 9 th <strong>of</strong> December 1961, Tanganyika became an<br />

independent nation, and <strong>the</strong> following year it was established as a republic with Nyerere<br />

as its first president. On <strong>the</strong> 26 th <strong>of</strong> April 1964, Tanganyika formed a union with <strong>the</strong><br />

13


newly independent island <strong>of</strong> Zanzibar, creating The United Republic <strong>of</strong> Tanzania.<br />

(Fitzpatrick, 2002:14)<br />

Socialist land tenure policy in Africa<br />

Since independence, socialism was embraced as <strong>the</strong> dominating political ideology <strong>of</strong><br />

Tanzania. The speeches and writings <strong>of</strong> President Nyerere had a tremendous impact on<br />

<strong>the</strong> political direction in which <strong>the</strong> new born nation took <strong>of</strong>f. In <strong>the</strong> making <strong>of</strong> an African<br />

Socialism, as <strong>the</strong> ideological path was called, land tenure was a matter <strong>of</strong> central interest.<br />

Already in <strong>the</strong> first five-year plan, 1964-69, land tenure reforms were in <strong>the</strong> making. The<br />

ineffective, traditional way <strong>of</strong> farming was issued, and <strong>the</strong> peasants were at first<br />

encouraged to voluntarily form collective farming villages. In <strong>the</strong> important doctrine, <strong>the</strong><br />

Arusha Declaration <strong>of</strong> 1967, <strong>the</strong> ideological fundaments for <strong>the</strong> fur<strong>the</strong>r development <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> country, were laid down. This doctrine committed Tanzania to a policy called<br />

Socialism and Self Reliance (Ujamaa na kujitegemea). Initially, <strong>the</strong> ideology was<br />

leavened by an idealistic vision <strong>of</strong> collective achievements based on unselfish ambitions.<br />

Nyerere stressed an individualistic kind <strong>of</strong> socialism, based on traditional African values.<br />

The cornerstone was <strong>the</strong> vision <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Ujamaa village, zealously encouraging communal<br />

ownership and common achievements. (See boxed text,“The Ujamaa <strong>Village</strong>”) Basic<br />

goods and tools were to be commonly held and shared among <strong>the</strong> village members, while<br />

each individual was obligated to commonly work on <strong>the</strong> land.<br />

A desire to rid oneself from <strong>the</strong> colonial yoke and build something new, led Tanzania to<br />

establish contacts with o<strong>the</strong>r socialist states in Africa, as well as with <strong>the</strong> Soviet Union<br />

and China. Through <strong>the</strong> initiating <strong>of</strong> Tanzania’s second five-year plan, 1969-74, and <strong>the</strong><br />

following Mwongozo manifest <strong>the</strong> nationalising <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> country’s economy took <strong>of</strong>f.<br />

Especially in <strong>the</strong> area <strong>of</strong> land tenure, <strong>the</strong>se policies eventually took on <strong>the</strong> shape <strong>of</strong> direct<br />

state control. (Fitzpatrick, 2002:14f), (Hydén, 1972:42ff), (Lunden, 1990:4f)<br />

The Ujamaa <strong>Village</strong><br />

The main idea with <strong>the</strong> Ujamaa village was to through cooperation achieve higher output than through<br />

individual farming. The Ujamaa village was also meant to be a proactive component in <strong>the</strong> rural<br />

development, a receiver <strong>of</strong> governmental funds in order to distribute welfare through educational and<br />

medical investments to <strong>the</strong> rural population. Being <strong>of</strong> central importance for <strong>the</strong> emerging socialist<br />

state, <strong>the</strong> Ujamaa village also held <strong>the</strong> seat <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> local political <strong>of</strong>ficer. Later on, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Act</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

1975 stated directives for <strong>the</strong> Ujamaa village. The <strong>Act</strong> prescribed each family <strong>the</strong> right to some land<br />

within <strong>the</strong> village for <strong>the</strong>ir household farm. Initially, an area <strong>of</strong> at least an acre was prescribed for <strong>the</strong><br />

family to settle down, build a house and have <strong>the</strong> possibility to grow crops <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir own choice. Next to<br />

<strong>the</strong> household farm, <strong>the</strong> Ujamaa shamba (<strong>the</strong> village farm) was prioritised. These components formed<br />

<strong>the</strong> nucleus <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Ujamaa village. In <strong>the</strong> Ujamaa shamba, all able-bodied people residing in <strong>the</strong> village<br />

were required to work communally for at least two days a week. The village government planned which<br />

crops to grow and what to do with <strong>the</strong> surplus. Beside <strong>the</strong> household farm, a single family was not<br />

allowed to gain more land for <strong>the</strong>mselves. Instead <strong>the</strong> block farm was supposed to fill that need. In<br />

those fields each household was given an allotment. The choice <strong>of</strong> crop and method <strong>of</strong> cultivation were<br />

again decided communally by <strong>the</strong> village government, although <strong>the</strong> tilling was to be done by each<br />

individual household, to whom <strong>the</strong> harvest also accrued. (Friis-Hansen, 1986)<br />

14


The villagisation reforms<br />

In order to lift <strong>the</strong> agricultural sector, already <strong>the</strong> Germans, followed by <strong>the</strong> British, had<br />

tried in different ways to ga<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> scattered peasant settlements into proper villages <strong>of</strong> a<br />

certain size. Such achievements were generally met by a compact resistance.<br />

Through <strong>the</strong> Arusha Declaration, <strong>the</strong> vision for <strong>the</strong> rural development was laid out, and<br />

called for a rapid <strong>implementation</strong>. To meet <strong>the</strong> aims <strong>of</strong> national self-reliance, <strong>the</strong><br />

agricultural production had to improve considerably. This was done in three phases<br />

during 1967-76, succeeding each o<strong>the</strong>r with increasing compulsory characteristics.<br />

The first phase was characterised by voluntariness. Financial support and o<strong>the</strong>r benefits<br />

were being canalised through development funds to attract people to form Ujamaa<br />

villages. In 1969 a second phase was initiated through <strong>the</strong> regional villagisation<br />

campaigns. In order to take advantage <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> need for reconstruction after <strong>the</strong> devastating<br />

flooding <strong>of</strong> river deltas (Mtwara and Lindi regions in 1969), and droughts (Dodoma<br />

district in 1970), major resettlements were implemented. During <strong>the</strong> period <strong>of</strong> 1969-73<br />

<strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> people living in villages on <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian countryside increased from half<br />

a million to two million. Still, this constituted only 20 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rural population, and<br />

<strong>the</strong> political impatience grew.<br />

The National Executive Committee initiated <strong>the</strong> third phase in 1973, when deciding that<br />

<strong>the</strong> whole rural population <strong>of</strong> Tanzania was to live in villages before 1976. The<br />

requirements <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> peasants was now, and foremost, to move into villages, and only<br />

secondly, to cultivate <strong>the</strong> land communally. Within two years after <strong>the</strong> initiating <strong>of</strong><br />

Operation Vijiji, almost all peasants had been moved to villages, with <strong>the</strong> result that some<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> existing villages more than doubled its population during this short period <strong>of</strong> time.<br />

The great <strong>implementation</strong> stress made it impossible to follow <strong>the</strong> procedures <strong>of</strong><br />

carefulness that characterised <strong>the</strong> earlier village planning. Instead, <strong>the</strong> new village<br />

population was, in an unplanned manner, allotted land hastily expropriated from peasants<br />

that have been living in <strong>the</strong> village for generations. (Friis-Hansen, 1986, p.20ff) The<br />

effect that <strong>the</strong>se forced resettlements had on social structures, are hard to fathom, save <strong>the</strong><br />

impact on <strong>the</strong> land tenure and <strong>the</strong> environment. Considering that <strong>the</strong> operation coincided<br />

with <strong>the</strong> draught <strong>of</strong> 1973-74, <strong>the</strong> rural situation became very vulnerable, resulting in<br />

starvation and widespread suffering. (Maliyamkono & Bagachwa, 1990:6)<br />

<strong>Land</strong> tenure after independence<br />

There is no doubt that <strong>the</strong> post-independence government took over <strong>the</strong> conceptual<br />

framework <strong>of</strong> land tenure from <strong>the</strong> colonial system. Only slightly amended, <strong>the</strong> British<br />

<strong>Land</strong> Ordinance was still forming <strong>the</strong> foundation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian land legislation. (See<br />

Figure 2.2) The major modification concerned <strong>the</strong> consolidation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> concept <strong>of</strong> land<br />

tenure. All sorts <strong>of</strong> freeholds and enfranchisements were converted to leaseholds for<br />

definite periods, under <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy regime. Thereby, literally all land was<br />

public land, now being vested in <strong>the</strong> president as a trustee for <strong>the</strong> people, instead <strong>of</strong> in <strong>the</strong><br />

British governor on behalf <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> monarch. (Commission report, 1994:19f) The<br />

commission report underlines <strong>the</strong> fact that this conversion was not a matter <strong>of</strong><br />

nationalisation, but <strong>of</strong> reducing <strong>the</strong> time frame <strong>of</strong> interests in land from a perpetual to a<br />

definite period <strong>of</strong> time, <strong>the</strong> maximum being 99 years. (Commission report, 1994:17f) No<br />

land was taken from previous freehold owners, even though some settlers decided to<br />

leave <strong>the</strong> country, abandoning <strong>the</strong>ir land. Elements <strong>of</strong> nationalisation instead appeared<br />

15


when, through <strong>the</strong> issuing <strong>of</strong> specific laws, c<strong>of</strong>fee and sisal estates were taken over and<br />

vested in parastatal organisations. 2 (Zainab, 2004:10), (Commission report, 1994:20)<br />

Precolonial period<br />

German period<br />

(1884-1919)<br />

British period<br />

(1922-1961)<br />

Tanzanian<br />

independence<br />

(1961-1999)<br />

Imperial Crown <strong>Land</strong> vested in <strong>the</strong> German Empire<br />

on behalf <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> German emperor<br />

Unoccupied land<br />

Unoccupied land<br />

Public <strong>Land</strong> vested in <strong>the</strong> governor<br />

on behalf <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> British monarch<br />

Unoccupied land Freehold<br />

Public <strong>Land</strong> vested in <strong>the</strong> president<br />

on behalf <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> people<br />

Unoccupied land<br />

Freehold<br />

Occupied land held under a variety <strong>of</strong><br />

customary land-tenure practises<br />

(including semi-feudal forms)<br />

Occupied land<br />

Occupied land,<br />

deemed Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy (from 1928)<br />

Occupied land,<br />

granted Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy (from 1928)<br />

Occupied land,<br />

deemed Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy<br />

Occupied land,<br />

granted Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy<br />

Figure 2.2<br />

The figure aims to give an orientation in how <strong>the</strong> different land categories relate to each o<strong>the</strong>r, how <strong>the</strong><br />

tenure structure is being inherited between <strong>the</strong> regimes, and to give a hint <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> comparative magnitude <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> land-tenure institutes.<br />

Consequences <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> villagisation<br />

The Arusha Declaration, giving rise to <strong>the</strong> villagisation process, <strong>the</strong> establishment <strong>of</strong><br />

parastatal large-scale agricultural companies et cetera, brought about pr<strong>of</strong>ound<br />

consequences for <strong>the</strong> land tenure system in <strong>the</strong> country. The land-reform development<br />

that started with dialogues between state <strong>of</strong>ficials and small-holders concerning<br />

compensation, and location <strong>of</strong> new villages for <strong>the</strong> alienation <strong>of</strong> customary land, ended in<br />

forced villagisation campaigns backed up by coercive laws. A set <strong>of</strong> legislations in <strong>the</strong><br />

1970s implied <strong>the</strong> possibility to extinguish customary rights within specified areas<br />

2 Among <strong>the</strong>se laws were <strong>the</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee Estate (Acquisition and Regrant) <strong>Act</strong> 1973, <strong>the</strong> Sisal Estates (Acquisition and Regrant) <strong>Act</strong> 1974,<br />

and <strong>the</strong> Rural Farmland (Acquisition and Regrant) <strong>Act</strong> 1966. The <strong>of</strong>ficial reason was to overcome mismanagement <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> targeted<br />

farms.<br />

16


without due process <strong>of</strong> law. (Havnevik & Hårsmar, 1999:88) After such legal turmoil,<br />

<strong>the</strong>re is no wonder that complications eventually appeared. The land commission asserts<br />

that, during <strong>the</strong> most furious period, 1973-1976, <strong>the</strong> villagisation itself, “was not<br />

preceded by any enabling legislation, nor was any existing piece <strong>of</strong> legislation cited, or<br />

applied to enable such an exercise”. It also reports that <strong>the</strong> existing customary land<br />

tenure systems had been totally disregarded, and that no thought seemed to have been<br />

given to <strong>the</strong> future land tenure in <strong>the</strong> newly established villages. (Commission report,<br />

1994:43)<br />

National crisis and financial liberalisation<br />

During <strong>the</strong> first ten years as an independent state, Tanzania improved in many areas. Its<br />

independent socialistic aspirations caused international attention, and Tanzania soon<br />

became exemplary among African countries in education, health care and rural<br />

development. However, a domestic political stagnation, reinforced by <strong>the</strong> unfavourable<br />

international economic development, <strong>the</strong> break-up <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> East African Community,<br />

repeated draughts and a costly military intervention in Uganda, gradually put <strong>the</strong> country<br />

to <strong>the</strong> brink <strong>of</strong> catastrophe. In <strong>the</strong> mid-80s, Nyerere resigned from <strong>the</strong> presidency, and<br />

was succeeded by <strong>the</strong> more market-oriented, Ali Hassan Mwinyi. The financial situation,<br />

as well as pressure on democratic reforms from donors, forced Tanzania to take part in an<br />

economic-recovery programme. The International Monetary Fund (IMF) imposed<br />

extensive liberalisation in <strong>the</strong> financial system <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> nation. Through a supplement to <strong>the</strong><br />

constitution in 1992, <strong>the</strong> one-party system, created in 1977, was abolished. The first<br />

multi-party election was held in 1995. (Heldgaard, 2005), (UI, 2005)<br />

The devolution <strong>of</strong> political monopoly<br />

Through a merger between TANU and <strong>the</strong> Zanzibar socialists, ASP, in 1977, <strong>the</strong> Revolutionary<br />

Party, CCM (Chama Cha Mapinduzi), was created. The same year, a new constitution was enacted,<br />

declaring Tanzania as a one-party state. Having representatives in all village leaderships, as well<br />

as at semi-local, district and regional levels, CCM autocratically gained control <strong>of</strong> virtually all<br />

political activity in <strong>the</strong> land. While lacking opposition, <strong>the</strong> solitary party gradually stiffened,<br />

developing an inefficient bureaucracy with corrupt elements. In order to prevent criticism and what<br />

could possibly threaten <strong>the</strong>ir power, independent trade unions, cooperative movements and <strong>the</strong> free<br />

press was eventually abolished. (Heldgaard, 2005)<br />

<strong>Land</strong> tenure during liberalisation<br />

Doubtlessly, <strong>the</strong> tangled rural land tenure situation would cause big future problems if not<br />

quickly being dealt with. As a response, <strong>the</strong> government in 1987 urgently initiated <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Village</strong> Titling Programme. The intention was to survey and demarcate village borders in<br />

order to secure a single right <strong>of</strong> occupancy for <strong>the</strong> whole village. Thereafter, <strong>the</strong> village<br />

council were to grant sub-titles, i.e. leases, to <strong>the</strong> villagers. The land commission argues<br />

that this handling aimed at abolishing <strong>the</strong> traditional land institution, thus revolutionizing<br />

<strong>the</strong> customary land tenure system. (Commission report, 1994:46f) However, <strong>the</strong> action<br />

turned out to be not only slow and expensive, but also assailed with legal and procedural<br />

problems. As existing deemed rights on village land was not properly cleared, double<br />

allocation aroused, causing considerable confusion. (Havnevik & Hårsmar, 1999:89)<br />

17


Centrally approved alienations<br />

The land commission also seriously criticised a number <strong>of</strong> controversial alienations <strong>of</strong><br />

village land that, until as late as in <strong>the</strong> 1990s, were undertaken to promote investments.<br />

Almost without exceptions, <strong>the</strong>se alienations intruded on customary land and village<br />

activities, whe<strong>the</strong>r it affected small-holding farming or pastoral cattle keeping. These<br />

situations accentuated <strong>the</strong> insecurity <strong>of</strong> tenure for <strong>the</strong> customary land rights. (Havnevik &<br />

Hårsmar, 1999:90ff), (Commission report, 1994:30)<br />

Amplified land confusion<br />

Summarising <strong>the</strong>ir investigation, <strong>the</strong> land commission explicitly states that <strong>the</strong><br />

villagisation period left not much but legal confusion in land matters. (Commission<br />

report, 1994:44ff) The political liberalisation led to that <strong>the</strong> control power <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> CCM<br />

was gradually broken down. Now, complaints over <strong>the</strong> abuses and injustices performed<br />

during <strong>the</strong> villagisation period, started to be heard from all around <strong>the</strong> country. <strong>Land</strong><br />

owners <strong>of</strong> alienated farms and estates, reclaimed <strong>the</strong>ir previous rights to land, held under<br />

customary tenure. (Havnevik & Hårsmar, 1999:93) A widespread questioning <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

legacy <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> villagisation reforms created confusion about which legislation should<br />

govern land tenure in <strong>the</strong> villages. The courts inclined to uphold <strong>the</strong> pre-villagisation<br />

customary land titles, when colliding with post-villagisation allocations. (Commission<br />

report, 1994:45) This legal confusion and policy vacuum on land matters, led to <strong>the</strong><br />

appointment <strong>of</strong> a land commission 3 in early 1991. (Commission report, 1994:xii ff),<br />

(Havnevik & Hårsmar, 1999:93)<br />

2.2 Customary law<br />

Customary law in Africa is <strong>the</strong> non-formal complex <strong>of</strong> codes <strong>of</strong> behaviour and social<br />

control that have guided rural life in tribes and societies from generation to generation.<br />

These “laws“ vary among societies and also show local differences between villages<br />

within <strong>the</strong> same tribe.<br />

It is made up <strong>of</strong> fragments <strong>of</strong> rules, customs and taboos embedded in <strong>the</strong> tradition and<br />

comprises practical knowledge about methods <strong>of</strong> land management, procedures for<br />

dispute settlement, rules for social privileges and obligations within <strong>the</strong> society, as well<br />

as rules for leadership succession et cetera. (Ndjovu, 2003:75) Significant for customary<br />

laws is <strong>the</strong> oral tradition, whereas written documentation has not yet been fully accepted.<br />

Customary laws may seem conservative in preserving old manners and ethics, but <strong>the</strong>y<br />

are also dynamic through <strong>the</strong>ir ability to transform over <strong>the</strong> years. (James, 1971:61f)<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial land legislation in Tanzania has formally recognised customary<br />

laws since <strong>the</strong> 1928 amendment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> Ordinance, (See chapter 2.3) directions on<br />

how to deal with <strong>the</strong>se customary laws have never become incorporated in any written<br />

legislation, and have <strong>the</strong>refore <strong>of</strong>ten been neglected by <strong>the</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficials. (James, 1971:96f)<br />

3 The Presidential Commission <strong>of</strong> Inquiry into <strong>Land</strong> Matters, appointed in January 1991, were given as terms <strong>of</strong> reference: i) to hear<br />

complaints from <strong>the</strong> general public concerning land, ii) to identify <strong>the</strong> basic causes <strong>of</strong> land disputes and recommend means for settling<br />

land disputes, iii) to review current matters <strong>of</strong> policy and recommend changes concerning allocation <strong>of</strong> land, land tenure, land use and<br />

land development, iv) to analyse <strong>the</strong> structures <strong>of</strong> institutions involved in land matters, intending to identify problems <strong>of</strong> overlapping<br />

<strong>of</strong> powers and to make recommendations.<br />

18


Customary view on land value and security <strong>of</strong> tenure<br />

Except for a few areas in Tanzania, land has always been abundant. Every young family<br />

was allotted as much land for cultivation as <strong>the</strong>y could clear and manage in <strong>the</strong> vicinity <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> village. (van den Brink, 2003:6) The prevailing practice was ei<strong>the</strong>r shifting<br />

cultivation, where old fields after some years <strong>of</strong> cultivation were left fallow in order to<br />

recover, or transhumance, requiring a more mobile lifestyle. This way <strong>of</strong> farming brought<br />

about a flexible attitude towards <strong>the</strong> holding <strong>of</strong> land and formed <strong>the</strong> base for <strong>the</strong><br />

traditional land-rights system. Instead <strong>of</strong> emphasizing <strong>the</strong> perpetual ownership <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> plot<br />

itself, it was <strong>the</strong> temporary occupation, <strong>the</strong> efforts laid down in <strong>the</strong> farming, which<br />

created security <strong>of</strong> tenure. (Ndjovu, 2003:75) The abundance <strong>of</strong> land, toge<strong>the</strong>r with <strong>the</strong><br />

traditional belief that land was given by God for free to all men, caused <strong>the</strong> view that land<br />

had no economic value. Instead it was <strong>the</strong> productive efforts made upon <strong>the</strong> land that was<br />

important (James, 1971:62), (Ndjovu, 2003:74) Out <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se traditional beliefs <strong>the</strong> widely<br />

used concept <strong>of</strong> unexhausted improvements has come. The concept includes<br />

improvements <strong>of</strong> many kinds, which invariably increase <strong>the</strong> productive capacity, <strong>the</strong><br />

utility or amenity <strong>of</strong> standing crops or growing produce. 4 (Ndjovu, 2003:74)<br />

Traditionally, land security is related to <strong>the</strong> idea that land value is created through labour.<br />

Security <strong>of</strong> tenure comes namely with continuity <strong>of</strong> cultivation. Abandoned fields would<br />

after some years be returned to <strong>the</strong> village, in order to be allotted anew to someone who<br />

could make better use <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m. On top <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> individually used land, being a part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

village also included equal and non-exclusive rights in <strong>the</strong> village commons. For every<br />

village, <strong>the</strong>re are locally adapted rules and customs, many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m inherited from<br />

previous generations, on how to deal with <strong>the</strong> common areas.<br />

Customary laws normally recognise exchange <strong>of</strong> land between land-holders within <strong>the</strong><br />

same community. When involving outsiders, <strong>the</strong> exchange is sometimes surrounded by<br />

restrictions, ranging from outright prohibition <strong>of</strong> sale to outsiders, to requiring <strong>the</strong><br />

fulfilment <strong>of</strong> certain conditions, for example to join <strong>the</strong> community. (James, 1971:64ff)<br />

Exceptions within customary land tenure<br />

In areas where perennial cash crops are cultivated, a tendency towards recognition <strong>of</strong><br />

individual and lineage proprietary land rights, tend to occur. This development disrupts<br />

<strong>the</strong> traditional pattern <strong>of</strong> land use and disturbs <strong>the</strong> community’s power to allocate land.<br />

(James, 1971:62f) The same trend is also unfolded in areas where land has become<br />

scarce. Under such circumstances, land acquires an intrinsic value, and what James calls,<br />

“a development <strong>of</strong> a private sector in customary law“ is at hand. (James, 1971:63)<br />

There are tangible differences in how different customary laws have been influencing <strong>the</strong><br />

village life among <strong>the</strong> rural regions. James and Fimbo recall <strong>the</strong> historical development<br />

where certain tribes have exercised feudal-like influence on inferior tribes, in a<br />

landlord/tenant-like relationship. (James & Fimbo, 1972) (Commission report, 1994:17f)<br />

These tenure forms may have been even more incompatible than <strong>the</strong> freehold tenure with<br />

<strong>the</strong> ideology <strong>of</strong> independent Tanzania. Never<strong>the</strong>less, it lasted until 1968 5 before <strong>the</strong>se<br />

types <strong>of</strong> feudalism were finally abolished. (Commission report, 1994:18) The freehold<br />

tenure was abolished already in 1963 6 when first being turned into government<br />

4 Ndjovu mentions following assets as example <strong>of</strong> unexhausted improvements, (from First Schedule <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> Regulations 1948):<br />

farm buildings, fencing, water burrows, trees or live hedges, walls, wells, reclamation <strong>of</strong> swamp land, road making, bridges, clearing<br />

land for agricultural purposes; water boring, water races, sheep or cattle dips, embankments or protective works <strong>of</strong> any kind, longlived<br />

crops, water tanks, irrigation works, fixed machinery, reservoirs, dams <strong>of</strong> permanent nature etc.<br />

19


leaseholds with a definite period, <strong>the</strong> maximum being 99 years, and later into granted<br />

rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy.<br />

Customary leadership<br />

According to tradition, <strong>the</strong> rural leadership were usually chiefs or elders exercising <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

leadership functions on behalf <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> tribe. Customary land was under <strong>the</strong> direct control<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> chiefs who were guardians <strong>of</strong> customary law. (Interview, Mutakyamilwa) During<br />

colonial days, as well as after independence, a few structure reforms concerning <strong>the</strong><br />

native authority were launched. Some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se laws acknowledged <strong>the</strong> traditional<br />

authorities 7 , whereas o<strong>the</strong>rs intended to abolish <strong>the</strong> chieftaincy 8 . (James, 1971:65f)<br />

2.3 The Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy System<br />

The legal institution <strong>of</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy was imported from <strong>the</strong> British colony <strong>of</strong><br />

Nor<strong>the</strong>rn Nigeria, where it was developed, and given statutory recognition in 1910.<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy is not a purely customary law conception, it has a<br />

precursor in <strong>the</strong> customary law system. (James, 1971:93ff) It was primarily intended to<br />

meet <strong>the</strong> need <strong>of</strong> connecting <strong>the</strong> customary system <strong>of</strong> land tenure with <strong>the</strong> interests <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

colonial system.<br />

Right <strong>of</strong> occupancy in Tanzania<br />

The first definition <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian right <strong>of</strong> occupancy is being vaguely described in <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Land</strong> Tenure Ordinance <strong>of</strong> 1923 9 as “a title to <strong>the</strong> use and occupation <strong>of</strong> land“. Being<br />

criticised by <strong>the</strong> League <strong>of</strong> Nations for not enough recognising and protecting <strong>the</strong> land<br />

rights <strong>of</strong> indigenous people, a second, more precise, definition was given in <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong><br />

Ordinance <strong>of</strong> 1928 10 where it was stated as, “<strong>the</strong> title <strong>of</strong> a native or a native community<br />

lawfully using and occupying land in accordance with native law and custom“. (James,<br />

1971:96f) Since <strong>the</strong>n, a dual system <strong>of</strong> land tenure exists in Tanzania embracing deemed<br />

rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy, which allowed natives <strong>the</strong> right to land according to <strong>the</strong>ir customary<br />

laws, and granted rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy, which secured mainly foreign immigrants and<br />

companies well defined and legally protected rights to land according to a British model.<br />

The deemed rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy, though, remained only declaratory, and was nei<strong>the</strong>r<br />

brought within <strong>the</strong> public sector <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land tenure structure, nor explicitly mentioned in<br />

any law until <strong>the</strong> current legislation was passed in 1999. (Ndjovu, 2003:76), (James,<br />

1971:97) Through <strong>the</strong> land acts, a right <strong>of</strong> occupancy is to be understood as ”a title to <strong>the</strong><br />

use and occupation <strong>of</strong> land, and includes <strong>the</strong> title <strong>of</strong> a Tanzanian citizen <strong>of</strong> African<br />

descent…” or a community <strong>the</strong>re<strong>of</strong> ”using and occupying land in accordance with<br />

customary law.” (Interview, Mutakyamilwa), (LA 1999:2), (VLA 1999:2)<br />

5 The first attempt to revoke <strong>the</strong> semi-feudal landlord/tenant relationship was through The Nyarubanja Enfranchisement <strong>Act</strong> 1965, but<br />

as this law failed to address <strong>the</strong> many different forms <strong>of</strong> feudal tenure around <strong>the</strong> nation, The Customary Leaseholds<br />

(Enfranchisement) <strong>Act</strong>, 1968 was enacted three years later.<br />

6 Through The Freehold Titles (Conversion) and Government Leases <strong>Act</strong>, 1963 and <strong>the</strong> following Government Leaseholds<br />

(Conversion to Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy) <strong>Act</strong>, 1969<br />

7<br />

The Native Authority Ordinance, Cap 72<br />

8<br />

African Chiefs Ordinance (Repeal) <strong>Act</strong>, 1963<br />

9<br />

Ordinance No. 3/1923, Section<br />

5<br />

10<br />

Ordinance No. 7/1928<br />

20


A form <strong>of</strong> leasehold<br />

The right <strong>of</strong> occupancy system in its statutory form is built on <strong>the</strong> leasehold principle.<br />

The carrying idea is that <strong>the</strong> radical title, i.e. <strong>the</strong> ultimate ownership and control <strong>of</strong> land,<br />

belongs to <strong>the</strong> community, entrusting <strong>the</strong> government its legal instruments. (Ndjovu,<br />

2003:76) At a first glance, <strong>the</strong> principle seems to have been adopted from <strong>the</strong> customary<br />

view <strong>of</strong> land, although enlarged to <strong>the</strong> national level instead <strong>of</strong> being rooted in <strong>the</strong> local<br />

context <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village or <strong>the</strong> tribe. It might, though, be precisely this distinction that<br />

turned <strong>the</strong> concept around. As soon as <strong>the</strong> principle was loosened from its local<br />

foundation, it was also robbed <strong>of</strong> its distinctive character, namely that <strong>of</strong> being locally<br />

anchored and informally managed. Having completed this transformation, <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong><br />

occupancy turned out to well suit <strong>the</strong> intentions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> British administration to<br />

effectively control land utilisation. Noteworthy in this sense is, that <strong>the</strong> conceptual<br />

framework that lies behind <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> Ordinance has been imported virtually unaltered into<br />

<strong>the</strong> new land acts. The statement in <strong>the</strong> new legislation, “All land in Tanzania is public<br />

land vested in <strong>the</strong> President as a trustee on behalf <strong>of</strong> all citizens“, is merely replicated<br />

from <strong>the</strong> British law, with <strong>the</strong> principle difference that <strong>the</strong> previous word governor, as a<br />

representative for <strong>the</strong> imperial crown, has been replaced with <strong>the</strong> republican president.<br />

(Commission report, 1994:19) Critics hold that it is <strong>the</strong> same idea <strong>of</strong> centralisation and<br />

control that governs both writings and <strong>the</strong>ir underlying legal frameworks.<br />

(Shivji, 1999(1))<br />

In one area, though, <strong>the</strong> independent government made immediate amendments in <strong>the</strong><br />

inherited land legislation. Within <strong>the</strong> first years after independence, all different types <strong>of</strong><br />

freehold titles, issued during <strong>the</strong> colonial period, were repealed and converted into<br />

government leaseholds for a definite period <strong>of</strong> time. 11 (Commission report, 1994:18)<br />

Conditions<br />

The right <strong>of</strong> occupancy system shows similarity to a leasehold system by granting rights<br />

to use <strong>the</strong> land for a fixed term <strong>of</strong> certain duration. Three main durations were given,<br />

depending on <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> land. For residential development, 33 years; for commercial<br />

property and farms, 66 years; and for agricultural purposes, 99 years. (Ndjovu, 2003:71)<br />

As will be seen in chapter 5, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> 1999 introduces infinite duration for<br />

villagers in <strong>the</strong> countryside. (VLA 1999:27) Keeping land under <strong>the</strong> radical title <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

central government allows it to ascribe conditions to <strong>the</strong> use and maintenance <strong>of</strong> land.<br />

This is meant to avoid undesired land speculation or abuse <strong>of</strong> property rights. A primary<br />

condition in order to keep <strong>the</strong> accorded right to land is, that <strong>the</strong> land must be under<br />

continuous utilisation. (LA 1999:34, VLA 1999:29) This condition has, also traditionally,<br />

been imperative for <strong>the</strong> security <strong>of</strong> tenure. (See chapter 2.2) (Ndjovu, 2003:72)<br />

11 Freehold Titles (Conversion) and Government Leases <strong>Act</strong> 1963, Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy (Development Conditions) <strong>Act</strong> 1963,<br />

Government Leaseholds (Conversion to Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy) <strong>Act</strong> 1965<br />

21


2.4 Tanzanian land ideology<br />

A few years before <strong>the</strong> independence <strong>of</strong> Tanganyika, Julius Nyerere formulated his<br />

conception <strong>of</strong> land tenure, which a few years later became part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> established<br />

ideology in <strong>the</strong> new born independent African nation. In a pamphlet named National<br />

Property 12 , published in 1958, Nyerere confronts <strong>the</strong> injustices he finds in <strong>the</strong> freehold<br />

system, and <strong>the</strong> consequences it would bring to <strong>the</strong> Tanganyikan society if being<br />

introduced. In a desire to avoid <strong>the</strong> drawbacks from both <strong>the</strong> freehold system, and <strong>the</strong><br />

old-fashioned customary system, Nyerere discusses <strong>the</strong> philosophical foundation <strong>of</strong> an<br />

alternative land tenure system. Thanks to <strong>the</strong> working out <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new legislation, some <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong>se topics are once again put on <strong>the</strong> agenda <strong>of</strong> national discussion.<br />

Succession <strong>of</strong> ownership<br />

Being deeply rooted in <strong>the</strong> principles <strong>of</strong> African traditionalism, Nyerere’s argumentation<br />

is based on <strong>the</strong> idea that land, in <strong>the</strong> same manner as air and water, is no single mans<br />

property. Instead it is a gift <strong>of</strong> God given to all people. Nyerere questions what authorizes<br />

someone <strong>the</strong> right to possess land, thus refusing <strong>the</strong> whole world this right <strong>of</strong> ownership.<br />

Accordingly, he argues that no one has any better right to land than <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r; nei<strong>the</strong>r<br />

yesterdays owner, nor <strong>the</strong> present generation or <strong>the</strong> one to come. Hence, access to land<br />

should be a matter <strong>of</strong> temporary tenancy. Nyerere holds that all citizens are provided with<br />

as equal rights to land as possible only when land ownership is seen as a succession <strong>of</strong><br />

expiring tenancies.<br />

Public property<br />

In order to preserve accessibility to land also for coming generations, land should remain<br />

public property. If acknowledging <strong>the</strong> idea that everybody is but a mere tenant <strong>of</strong> land,<br />

which does not actually belong to him, it would be wrong to distribute land on an<br />

ownership basis. Instead <strong>of</strong> a freehold system, where all decisions <strong>of</strong> property rights are<br />

individually owned, land should be publicly owned, with individual rights granted<br />

through leaseholds. When publicly owned, Nyerere reasons, <strong>the</strong> right to decide on land<br />

use, will not be in <strong>the</strong> hands <strong>of</strong> individuals; instead all citizens decides on regulations<br />

governing <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> land. Hence, “<strong>Land</strong> remains <strong>the</strong> property <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> public, but <strong>the</strong><br />

leaseholder has <strong>the</strong> promise <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> public, all his fellow citizens, that he will not be<br />

interfered with in his right to use that land“. Nyerere sketches within <strong>the</strong> leasehold<br />

system, <strong>the</strong> fulfilment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> three main requirements to secure <strong>the</strong> leaseholder a<br />

predictable future. Firstly, <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> sufficient land, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> assurance <strong>of</strong> not being<br />

evicted from <strong>the</strong> land, and finally, <strong>the</strong> availability <strong>of</strong> capital needed to invest in <strong>the</strong> land.<br />

In exchange, <strong>the</strong> leaseholder must submit to <strong>the</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> leasehold agreement in using<br />

and maintaining <strong>the</strong> land.<br />

<strong>Land</strong> value<br />

Closely connected to this topic, Nyerere discusses <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> added labour. (See also<br />

chapter 2.2) By transforming a piece <strong>of</strong> land through her own labour, a person is enabled<br />

to lay claim <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> added value to that piece <strong>of</strong> land. When leaving <strong>the</strong> land, she is<br />

entitled to compensation for <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> unexhausted improvements being made,<br />

12 In Swahili titled, ”Mali ya Taifa”<br />

22


including clearing, plantations, constructions et cetera. Hence, a fundamental policy was<br />

not to recognise any value to bare land, but only to <strong>the</strong> improvements made to <strong>the</strong> land. In<br />

<strong>the</strong> principally important Arusha Declaration, this idea is stated as a policy <strong>of</strong> nonmarketability<br />

<strong>of</strong> land. (Ndjovu, 2003:79) One <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> assumptions supporting this policy<br />

was to keep <strong>the</strong> price <strong>of</strong> land low through suppressing <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> a land market.<br />

The policy aimed at keeping land prices regulated in <strong>the</strong> interest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor. (Interview,<br />

Mutakyamilwa, 2004-12-13)<br />

Confronting <strong>the</strong> freehold system<br />

Nyerere’s strongest argument against a freehold system is to prevent a separation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

population into unequal classes. In his view, he imagines a small group <strong>of</strong> landlords on<br />

<strong>the</strong> one hand, holding ownership rights; and on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, a large group <strong>of</strong> tenants being<br />

dependent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> goodwill <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> landlords. Nyerere fears that such a development would<br />

create inequality and violent antagonism among <strong>the</strong> people. A freehold system would<br />

also encourage exploiters and speculators in land, preventing access to land by true land<br />

users with insufficient finances. Nyerere clearly states that <strong>the</strong> system <strong>of</strong> leasehold would<br />

effectively prevent such biases. It would not only avoid <strong>the</strong> unjust paying <strong>of</strong> land rents to<br />

private landlords, but instead promote <strong>the</strong> more equal paying <strong>of</strong> land rents to <strong>the</strong><br />

government by all land-holders.<br />

23


3. Conceptual basics<br />

Introduction<br />

The issue <strong>of</strong> property rights in relation to land certainly catches political attention.<br />

According to some viewpoints, land represents considerable economic values, whereas<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r sentiments connect <strong>the</strong> holding <strong>of</strong> land mainly to social values. This chapter aims to<br />

provide insights into <strong>the</strong> terminology <strong>of</strong> property rights <strong>the</strong>ory. This is necessary in order<br />

to fur<strong>the</strong>r discuss <strong>the</strong> topic applied to <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian reality, as well as to more general<br />

African land issues. In <strong>the</strong> latter part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> chapter, a comparison is taking place between<br />

<strong>the</strong> Tanzanian system <strong>of</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy and a general position <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> ownership<br />

model, here identified as <strong>the</strong> freehold system.<br />

3.1 Property rights <strong>the</strong>ory<br />

<strong>Land</strong> as limited resource, scarcity and land value<br />

<strong>Land</strong> is quite obviously a limited resource. The potential limitation <strong>of</strong> having a finite<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> land does not necessarily imply scarcity <strong>of</strong> land. On <strong>the</strong> contrary, if divided<br />

equally, <strong>the</strong>re is more than enough land for everyone in <strong>the</strong> world. It is precisely this<br />

issue, <strong>the</strong> biased distribution <strong>of</strong> land, which is one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> main reasons for <strong>the</strong> scarcityrelated<br />

land problems <strong>of</strong> today. Closely related to biased distribution is <strong>the</strong> fact that not<br />

all land is equally attractive from a human point <strong>of</strong> view. Yet ano<strong>the</strong>r contributing factor,<br />

especially pressurising urban and semi-urban areas in developing countries, is <strong>the</strong><br />

increasing population density.<br />

Looking at <strong>the</strong> African context, <strong>the</strong> population density has been kept low until <strong>the</strong> middle<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> twentieth century. Hence, land has always been an abundant resource. Since <strong>the</strong>n,<br />

an exploding population growth, land degradation and unstable climatic conditions, have<br />

increased <strong>the</strong> demand for land. Especially fertile land and land containing important and<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itable natural resources 13 have been subject to increased attention. This has resulted<br />

in local land scarcity, creating an emerging land market and an increased awareness <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> tradable value <strong>of</strong> land. As will be shown, access to land has strong social<br />

implications, and cannot <strong>the</strong>refore simply be treated like any o<strong>the</strong>r tradable commodity.<br />

Instead, <strong>the</strong> handling <strong>of</strong> rights to land needs to be enclosed with careful and competent<br />

regulations. (Quan, 2003) 14 , (Interview, Mutakyamilwa)<br />

Alternative land use, institutions<br />

Besides scarcity, alternative land use is a factor determining <strong>the</strong> demand for, as well as<br />

<strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> land. The choice to use land for a certain purpose mostly prevents it from<br />

being used to satisfy o<strong>the</strong>r needs. Such competing interest causes decisions to be made<br />

that will have socio-economic effect. While similar occurrences show up in all societies,<br />

each society has developed a structure <strong>of</strong> incentives to determine which rules and values<br />

<strong>the</strong> distribution <strong>of</strong> land is to follow. Pejovich names <strong>the</strong>se structures institutions, and<br />

explains <strong>the</strong>m as being “legal, administrative and customary arrangements for repeated<br />

13 Natural resources such as hardwood forests, valuable or easily accessible minerals and oil, but also wildlife and scenic views.<br />

14 Julian Quan was at that time <strong>Land</strong> Policy Advicer at <strong>the</strong> U.K. Department for International Development, DFID<br />

24


human interaction”. These institutions include an agreed upon system <strong>of</strong> behaviour and a<br />

chain <strong>of</strong> influence concerning land issues. Simply stated, <strong>the</strong>y determine <strong>the</strong> land-use<br />

priority. Pejovich tracks <strong>the</strong> institutions to be “based on customs including past<br />

experiences, taboos, standards <strong>of</strong> behaviour and perceptions that individuals had formed<br />

about <strong>the</strong> world around <strong>the</strong>m”. (Pejovich, 1990:3f) In western societies, <strong>the</strong>se values<br />

have mainly been <strong>of</strong> economic nature. Looking back, it appears like economic values<br />

easily result in short-range pr<strong>of</strong>itability calculations, lacking sustainable perspectives on<br />

<strong>the</strong> environment or on social relations. In many indigenous societies, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand,<br />

values such as social comfort and equality are highly preferred. Here <strong>the</strong> alternative land<br />

use is less a matter <strong>of</strong> maximised effectiveness from a monetary point <strong>of</strong> view, than <strong>of</strong><br />

social relations and interactions with <strong>the</strong> neighbouring land-holders. It seems like <strong>the</strong><br />

interdependence and co-operation favouring a social structure tends to become greater<br />

where <strong>the</strong> financial resources are scarce. Ano<strong>the</strong>r conclusion might be that financial<br />

independence inherently brings about an independent behaviour, even though cooperation<br />

would have been a more efficient way. Never<strong>the</strong>less, with changes in <strong>the</strong><br />

structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> surrounding world, also <strong>the</strong> customary institutions are being subject to<br />

transformation. As <strong>the</strong> society grows more complex, <strong>the</strong> core values <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> customary<br />

institutions tend to become more formalised, and are eventually being replaced by<br />

statutory laws and centrally administered regulations.<br />

Property as a social relation<br />

According to modern academic <strong>the</strong>ory, owning property is less a matter <strong>of</strong> owning a<br />

physical resource, than it gives access to a bundle <strong>of</strong> rights attached to <strong>the</strong> resource.<br />

Ownership, hence, represents <strong>the</strong> rights to use a resource in a specified and limited way.<br />

(Alchian & Demsetz, 1973:17) These rights would have no value at all, if not being<br />

recognised by <strong>the</strong> surrounding society. Thus, ”property is a social relation, defining what<br />

an individual, or group, can and cannot do with a certain thing, and which needs to be<br />

respected by o<strong>the</strong>rs.” (van den Brink, 2003:2) 15 This relation is valid in all types <strong>of</strong><br />

ownerships, but is especially obvious when related to land and property rights. Having<br />

this assessment in mind, <strong>the</strong> frequent confusion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> terms property and ownership<br />

appears explicable as <strong>the</strong>y both refer to <strong>the</strong> rights connected to a piece <strong>of</strong> land.<br />

Scarcity as a driving force<br />

As instruments <strong>of</strong> society, property rights are guiding social behaviour for both<br />

beneficiaries and outsiders. (Demsetz, 1967:247f) Regardless if <strong>the</strong> tenure system allows<br />

formal ownership, or usufruct rights <strong>of</strong> different types, <strong>the</strong> system regulates certain rights<br />

and obligations for right holders as well as outsiders. (See chapter 3.2)<br />

These socially sanctioned rights <strong>of</strong> action are, according to Alchian and Demsetz,<br />

responding to a specific social system. (Alchian & Demsetz, 1973:17) This system is<br />

“relying on techniques, rules, or customs to resolve conflicts that arise in <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong><br />

scarce resources“. Pejovich states it similarly, “Property rights are relations among men<br />

that arise from <strong>the</strong> existence <strong>of</strong> scarce goods and portain to <strong>the</strong>ir use” (Pejovich,<br />

1990:27) In order to be useful, <strong>the</strong> property rights have to be accepted, clearly defined,<br />

well understood and strictly enforced. (van den Brink, 2003:8) It may be assumed that<br />

15 Rogier van den Brink was at that time <strong>Land</strong> Reform and <strong>Land</strong> Policy Coordinator at <strong>the</strong> World Bank, Africa Region, in South<br />

Africa. The following quotations are taken from a preliminary draft <strong>of</strong> a paper on land policy and land reform in Sub-Saharan Africa.<br />

It should be noted that <strong>the</strong> opinions expressed in <strong>the</strong> paper not necessary have to be those <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> World Bank.<br />

25


homogenous societies with common values, and where <strong>the</strong> cultural control is strong, have<br />

developed less complex systems <strong>of</strong> property rights.<br />

Diverse African land tenure<br />

As <strong>the</strong> societies grow more diverse and complex, <strong>the</strong> rules <strong>of</strong> property rights have to be<br />

more explicitly stated. James and Fimbo emphasises <strong>the</strong> great diversity and variation <strong>of</strong><br />

land tenure systems also within societies practising customary land tenure. They stress<br />

that <strong>the</strong>re is no such thing as a corporate system <strong>of</strong> African customary land tenure.<br />

Instead <strong>the</strong>y reason that <strong>the</strong> variety <strong>of</strong> customary land tenure in Africa is as diversified as<br />

<strong>the</strong> structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> individual societies. “A record on African land tenure systems would<br />

certainly differ from and be wider in scope than a record on different Western land<br />

tenure systems.” (James & Fimbo, 1973:5) In relation to western societies, though,<br />

African societies do share corporate values. James and Fimbo explain that <strong>the</strong> difference<br />

lies in that law in <strong>the</strong> western context is founded on an individualistic assumption,<br />

whereas in <strong>the</strong> African context, it is based on a collectivist organisation. (James & Fimbo,<br />

1973:5) As land in western societies is considered capable <strong>of</strong> being owned in similar<br />

ways as o<strong>the</strong>r goods, <strong>the</strong> bulk <strong>of</strong> land tenure rules are <strong>the</strong>refore concerned with an<br />

analysis <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land rights <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> individual. The emphasis is laid upon <strong>the</strong> acquisition <strong>of</strong><br />

rights, as well as on <strong>the</strong> methods <strong>of</strong> transferring and extinguishing <strong>the</strong>se rights.<br />

For <strong>the</strong> Africans, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, land is more than just property. “<strong>Land</strong> continues to<br />

be <strong>the</strong> central force around which <strong>the</strong> rural people’s spiritual and cultural life is<br />

organised. Tampering with land <strong>the</strong>refore means tampering with <strong>the</strong> social/psychological<br />

fabric <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> society“. (Commission report, 1994:119)<br />

The land tenure rules form a part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> whole complex <strong>of</strong> culture. Contrary to <strong>the</strong><br />

individualistic western organisation, it is dominated by <strong>the</strong> need to protect units <strong>of</strong> groups<br />

to specific parcels <strong>of</strong> land. The corpus <strong>of</strong> law for each group is directed towards defining<br />

<strong>the</strong> rights and duties <strong>of</strong> everyone within <strong>the</strong> group, aiming at maintaining <strong>the</strong> interests <strong>of</strong><br />

that unit against outsiders. The central idea <strong>of</strong> land tenure rules have thus been one <strong>of</strong><br />

controls, emphasising controls, not titles, as <strong>the</strong> dominant aspect <strong>of</strong> land law. (James &<br />

Fimbo, 1973:6) (See also chapter 2.2)<br />

Three main forms <strong>of</strong> ownership<br />

Keeping in mind that ownership represents a bundle <strong>of</strong> rights, three forms <strong>of</strong> ownership<br />

appears, which will be fur<strong>the</strong>r explained below. These are according to Demsetz,<br />

communal ownership, private/individual ownership and state ownership. (Demsetz<br />

1967:353) O<strong>the</strong>r scholars add lack <strong>of</strong> ownership to <strong>the</strong> list. (van den Brink, 2003:4)<br />

With communal ownership, Demsetz means rights which can be exercised by all<br />

members <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> community. No one, not even <strong>the</strong> state, have <strong>the</strong> right to interfere with<br />

any person’s exercise <strong>of</strong> communally owned rights. As will be shown later in <strong>the</strong> chapter,<br />

it is important to clearly define <strong>the</strong> society in order to find out <strong>the</strong> circle <strong>of</strong> beneficiaries<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> communal rights in question.<br />

Private ownership, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, implies that <strong>the</strong> community recognises <strong>the</strong> owner’s<br />

right to exclude foreigners from exercising private or communal rights on his territory.<br />

Finally, state ownership implies that <strong>the</strong> state may, by way <strong>of</strong> exception, exclude anyone<br />

from <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> a right, as long as <strong>the</strong> state follows accepted political procedures for<br />

determining who may not use state-owned property. (Demsetz, 1967:353f)<br />

26


Common, communal and public property<br />

As land tenure in Africa is based on a collectivist organisation, <strong>the</strong>re is a need to bring<br />

clarity in <strong>the</strong> slightly confusing terminology alluding to collectivist types <strong>of</strong> ownership.<br />

Notably <strong>of</strong>ten, <strong>the</strong> words common property, communal property, public property and<br />

state property are wrongly used as synonyms.<br />

Private property Communal property<br />

Individual property Common/communal property State / public property<br />

Figure 3.1<br />

The figure aims to sort out <strong>the</strong> disparities between private and communal property (ownership).<br />

As property is defined to comprise a bundle <strong>of</strong> socially accepted rights, <strong>the</strong> terms property, property rights<br />

and ownership may be understood similarly.<br />

The two main types <strong>of</strong> ownership are private and communal property rights. Within <strong>the</strong><br />

private sector we distinguish between individual and common property rights, where<br />

common property simply represents private property for <strong>the</strong> group. (Bromley, 1992:11)<br />

The limited community holds <strong>the</strong> land in common, whereby <strong>the</strong> utilisation <strong>of</strong> portions <strong>of</strong><br />

land may be allotted to individuals within <strong>the</strong> group. In <strong>the</strong> communal sector, communal<br />

and state/public property rights are separated. Normally, both common and communal<br />

property refers to a limited community, whereas state and public property means property<br />

where a larger group <strong>of</strong> people, a city or a whole nation, have access. (van den Brink,<br />

2003:3)<br />

Communal ownership<br />

Communal ownership, including state or public ownership, means that property rights are<br />

exercised within a defined group <strong>of</strong> people. Individuals within this group are sharing <strong>the</strong><br />

communal property, although <strong>the</strong>y cannot normally claim any specific piece <strong>of</strong> land.<br />

The use, maintenance and return from <strong>the</strong> communal area, excluding public land, is split<br />

between <strong>the</strong> shareholders according to traditional, or agreed upon, rules and procedures.<br />

(van den Brink, 2003:3f) <strong>Village</strong> commons in rural areas <strong>of</strong> Tanzania for example, are<br />

used as reserve land for <strong>the</strong> future expansion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village. How this traditional practice<br />

will be dealt with in <strong>the</strong> new legislation is not yet clear. Van den Brink maintains that<br />

nothing refrains <strong>the</strong> community from assigning certain rights to individuals, and o<strong>the</strong>rs to<br />

<strong>the</strong> group as a whole also within a common property regime. Also <strong>the</strong> right to inherit,<br />

exchange, rent, or sell its share will be decided upon by <strong>the</strong> group. (v.d. Brink, 2003:4)<br />

27


The issue <strong>of</strong> open access<br />

The situation <strong>of</strong> no ownership, also called open access, occurs when <strong>the</strong> “property rules<br />

applying to natural resources are nei<strong>the</strong>r able to be defined, nor enforced, by <strong>the</strong><br />

communities“. (van den Brink, 2003:4) Under such conditions <strong>the</strong>re is no defined group<br />

<strong>of</strong> owners, land security have ceased to exist, and access to <strong>the</strong> resources is available to<br />

anyone. (van den Brink, 2003:4) The tragedy <strong>of</strong> this regime is that it rewards greed, and<br />

counteracts a sustainable development. A restraining attitude from a few individuals, in<br />

order to promote sustainability, will only reward <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs. Unless an agreement<br />

is established, or <strong>the</strong> state takes authority to restrict <strong>the</strong> rapacity, <strong>the</strong> situation will become<br />

destructive. Disastrous large-scale examples <strong>of</strong> this behaviour are <strong>the</strong> continuous over<br />

fish <strong>of</strong> lakes and oceans, <strong>the</strong> overuse <strong>of</strong> subsoil water, especially <strong>the</strong> non-renewable fossil<br />

aquifers, and <strong>the</strong> worldwide pollution <strong>of</strong> lakes, oceans, and <strong>the</strong> atmosphere. The result in<br />

<strong>the</strong>se and similar areas is likely to be a situation where unsustainable overuse brings<br />

tragic consequences to <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> scarce resources and species. 16<br />

Private ownership<br />

Private ownership is <strong>of</strong>ten seen as <strong>the</strong> strongest form <strong>of</strong> land-holding. It bears far going<br />

exclusive rights for <strong>the</strong> rights-holder, and is limited only by restrictions explicitly stated<br />

in <strong>the</strong> law. In individualistic societies, this implies a strong link between <strong>the</strong> owner’s<br />

choice to use <strong>the</strong> asset, and him bearing <strong>the</strong> consequences <strong>the</strong>re<strong>of</strong>. (Pejovich, 1990:28)<br />

But although this is true, van den Brink points out that property rights under private<br />

ownership, similar to those under communal ownership, are always restricted by<br />

regulations. “Under a communal property regime, individual rights are regulated by <strong>the</strong><br />

community, whereas, under a private property regime, individual rights are regulated by<br />

<strong>the</strong> state.“ (van den Brink, 2003:4) Consequently, <strong>the</strong> scope for freedom <strong>of</strong> action for <strong>the</strong><br />

private land-holder is not at all unlimited, but is to be decided by <strong>the</strong> state. It is here that<br />

<strong>the</strong> country-specific and <strong>of</strong>ten politically coloured land policy is being applied, which<br />

among <strong>the</strong> nations shows a broad variety <strong>of</strong> attitudes towards interference by <strong>the</strong> state.<br />

To elucidate <strong>the</strong> situation where also private ownership accomplishes open access like<br />

behaviour, let us use a classic example. Imagine a brook running through a<br />

neighbourhood, crossing several private properties. None <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> landowners have <strong>the</strong><br />

right to exclude <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs from using <strong>the</strong> water except when it passes <strong>the</strong>ir own property.<br />

Likewise, no one have <strong>the</strong> power, except through negotiation, to hinder anyone else from<br />

using <strong>the</strong> water when it passes <strong>the</strong>ir own plot. Whatever <strong>the</strong> landowners situated upstreams<br />

decides to do, whe<strong>the</strong>r it is tapping water for irrigation, or disposing waste into<br />

<strong>the</strong> brook, will unconditionally have impact on <strong>the</strong> flow, or <strong>the</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> water<br />

received down-streams. According to <strong>the</strong> contract <strong>of</strong> private ownership, those situated<br />

up-streams have no incentives to act responsibly, o<strong>the</strong>r than for reasons <strong>of</strong> goodwill.<br />

(Demsetz, 1967:356) Here <strong>the</strong> definition <strong>of</strong> property as a social relation comes in. In<br />

societies with strong cultural control, certain behaviour is simply not acceptable, whereas<br />

where regulations have substituted <strong>the</strong> control mechanisms, outright prohibition first have<br />

to be regulated in <strong>the</strong> written law, and <strong>the</strong>n strictly policed, in order to become effective.<br />

16 Deriving from Hardin’s renowned article named The tragedy <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> commons (Hardin, 1968) Demsetz confusingly uses <strong>the</strong> term<br />

communal rights when describing <strong>the</strong> unsustainable incentives connected with <strong>the</strong> open-access problematic. (Alchian & Demsetz,<br />

1973:19) van den Brink argues that this reasoning has nothing to do with communal ownership, but instead describes a state with lack<br />

<strong>of</strong> ownership. He recognises this confusion and instead prefers to call this phenomenon “The tragedy <strong>of</strong> open access”.<br />

28


State ownership<br />

State ownership, normally including public ownership, is characterised by providing<br />

services for <strong>the</strong> good <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> citizens. To a large extent, publicly owned areas are<br />

equivalent with free entry for anyone, whereas entrance into publicly owned<br />

establishments 17 normally requires paying <strong>of</strong> fees. Unlike open access, <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> public<br />

areas is strictly regulated. Public parks, for example, are not for picking flowers or<br />

cutting firewood; likewise is <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> public roads submitted to detailed driving<br />

regulations. Military reservations are one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> few examples <strong>of</strong> state-owned areas<br />

leaving almost no rights for <strong>the</strong> fellow citizen. (Alchian & Demsetz, 1973:19)<br />

The ideologically charged issue <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> ultimate owner <strong>of</strong> land, has over <strong>the</strong> years opened<br />

up for several more or less coercive land reforms. Demsetz demarcates an interesting<br />

limitation when he states, “State ownership implies that <strong>the</strong> state may exclude anyone<br />

from <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> a right as long as <strong>the</strong> state follows accepted political procedures for<br />

determining who may not use state-owned property.“ (Demsetz, 1967:354) The definition<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> peculiar phrase “accepted political procedures” has truly varied from time to time.<br />

The colonial governors, for example, interpreted it one way, and <strong>the</strong> one-party socialist<br />

regime in Tanzania interpreted it ano<strong>the</strong>r.<br />

The issue <strong>of</strong> public interest<br />

Representing <strong>the</strong> state in relation to <strong>the</strong> citizens is a ra<strong>the</strong>r delicate task. Many are <strong>the</strong><br />

examples <strong>of</strong> abuse from politicians bent on pr<strong>of</strong>iting from <strong>the</strong> inherently unequal power<br />

relation. Multiple cases, being scrutinised by <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian land commission, testifies <strong>of</strong><br />

an obvious lack <strong>of</strong> equity and integrity from representatives <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> state. Ano<strong>the</strong>r<br />

universally known complication arises when <strong>the</strong> state simultaneously holds two<br />

incompatible positions. On <strong>the</strong> one hand, <strong>the</strong> state represents one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> parties involved<br />

in a legal case, possibly as landlord, and on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, it claims to represent <strong>the</strong> interest<br />

and welfare <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> majority. The power relations are destined to become biased, which<br />

opens up for corrupt practises and unjust decisions. (Commission report, 1994:115f) In<br />

order to find legitimacy for encroachments concerning land, <strong>the</strong> state <strong>of</strong>ten claims to act<br />

on behalf <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> entire population by stating to act in public interest, or <strong>the</strong> interest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

nation. In traditional democracies, property rights are secured in <strong>the</strong> constitution, which<br />

also contains rules, limits and <strong>the</strong> right to fair compensation for encroachments that may<br />

arise. An <strong>of</strong>ten noticed weakness in Tanzania, as well as in many o<strong>the</strong>r young<br />

democracies, is <strong>the</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> criterion constituting <strong>the</strong> legal definition <strong>of</strong> public interest.<br />

This constitutional weakness has enabled <strong>the</strong> state to interpret this powerful tool very<br />

widely, serving unfair, dubious or even corrupt purposes. There is nei<strong>the</strong>r in <strong>the</strong><br />

constitution, nor <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian land legislation any definition <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> term public interest.<br />

Only a vague writing is available in <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> Acquisition <strong>Act</strong> <strong>of</strong> 1967. (Wily, 2003:11)<br />

17 Publicly owned establishments such as: swimming halls, museums, trains and metros et cetera.<br />

29


3.2 Comparison <strong>of</strong> rights<br />

We have seen that ownership can be identified as socially recognised rights attached to a<br />

specific piece <strong>of</strong> land. Seen from a higher perspective, <strong>the</strong> very reason for a clearly<br />

defined land tenure system is to elucidate <strong>the</strong> rights, limitations and obligations<br />

connected to <strong>the</strong> holding <strong>of</strong> land. If <strong>the</strong>se rights were well defined and effectively policed,<br />

land security would be strong, whereas mismanagement and land disputes would cease to<br />

cause problems.<br />

The objective <strong>of</strong> this part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> study is to analyse <strong>the</strong> bundle <strong>of</strong> rights connected to each<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two apparently opposing systems <strong>of</strong> land tenure, <strong>the</strong> freehold system and <strong>the</strong> right<br />

<strong>of</strong> occupancy system.<br />

A<br />

B<br />

C<br />

A, B and C represents land-tenure<br />

systems <strong>of</strong> three different societies.<br />

Components <strong>of</strong> land rights<br />

common for both A and B.<br />

Component <strong>of</strong> land right<br />

common for both B and C.<br />

Components <strong>of</strong> land rights<br />

shared by all three tenure systems.<br />

Figure 3.2<br />

The figure illustrates how <strong>the</strong> bundles <strong>of</strong> rights connected to different land tenure systems overlap each<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r. Although <strong>the</strong> land tenure systems in societies B and C resembles one ano<strong>the</strong>r by <strong>the</strong>ir outward form,<br />

when it comes to factual land rights <strong>the</strong>y may have less in common than with <strong>the</strong> apparently different land<br />

tenure system A.<br />

The fact that <strong>the</strong>re exist radically different land tenure systems, underlines that <strong>the</strong>re is no<br />

universal, technical definition <strong>of</strong> ownership to land. (van den Brink, 2003:2) Existing<br />

tenure systems may, hastily examined, appear to have almost nothing in common, but<br />

deviates by closer examination only in <strong>the</strong> amount and type <strong>of</strong> rights that are given to<br />

holders <strong>of</strong> land. Within each tenure-system <strong>the</strong>re is normally more than one type <strong>of</strong> landholding,<br />

which enables <strong>the</strong> rights to somehow overlap between different systems.<br />

(See figure 3.2)<br />

The bundle <strong>of</strong> rights attached to a specific type <strong>of</strong> land-holding, determines within which<br />

limits <strong>the</strong> land-holder must keep. On <strong>the</strong> one hand, it restricts him in claiming property<br />

rights in relation to neighbours and <strong>the</strong> society, but on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, it enables him to<br />

fully occupy, and execute dominion within <strong>the</strong> prescribed area <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> stated property<br />

rights.<br />

30


Elements <strong>of</strong> ownership rights<br />

According to Pejovich, <strong>the</strong> four following elements were used by <strong>the</strong> ancient Roman Law<br />

to describe different forms and levels <strong>of</strong> authorities over ownership rights:<br />

i) <strong>the</strong> right to use <strong>the</strong> asset (usus)<br />

ii) <strong>the</strong> right to capture benefits from <strong>the</strong> asset (usus fructus)<br />

iii) <strong>the</strong> right to change its form and substance (abuses)<br />

iv) <strong>the</strong> right to transfer all, or some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rights specified<br />

under i-iii to o<strong>the</strong>rs, at a mutually agreed upon price.<br />

For far-reaching individual ownership, <strong>the</strong> last two elements are fundamental. They are<br />

securing <strong>the</strong> owners right to bear changes in <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> his property. (Pejovich,<br />

1990:27f) Conflicts over <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> scarce resources are here prevented by enforcing<br />

distinct boundaries, creating an inside, where <strong>the</strong> owner has been given extensive rights<br />

to decide, and an outside, where <strong>the</strong>se rights are in <strong>the</strong> hands <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r people. Adjacent to<br />

this reasoning comes that management <strong>of</strong> land sometimes have effect outside <strong>the</strong><br />

property, causing a phenomenon called external effects.<br />

Communal ownership<br />

Within communal ownership <strong>the</strong> beneficiary is a collective group sharing <strong>the</strong> rights to a<br />

certain area <strong>of</strong> land among <strong>the</strong>mselves. This type <strong>of</strong> ownership is frequent in large parts<br />

<strong>of</strong> rural Africa. It was also common in Europe, at least until land reforms scattered <strong>the</strong><br />

villages, or <strong>the</strong> industrialisation strongly depopulated <strong>the</strong> countryside.<br />

Obvious rights connected to members <strong>of</strong> commons:<br />

1) The right to enter and pass through an area<br />

2) The right to make use <strong>of</strong> what naturally grows or can be found on <strong>the</strong> ground<br />

Communally held rights that also may be allotted to individuals:<br />

3) The right to till <strong>the</strong> land and pr<strong>of</strong>it from its yield<br />

4) The right to build on <strong>the</strong> property<br />

5) The right to expel non-members from <strong>the</strong> property<br />

Figure 3.3 Features <strong>of</strong> communally held rights<br />

Examples <strong>of</strong> communally owned rural areas are, in an African context, unoccupied<br />

village land kept in common for <strong>the</strong> purpose <strong>of</strong> grazing. Normally, this is land that for<br />

some reason is not suitable for agriculture. It might be too stony, too dry, too wet, or too<br />

far away. O<strong>the</strong>r communally held areas could be village forest reserves, supplying <strong>the</strong><br />

villagers with firewood and construction materials. Communal ownership may also<br />

concern technical devices that benefits from co-operation, such as irrigation schemes<br />

including ditches, pipes, wells and ponds.<br />

Individual ownership<br />

In western societies, individual ownership has during <strong>the</strong> last two centuries constituted<br />

<strong>the</strong> largest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> three categories. Also here, <strong>the</strong> national variety has been wide.<br />

31


Where to be found Type <strong>of</strong> rights for <strong>the</strong> rightsholder<br />

(Designation according to Roman law)<br />

1) The right to enter and pass through <strong>the</strong> property<br />

(The right <strong>of</strong> trespassing)<br />

Characteristic elements <strong>of</strong><br />

both communal ownership<br />

and individual ownership<br />

---------------------------------<br />

Characteristic elements <strong>of</strong><br />

individual ownership,<br />

Present in a communal<br />

manner within communal<br />

ownership<br />

---------------------------------<br />

Characteristic elements <strong>of</strong><br />

individual ownership, but<br />

unusual within communal<br />

ownership<br />

---------------------------------<br />

Equally possible rights<br />

within individual as well as<br />

communal ownership<br />

(although uncommon)<br />

2) The right to make use <strong>of</strong> what naturally grows<br />

(Usus)<br />

-----------------------------------------------------------------<br />

3) The right to till <strong>the</strong> land and pr<strong>of</strong>it from its yield<br />

(Usus fructus)<br />

4) The right to build on <strong>the</strong> property (Abusus)<br />

5) The right to expel outsiders from <strong>the</strong> property<br />

6) The right to fence in <strong>the</strong> property<br />

7) The right to let <strong>the</strong> property be inherited<br />

(The right to transfer all rights to o<strong>the</strong>rs)<br />

-----------------------------------------------------------------<br />

8) The right to mortgage <strong>the</strong> property<br />

(The right to transfer some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rights to o<strong>the</strong>rs)<br />

9) The right to lease out whole/parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> property<br />

(The right to transfer some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rights to o<strong>the</strong>rs)<br />

10) The right to sell <strong>the</strong> property<br />

(The right to transfer all rights to o<strong>the</strong>rs)<br />

-----------------------------------------------------------------<br />

11) The right to make full use <strong>of</strong> minerals in <strong>the</strong><br />

ground (Abusus)<br />

Relative strength<br />

Weaker rights<br />

Stronger rights<br />

Figure 3.4<br />

The figure systematises <strong>the</strong> most common land-related rights in order <strong>of</strong> relative strength. The order in<br />

which <strong>the</strong> rights follow may vary in different cultures, but <strong>the</strong> stronger rights normally include subordinate<br />

rights, or parts <strong>the</strong>re<strong>of</strong>.<br />

State ownership<br />

Examples <strong>of</strong> state-owned rural areas could be public roads, national parks, and national<br />

forest and game reserves. The state keeps <strong>the</strong>se areas for <strong>the</strong> protection <strong>of</strong> public<br />

interests. Due to <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rwise immense transaction costs, it is a worldwide accepted<br />

principle that <strong>the</strong> state provides means for <strong>the</strong> need <strong>of</strong> transportation through public<br />

roads, railroads, ports and airports. Hence, a certain amount <strong>of</strong> state-owned land is to be<br />

found in societies with leasehold tenure as well as in societies having freehold tenure.<br />

Access to state-owned property is normally open for everyone on a first-come, first-serve<br />

basis. Although <strong>the</strong> impression <strong>of</strong> availability is large on state owned property, only <strong>the</strong><br />

two first rights in <strong>the</strong> table are applicable for common users. On public railroads, ports<br />

32


and airports, availability is connected with <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> a charged-for service.<br />

National parks and similar areas might have a discriminative approach to visitors. Native<br />

citizens might be allowed to enter for free, based on traditional rights, whereas foreigners<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten have to pay entrance fees.<br />

3.2.1 The Freehold System<br />

Although similar in its fundamental rights, <strong>the</strong> freehold system <strong>of</strong> each society has its<br />

own detailed bundle <strong>of</strong> rights. One <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> differing factors is, to which extent <strong>the</strong> state<br />

may enjoy exclusive rights to decide on <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> natural resources. There might also<br />

within a country appear classes <strong>of</strong> freehold properties that are restricted in its rights<br />

depending on certain considerations. In Sweden, for example, public access to <strong>the</strong> shore<br />

is considered a national interest, and is <strong>the</strong>refore a legally protected right. This means that<br />

fur<strong>the</strong>r privatisation through <strong>the</strong> erecting <strong>of</strong> new buildings closer to <strong>the</strong> seashore than 100<br />

metres needs to be sanctioned by <strong>the</strong> authorities.<br />

The true meaning <strong>of</strong> freehold is to demarcate a specified unit <strong>of</strong> land to constitute a parcel<br />

<strong>of</strong> its own. It is legally treated as an individual unit, and might differ both in ownership<br />

and bundle <strong>of</strong> rights from <strong>the</strong> surrounding parcels. Freeholds are created to be owned and<br />

managed on individual basis, and without limit in time. 18 This means that <strong>the</strong> owner have<br />

extensive rights to decide how to manage <strong>the</strong> property, as well as to exclude outsiders<br />

from <strong>the</strong> area. Once <strong>the</strong> ownership is secured, <strong>the</strong> owner has <strong>the</strong> right to continuously<br />

keep <strong>the</strong> property, to be succeeded by coming generations through inheritance.<br />

Limitations in <strong>the</strong> property rights<br />

The owner has <strong>the</strong> right to decide upon <strong>the</strong> use, or misuse, <strong>of</strong> her property. Whe<strong>the</strong>r to<br />

build something on it, cultivate it, or leave it to be overgrown, is a matter <strong>of</strong> her own<br />

choice. There are, though, normally public regulations to be followed. As misuse <strong>of</strong> land<br />

and water tends to cause negative external effects, <strong>the</strong>re are normally environmental laws<br />

curtailing <strong>the</strong> acceptable freedom <strong>of</strong> choice in how to use <strong>the</strong> land. Additionally, <strong>the</strong>re<br />

might be restrictions on how and what to build, requiring <strong>the</strong> owner to submit to zoning<br />

laws and apply for building permits. In some cases, <strong>the</strong> owner is prescribed to allow <strong>the</strong><br />

public access for hiking or fishing on <strong>the</strong> property. (van den Brink, 2003:3)<br />

<strong>Land</strong> value<br />

The freehold system is perfectly adjusted to <strong>the</strong> principle <strong>of</strong> trade on a free market. In<br />

<strong>the</strong>ory, it is not <strong>the</strong> piece <strong>of</strong> land itself that is traded, but <strong>the</strong> rights attached to it.<br />

Never<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong>se rights are tradable, and esteem a certain value related to <strong>the</strong> demand<br />

for land, <strong>the</strong> alternative land use and <strong>the</strong> individual prospective buyers’ willingness to<br />

pay. The land value is also affected by <strong>of</strong>ficial regulations circumscribing <strong>the</strong> rights, and<br />

<strong>the</strong> actual policing <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se regulations. Factors like <strong>the</strong>se are weighed by <strong>the</strong> market,<br />

finding an equilibrium that describes <strong>the</strong> market value at each moment.<br />

18 Recognising also organisations as individuals.<br />

33


Fees and taxes<br />

Since freehold systems are common in societies with an established financial<br />

infrastructure, and <strong>the</strong> important land security is built and maintained through <strong>the</strong> keeping<br />

<strong>of</strong> accurate and reliable registers, <strong>the</strong> fee for entry into <strong>the</strong> land register is ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

significant. On top <strong>of</strong> this registering fee, <strong>the</strong> paying <strong>of</strong> an annual tax normally belongs to<br />

<strong>the</strong> duties <strong>of</strong> landowners. The amount <strong>of</strong> this land tax is politically sensitive and varies<br />

considerably between countries.<br />

Security <strong>of</strong> tenure<br />

One <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> fundamental ideas with freehold tenure, is that <strong>the</strong> security <strong>of</strong> ownership must<br />

be guaranteed. This is so, while owning property is highly esteemed and considered a<br />

fundamental right in countries applying to <strong>the</strong> freehold system. Security <strong>of</strong> ownership is<br />

very close connected to financial credibility, as very large sums <strong>of</strong> borrowed money are<br />

secured in property. But, in order to use land as collateral, reliable evidence to pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

identity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> correct land-holder has to be shown. Hence, reliable registers are <strong>of</strong><br />

fundamental importance.<br />

As <strong>the</strong> possessive rights connected to freehold tenure are very strong, it is only in<br />

exceptional cases legally possible to evict <strong>the</strong> holder <strong>of</strong> a freehold land title from his<br />

property. Such situations may occur when projects <strong>of</strong> national interest show up with a<br />

competing land use on <strong>the</strong> same area. In order not to inhibit <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

society, individually owned land may be expropriated against <strong>the</strong> owners will. In such<br />

cases, <strong>the</strong> owner has constitutional rights to be duly compensated for his loss <strong>of</strong> property.<br />

3.2.2 The Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy System<br />

Since <strong>the</strong> independence in 1961, all land in Tanzania is formally owned by <strong>the</strong> people as<br />

a collective group. The president <strong>the</strong>n, is responsible for <strong>the</strong> management and allocation<br />

<strong>of</strong> usufruct rights in <strong>the</strong> land. This means that individuals, groups <strong>of</strong> individuals,<br />

companies and organisations are granted <strong>the</strong> right to use a piece <strong>of</strong> land for a certain<br />

period <strong>of</strong> time.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> new land legislation, a right <strong>of</strong> occupancy title is <strong>the</strong> only available tenure form.<br />

The land acts distinguish between two types <strong>of</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy, <strong>the</strong> Customary Right<br />

<strong>of</strong> Occupancy, being applied only within village land, and <strong>the</strong> Granted Right <strong>of</strong><br />

Occupancy, which is to be used outside village land.<br />

Limitation in time<br />

The most striking difference from a freehold is, that <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy is limited in<br />

time. Depending on land use, <strong>the</strong> time limits are 33 years, 66 years, with a maximum <strong>of</strong><br />

99 years. (LA 1999:32) Excepted from this time limitation is <strong>the</strong> customary right <strong>of</strong><br />

occupancy, which is limitless.<br />

Restriction in use<br />

A right <strong>of</strong> occupancy is allotted for a specific land use purpose. 19 The holder is required<br />

to stick to <strong>the</strong> land use for which <strong>the</strong> certificate is issued. (LA 1999:35) In <strong>the</strong> rural<br />

setting it is also required <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> holder <strong>of</strong> a customary title to cultivate, or in o<strong>the</strong>r ways<br />

19 Common land use purposes are: industrial, residential or agricultural purpose.<br />

34


make use <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land in order to keep it. Although <strong>the</strong> customary title is issued without<br />

limitation in time, this restriction is meant to avoid people from trying to grab land for<br />

speculative purposes. O<strong>the</strong>r restrictions concerning land use, building permits and<br />

allowances in urban areas are similar to <strong>the</strong> corresponding limitations under a freehold<br />

tenure.<br />

<strong>Land</strong> value<br />

Before <strong>the</strong> passing <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new land legislation in 1999, land in itself was formally not<br />

considered to have any saleable value. In <strong>the</strong>ory, bare land was not allowed to be sold,<br />

only given away for free. The existence <strong>of</strong> a land market was suppressed, although it<br />

existed informally as a result <strong>of</strong> increasing land scarcity in some areas. (Interview,<br />

Kironde) As explained in chapter 2.2 and 2.4, <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> land value have historical as<br />

well as ideological roots. Historically, land has been an abundant resource in Africa,<br />

whereas <strong>the</strong>re have been scarcity <strong>of</strong> labour force. Abundance <strong>of</strong> land and shifting<br />

cultivation has implied that ownership has never been any relevant issue. It was far easier<br />

and more efficient to just move to next plot when <strong>the</strong> field started to show signs <strong>of</strong><br />

malnutrition. What really mattered was <strong>the</strong> right to <strong>the</strong> fruits <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> labour. (van den<br />

Brink, 2003:5f) The valuable property was <strong>the</strong> harvest, ra<strong>the</strong>r than in <strong>the</strong> land itself. This<br />

approach partly explains <strong>the</strong> total misunderstanding between <strong>the</strong> first settlers, bargaining<br />

to buy land, and <strong>the</strong> tribal chiefs, considering land being a gift from God, not able to be<br />

possessed. Also many modern land conflicts originate in <strong>the</strong> different views on<br />

ownership. For example claim villagers whom trespass and cultivate <strong>the</strong> unused<br />

periphery areas <strong>of</strong> huge alienated estates, <strong>the</strong>ir customary right to use <strong>the</strong> land<br />

temporarily, and do not see <strong>the</strong> problem with doing so. (Commission report, 1994:62)<br />

Type <strong>of</strong> rights Freehold Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy<br />

1) Enter and pass through Always Always<br />

2) Make use <strong>of</strong> what naturally grows<br />

or can be found on <strong>the</strong> ground<br />

Normally, if not within<br />

protected areas<br />

Normally, if not protected<br />

areas<br />

3) Till <strong>the</strong> land, pr<strong>of</strong>it from its yield Always Depending on purpose<br />

4) Right to build Yes (Permit required) Sometimes (Permit required)<br />

5) Expel outsiders Normally (x) Normally<br />

6) Fence in Normally Normally<br />

7) Let <strong>the</strong> property be inherited Always Yes (considering time frame)<br />

8) Mortgage <strong>the</strong> property Always Yes<br />

9) Sub-lease Always Yes<br />

10) Sell <strong>the</strong> property Yes Yes (considering time frame)<br />

11) Make full use <strong>of</strong> minerals Possible (country specific) Possible (country specific)<br />

x) The freedom <strong>of</strong> roaming encroaches in some countries on <strong>the</strong> right to expel outsiders also from privately owned property.<br />

Figure 3.5<br />

The figure aims to compare <strong>the</strong> two different tenure forms by putting <strong>the</strong>m side by side to study how <strong>the</strong>y<br />

relate to <strong>the</strong> discussed types <strong>of</strong> rights.<br />

35


Fees and taxes<br />

The issuing <strong>of</strong> a certificate <strong>of</strong> a customary right <strong>of</strong> occupancy in <strong>the</strong> villages requires an<br />

initial small fee to cover <strong>the</strong> administrative costs. Thereafter, <strong>the</strong> payment <strong>of</strong> a yearly land<br />

rent to <strong>the</strong> village is required <strong>of</strong> those that have acquired a certificate. Acquiring formal<br />

certificates is voluntary. Without a certificate it is not possible to mortgage <strong>the</strong> land, but<br />

land-holders without certificates will, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, not be required to pay any land<br />

rent. (Interview, Sichone)<br />

Dispositions<br />

What normally distinguish leaseholds from freeholds, are <strong>the</strong> weaker rights concerning<br />

sub-lease, sale or inheritance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> property. A property held under leasehold tenure is<br />

normally not possible to mortgage. The land acts are in this matter introducing an<br />

empowered type <strong>of</strong> leasehold, providing for such rights within <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy<br />

system.<br />

Security <strong>of</strong> tenure<br />

The new land legislation claims to guarantee <strong>the</strong> same land security to customary landholders,<br />

regardless whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y have chosen to register <strong>the</strong>ir rights to land, or not. The<br />

acts provide for legal right to compensation for encroachments on anyone’s land rights.<br />

But, still <strong>the</strong>re exist some debated ambiguous statements under <strong>the</strong> issue <strong>of</strong> land security<br />

in <strong>the</strong> land acts. (See chapter 7.2)<br />

Summary<br />

The Tanzanian right <strong>of</strong> occupancy is still built on a usufruct-type <strong>of</strong> land holding, but its<br />

content has through <strong>the</strong> new land legislation come to considerably approach <strong>the</strong> freehold.<br />

From having previously been limited to mainly customary practises <strong>of</strong> land holding, <strong>the</strong><br />

land acts promises increased security <strong>of</strong> tenure, increased possibilities for dispositions<br />

including inheritance, sub-leasing, selling and mortgaging <strong>the</strong> property. 20<br />

20 As <strong>the</strong> granted right <strong>of</strong> occupancy is limited in time, it is not yet fully clear how to handle and assess <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> dispositional<br />

rights, when approaching expiration <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy. (Interview, Kironde)<br />

36


4. <strong>Land</strong>-political challenges<br />

“Given <strong>the</strong> crucial importance <strong>of</strong> land to <strong>the</strong> economies <strong>of</strong> East Africa, it is obvious that<br />

ownership, access and use <strong>of</strong> land is one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> key factors in economic policy<br />

formulation -and in poverty alleviation.“ (Palmer, 1997)<br />

Introduction<br />

In <strong>the</strong> present era <strong>of</strong> globalisation and liberalisation, <strong>the</strong> different African systems <strong>of</strong><br />

customary land tenure are more than ever put under pressure. In an article from 1998,<br />

Robin Palmer 21 pertinently catches some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> main tribulations concerning land tenure<br />

in Africa, “Access to land by <strong>the</strong> poor in many parts <strong>of</strong> Africa is currently seriously<br />

threatened by a combination <strong>of</strong> privatisation and unrestricted market forces; by<br />

governments desperately seeking foreign investment... and by greed and corruption by<br />

<strong>the</strong> rich and powerful.“<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> market-oriented system <strong>of</strong> private land ownership appears favourable in<br />

many ways, it is questionable whe<strong>the</strong>r its potentials are applicable in rural Africa.<br />

Acknowledging <strong>the</strong> fact that a large majority <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rural population have a very low<br />

income, and that access to land <strong>the</strong>refore plays a crucial role in <strong>the</strong> social security system<br />

(Palmer, 1997), essential parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> market-oriented system turns out totally different in<br />

<strong>the</strong> African setting than in western societies.<br />

The intention <strong>of</strong> this chapter is to outline some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> more debated issues related to land<br />

in Africa, and which roots are to be found in <strong>the</strong> deviating views on land. It will be shown<br />

that cultural differences, as well as discrepancies in <strong>the</strong> institutional structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

society, are <strong>of</strong> critical importance. We will also briefly feature <strong>the</strong> World Bank as it is<br />

globally <strong>the</strong> single most influential actor in development politics. The Bank’s recent shift<br />

<strong>of</strong> approach is acknowledged, from having previously focussed on individual titling<br />

alone, to having become increasingly willing to find more diversified and contextually<br />

adapted solutions.<br />

The importance <strong>of</strong> access to land<br />

The importance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> agricultural sector as employer and provider <strong>of</strong> livelihood in<br />

western societies has diminished throughout <strong>the</strong> twentieth century, to become <strong>the</strong><br />

marginal actor in <strong>the</strong> national economy it is today. In spite <strong>of</strong> this development, farming<br />

itself has gone through an industrialisation during <strong>the</strong> last fifty years that has enabled a<br />

significant increase in production. Consequently, access to fertile land for individuals in<br />

<strong>the</strong>se societies, is nei<strong>the</strong>r a question <strong>of</strong> survival nor <strong>of</strong> social welfare. Besides this, <strong>the</strong><br />

domestic demand for food is thanks to <strong>the</strong> weak population growth, only increasing<br />

slowly. The current African situation is generally <strong>the</strong> opposite. Firstly, <strong>the</strong> majority <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

population in most African countries is still living in <strong>the</strong> countryside, earning its<br />

livelihood from husbandry. 22<br />

21 Robin Palmer was at that time <strong>Land</strong> Policy Adviser at Oxfam GB<br />

22 Tanzania, being one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> least urbanised African countries, had in <strong>the</strong> 1988 census a rural population <strong>of</strong> 88 percent. (Fitzpatrick,<br />

2002:26)<br />

37


Secondly, <strong>the</strong> cultivation techniques used by <strong>the</strong> small-holders are remarkably simple and<br />

lowly mechanised. It is not lack <strong>of</strong> knowledge in using irrigation, fertilisers or highproducing<br />

planting seed that is <strong>the</strong> problem, but <strong>the</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> resources and organisation to<br />

get hold <strong>of</strong> and benefit from it. (Interview, Mbuzi) When it comes to initiatives for<br />

change, tradition and social pressure also seem to play a hampering role. It takes a lot <strong>of</strong><br />

courage to dare to do things differently than <strong>the</strong> inherited tradition and <strong>the</strong> way all <strong>the</strong><br />

neighbours hold to be right. Consequently, <strong>the</strong> family farm continues to be <strong>the</strong> primary<br />

occupation in rural Africa, demanding huge amount <strong>of</strong> labour. This apparent<br />

ineffectiveness is one side <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> coin; <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r side is that <strong>the</strong> simple methods actually<br />

provide both employment and affordable food for <strong>the</strong> millions <strong>of</strong> people living in <strong>the</strong><br />

African countryside.<br />

A third difference is <strong>the</strong> weak trade and industry sector, which is not as widely spread in<br />

Africa as in for example western or Asian societies. In <strong>the</strong> countryside, jobs are rarely<br />

found outside <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> agricultural sector. (Commission report, 1994:119), (Palmer, 2004)<br />

The possibility to learn skills beside traditional farming or handicraft is reduced, which<br />

makes <strong>the</strong> possibility to change occupation, and find alternative jobs, ra<strong>the</strong>r unlikely.<br />

Fourthly, <strong>the</strong> steady population growth puts additional pressure on <strong>the</strong> availability <strong>of</strong><br />

fertile land. The upcoming land scarcity puts limitations on <strong>the</strong> possibilities to produce<br />

enough food, but also on <strong>the</strong> provision <strong>of</strong> residence and occupation, whereas in western<br />

societies, individually owned land is mainly held for residential purposes. (Quan, 2002)<br />

This means that nei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> general source <strong>of</strong> income, nor <strong>the</strong> social security system is<br />

dependent on access to land. Ano<strong>the</strong>r striking difference is that <strong>the</strong> general financial<br />

situation has been more stable and reliable in western societies. (Palmer, 2004)<br />

Food production and employment<br />

Finding ways to increase <strong>the</strong> national food production, aiming at eventually becoming<br />

self-supporting, has for decades been an unreachable goal for most African nations. But,<br />

despite an increasing population, single nations have managed to reach <strong>the</strong> goals. Among<br />

<strong>the</strong>se nations, properly run large-scale commercial farms have shown to be <strong>the</strong> most<br />

successful way to produce large quantities <strong>of</strong> food (Nevin, 2004:28f), and, not least<br />

important, to establish and succeed with an efficient chain <strong>of</strong> transport and distribution <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> farm produce. For different reasons, it has shown to be privately owned farms, instead<br />

<strong>of</strong> state owned or communally run farms that in <strong>the</strong> long run have accomplished <strong>the</strong> best<br />

result. (Shaw, 2003:77f) It seems like <strong>the</strong>y have managed <strong>the</strong> best to ga<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> financial<br />

strength to invest in machinery, and to continuously improve and expand <strong>the</strong> farm. The<br />

structure <strong>of</strong> private ownership has also created an incentive to properly manage and well<br />

look after <strong>the</strong> capital assets. Although this efficient management is <strong>of</strong>ten <strong>the</strong> case, it is not<br />

an evident result <strong>of</strong> privately held estates. The land commission refers to complaints<br />

against several private estates holding abundant tracts <strong>of</strong> land in <strong>the</strong> midst <strong>of</strong> areas <strong>of</strong> land<br />

scarcity. These are private estates where <strong>the</strong> vast areas <strong>of</strong> land are being cultivated only to<br />

a small extent. (Commission report, 1994:62)<br />

Facilitating <strong>the</strong> establishment <strong>of</strong> large-scale commercial farms, for example through <strong>the</strong><br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> a market oriented land-ownership system, would affect <strong>the</strong> rural<br />

development in two ways. On <strong>the</strong> one hand, large portions <strong>of</strong> fertile land would be shifted<br />

from extensively run subsistence farming with minimal inputs, to large-scale intensive<br />

38


farming with enough resources to increase <strong>the</strong> output many times. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand,<br />

land being bought up and ga<strong>the</strong>red in only a few hands would lead to that many smallholders<br />

selling <strong>the</strong>ir land, would also find <strong>the</strong>m selling <strong>the</strong>ir occupation and <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

guarantee for food on <strong>the</strong> table. (Palmer, 1997) This contradiction is fundamentally about<br />

<strong>the</strong> different views <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> core values <strong>of</strong> development, i.e. <strong>the</strong> growth aspect against <strong>the</strong><br />

poverty-reduction aspect. (Mweta, 2004:5) The social implications <strong>of</strong> land holding in<br />

Africa are <strong>of</strong> course much more diverse than this simple example. This fact makes <strong>the</strong><br />

African situation differ markedly from <strong>the</strong> western situation, and needs <strong>the</strong>refore to be<br />

seriously considered.<br />

Differing prerequisites<br />

In <strong>the</strong> western society financial systems connected to a land market have developed<br />

throughout centuries and have, thus, gained stability both as recognised systems and<br />

concerning <strong>the</strong> required legal, financial and administrational infrastructure. In <strong>the</strong> daily<br />

selling and buying <strong>of</strong> property, information is available and openly handled; laws and<br />

regulations are closely followed, and <strong>the</strong> trade is taken place freely and between ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

equal and financially stable parts. Undoubtedly, <strong>the</strong> financial system enabling mortgaging<br />

<strong>of</strong> land has been a critical factor in <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economies <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> western society. In<br />

order to promote <strong>the</strong> required security, this system has had to be firmly managed, strictly<br />

policed and guaranteed by <strong>the</strong> state through detailed and accurately held registers.<br />

Intending to worldwide spread <strong>the</strong> advantages <strong>of</strong> domestic land markets, <strong>the</strong> World Bank<br />

has, in <strong>the</strong>ir contacts with, and advice to developing countries, strongly advocated <strong>the</strong><br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> land-tenure systems built on individualisation and titling <strong>of</strong> property. This<br />

has been done in spite <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> fact that not only <strong>the</strong> construction <strong>of</strong>, but also <strong>the</strong> required<br />

close management <strong>of</strong> such systems are tremendously costly. Even if <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong> such a system would be largely donor funded, experience show that <strong>the</strong> incomes from<br />

taxes and fees in developing countries are even insufficient to finance <strong>the</strong> continuous<br />

management <strong>of</strong> land-register systems<br />

Tremendous financial gaps<br />

The purchasing power in Africa is extremely unevenly distributed. Generally speaking,<br />

large parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rural population is, if not outright poor <strong>the</strong>n counting <strong>the</strong>ir land, <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

simple house, some cooking and farming utensils and maybe a few domestic animals as<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir only possessions. The average liquidity is low. Among <strong>the</strong> urban middle class <strong>the</strong><br />

purchasing power is significantly higher. Then, <strong>the</strong>re is <strong>the</strong> wealthy clique <strong>of</strong> privileged<br />

people, <strong>of</strong>ten with personal contacts within influential political and financial spheres.<br />

With this in mind, it is easy to realise that <strong>the</strong> financial gap is immense between <strong>the</strong> rural<br />

population and prospective buyers <strong>of</strong> land. Even though <strong>the</strong> prospective buyers may not<br />

be wealthier than <strong>the</strong> urban middle class, <strong>the</strong>ir purchasing power is far beyond that <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

average small holder. The immense income gaps in a society, turns <strong>the</strong> land market into<br />

something that increases <strong>the</strong> inequality. A purchase-price that would be an exorbitant<br />

sum <strong>of</strong> money for <strong>the</strong> peasant means almost nothing to <strong>the</strong> wealthy.<br />

39


Both in a market-oriented system, as in a customary, land is used to provide wealth and<br />

power. Palmer (1998) argues that “<strong>Land</strong> will always be a hugely controversial and<br />

contentious issue, since it is primarily about power and it involves unequal struggles<br />

between vested interests and <strong>the</strong> weak“. For <strong>the</strong> weak, access to land is a matter <strong>of</strong><br />

survival, whereas for <strong>the</strong> wealthy it is sometimes merely a matter <strong>of</strong> investment, or even<br />

financial speculation.<br />

<strong>Land</strong> speculation and corruption<br />

Ano<strong>the</strong>r difference compared to western societies, concerns <strong>the</strong> rules and regulations<br />

circumscribing undesirable behaviours. There is no use having detailed regulations if<br />

<strong>the</strong>re is no power behind to enforce <strong>the</strong>m. To open up for a free market, without<br />

allocating resources to check up on how <strong>the</strong> regulations are complied with, will pave for<br />

that weaknesses in <strong>the</strong> system will be exploited. This may end up in a situation where<br />

investors buy up land entirely for speculative purposes. To <strong>the</strong>m land is nothing but a<br />

financial investment, a commodity from which to pr<strong>of</strong>it when <strong>the</strong>y sell it a few years<br />

later.<br />

Due to <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> land, some politicians and <strong>of</strong>ficials within <strong>the</strong> governmental<br />

institutions apparently practice nepotism and similar forms <strong>of</strong> corruption. Unfortunately,<br />

corruption has been able to flourish thanks to <strong>the</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> transparency and effective<br />

accountability mechanisms in <strong>the</strong> administrational systems. (Commission report,<br />

1994:27) As a result <strong>of</strong> this, villagers and pastoralists have been chased away from land<br />

<strong>the</strong>y have long been occupying based on customary rights. But corruption occurs also at<br />

<strong>the</strong> local level. Local leaders at clan and village level have sometimes taken <strong>the</strong><br />

opportunity to enrich <strong>the</strong>mselves by secretly signing contracts selling <strong>of</strong>f land from <strong>the</strong><br />

village commons. (Commission report, 1994, pp.30, 100)<br />

Transparency and participation<br />

It needs to be emphasised that individual titling systems in western societies are based on<br />

long traditions <strong>of</strong> strong individual property rights, whereas in Africa, a much more<br />

corporate view <strong>of</strong> property rights has prevailed. Seeking to introduce an individual land<br />

tenure system in Africa based on <strong>the</strong> western presumptions, would inevitably come to<br />

face real obstacles and bear insurmountable costs, whereas <strong>the</strong> existing customary<br />

systems bears almost no costs at all.<br />

Individual titling is dependent on <strong>the</strong> keeping <strong>of</strong> accurate registers, requiring being<br />

continuously up-dated. In order to manage titling procedures and registers, institutions<br />

have to be built up, guaranteeing <strong>the</strong> same standard all over <strong>the</strong> country. A successful<br />

<strong>implementation</strong> <strong>of</strong> land reforms requires <strong>the</strong> acceptance and support from <strong>the</strong> rural<br />

population. In order to achieve this, <strong>the</strong> decision-making has to be as participatory and<br />

decentralised as possible. (Carney & Boyd, 1999) Experiences from Kenya show that<br />

governmental attempts to abolish indigenous land tenure, replacing it with statutory<br />

tenure, tend to fail. The customary systems have proved to be resilient, and have<br />

continued to be used parallel with <strong>the</strong> statutory system. The updating <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial<br />

registers has <strong>the</strong>n become imperfect, leading to that <strong>the</strong>y soon fail to reflect <strong>the</strong> factual<br />

reality, and have eventually turned useless. (Palmer, 2000(2)), (Commission report,<br />

1994:116f)<br />

40


Certainty and security <strong>of</strong> tenure<br />

<strong>Land</strong> security is essentially about recognizing legitimate evidence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> right to claim<br />

and make use <strong>of</strong> land. Whe<strong>the</strong>r it concerns <strong>the</strong> right to use a plot for housing and<br />

agricultural purpose, or <strong>the</strong> right to let <strong>the</strong> cattle roam over vast areas in a traditional,<br />

pastoral manner, <strong>the</strong>se rights need to be acknowledged and legally protected. According<br />

to <strong>the</strong> customary practise, management <strong>of</strong> land is based on oral tradition, ra<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

written documents. This means that knowledge about land-holding principles, succession,<br />

borders and different sub-locative rights, is to be found exclusively in <strong>the</strong> minds <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

elders, <strong>the</strong> traditional leadership. When confronted with <strong>the</strong> large scale investments <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

global economy, <strong>the</strong> whole concept <strong>of</strong> customary practise becomes threatened. In order to<br />

avoid <strong>the</strong> course <strong>of</strong> event from <strong>the</strong> 19th century imperialistic superiority to be repeated,<br />

not only <strong>the</strong> vulnerable rights <strong>of</strong> pastoralists need protection, but all kinds <strong>of</strong> customary<br />

rights have to be legally secured,<br />

The influence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> World Bank and international politics<br />

The World Bank policy on land tenure was <strong>of</strong>ficially formulated through <strong>the</strong> publication<br />

<strong>Land</strong> Reform in 1974. Well before that, <strong>the</strong> World Bank had firmly promoted formal land<br />

titling at <strong>the</strong> intended expense <strong>of</strong> traditional tenure regimes. Until <strong>the</strong> middle <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

1990s, it pushed towards a western-style modernisation, with a strong belief in technical<br />

solutions. These were materialised through innumerable construction projects and redistributive<br />

land reforms. The creation <strong>of</strong> a national credit market was seen as <strong>the</strong><br />

universally prevailing objective; <strong>the</strong> model <strong>of</strong> individual ownership to land a universal<br />

good and a precondition for agricultural growth and modern development. Needless to<br />

say small-scale farming, village commons and a pastoral lifestyle were considered being<br />

hopelessly backward.<br />

The land reforms being implemented through World Bank-funded development projects<br />

worldwide followed <strong>the</strong> ITR-principle. This emphasised individualisation <strong>of</strong> ownership,<br />

followed by titling <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> individualised property and finally, registration <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> formal<br />

document <strong>of</strong> ownership. (Commission report, 1994, chapter 12) Whe<strong>the</strong>r in Latin<br />

America, in South-East Asia or in Africa, <strong>the</strong> same concept was used with very little<br />

respect to existing cultural differences among <strong>the</strong> countries <strong>the</strong>mselves, or in relation to<br />

<strong>the</strong> preconditions from which <strong>the</strong> ITR-principles originates, i.e. <strong>the</strong> western society.<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> land titling programme in Thailand in <strong>the</strong> 1980s initially was regarded a<br />

success, <strong>the</strong> World Bank has since met strong critique for its keeping on to an out-dated<br />

development strategy. (Palmer, 2000:2) Even in <strong>the</strong> 1990s, <strong>the</strong> World Bank’s promotion<br />

<strong>of</strong> economic growth, solely based on free-market principles, lead to that land was treated<br />

as a commodity like any o<strong>the</strong>r (Quan, 2003) The assumption was that <strong>the</strong> market<br />

mechanisms automatically would allocate land to <strong>the</strong> most effective user, which would<br />

benefit <strong>the</strong> national productivity, as well as rural employment et cetera. But, while <strong>the</strong><br />

launched reforms turned out to liberate land mainly for <strong>the</strong> wealthy, <strong>the</strong> World Bank<br />

failed to intervene into inherent national structural inequalities in order to protect <strong>the</strong><br />

social rights and livelihood opportunities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land-dependent peasants and <strong>the</strong> poor.<br />

World Bank supported titling programmes in Russia and Eastern Europe, for example,<br />

instead created land-grabbing opportunities for predatory elites. (Quan, 2003)<br />

41


Throughout <strong>the</strong> 1990s, <strong>the</strong> World Bank gradually reconsidered and reassessed its<br />

position. This process has led to <strong>the</strong> publication in 2003 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Policy Research Report,<br />

PRR (Deininger, 2003). The new document indicates a remarkable alteration in <strong>the</strong> view<br />

<strong>of</strong> land issues. Although <strong>the</strong> report focuses on property rights from an economic point <strong>of</strong><br />

view, emphasising <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> secure rights to economic growth, <strong>the</strong> significance<br />

<strong>of</strong> social values <strong>of</strong> land rights are recognised as well. Now, collective and communal<br />

rights are seen as important elements <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rural society, contributing to social and<br />

environmental perseverance. Also, social aspects, such as <strong>the</strong> responsibility to protect <strong>the</strong><br />

land rights <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor and vulnerable, have been acknowledged. In addition, <strong>the</strong> new<br />

policy admits that rental markets can be seen as infinitely more useful in enabling access<br />

to land than are sales markets. Probably <strong>the</strong> most remarkable reconsideration is <strong>the</strong><br />

statement that land rights do not necessarily have to be secured through a formal titling<br />

process. Instead it may sometimes be recommendable to make use <strong>of</strong> more accessible and<br />

affordable processes, which are based in already existing local institutions. (Quan, 2003)<br />

Summary<br />

Although Tanzania and o<strong>the</strong>r African nations would strongly benefit from a land-tenure<br />

system that enables farmers to mortgage <strong>the</strong> land <strong>the</strong>y use, not one attempt to introduce a<br />

western-influenced land-tenure system in <strong>the</strong> continent have succeeded. <strong>Land</strong> in Africa is<br />

for several reasons not able to be treated like any o<strong>the</strong>r tradable commodity, and any<br />

comparison with <strong>the</strong> western society will inevitably have to recognise <strong>the</strong> immense<br />

difference in financial, legal and demographical prerequisites. It seems like even <strong>the</strong><br />

World Bank has finally modulated its opinion, after decades <strong>of</strong> inflexible advocacy <strong>of</strong><br />

individualisation and titling as <strong>the</strong> only way towards growth and development.<br />

42


5. The new land legislation<br />

5.1 Presenting <strong>the</strong> land acts<br />

Introduction<br />

This central chapter provides an orientation in <strong>the</strong> fundamentals <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new land<br />

legislation. A brief insight is given into <strong>the</strong> management structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village areas, as<br />

well as into <strong>the</strong> arrangements for <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>.<br />

Background<br />

In 1977, <strong>the</strong> final, compulsory phase <strong>of</strong> resettlement under <strong>the</strong> villagisation campaigns<br />

was stopped. (Chaula, 2004:26) Altoge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> villagisation affected more than 7500 new<br />

or completely restructured villages. As <strong>the</strong> reform turned out to be nei<strong>the</strong>r thoroughly<br />

planned, nor legally established, <strong>the</strong> end result was a terrible confusion in land tenure and<br />

land management. (Chaula, 2004:26), (Fitzpatrick, 2002:14), (Friis-Hansen, 1986:20ff)<br />

It did not last long until <strong>the</strong> public confidence in <strong>the</strong> legal framework was broken down<br />

and in <strong>the</strong> mid-80s <strong>the</strong> situation desperately called for any kind <strong>of</strong> land law reform.<br />

Complaints and land conflicts grew in number and <strong>the</strong> increased awareness <strong>of</strong> land value<br />

lead to <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> informal land markets. Also, <strong>the</strong> negative consequences <strong>of</strong><br />

governmental investment promotion policies elucidated a need for increased land tenure<br />

security for customary land holding. (Interview, Mutakyamilwa) In 1985, Julius Nyerere<br />

resigned from <strong>the</strong> presidency and was succeeded by <strong>the</strong> former vice president, Ali Hassan<br />

Mwinyi. In 1989, <strong>the</strong> policy-making process was started, aspiring at elaborating new land<br />

legislation. The process included numerous policy drafts, a number <strong>of</strong> commissioned<br />

studies by domestic and international experts, a presidential land commission, and a<br />

national workshop. (Sundet, 2005) After two years <strong>of</strong> intense research and discussion on<br />

matters <strong>of</strong> land tenure, <strong>the</strong> land commission submitted its exhaustive report in November<br />

1992. This crucial document called for <strong>the</strong> formulation <strong>of</strong> a land policy as a backbone for<br />

<strong>the</strong> formulation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> coming legislation. Three years later, in June 1995, <strong>the</strong> National<br />

<strong>Land</strong> Policy was completed. (Zainab, 2004:13) The core <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> policy was developed in<br />

accordance with <strong>the</strong> recommendations in <strong>the</strong> commission report, suggesting how to deal<br />

with <strong>the</strong> serious land problems and <strong>the</strong> numerous land-disputes. Having no legal force in<br />

land matters, <strong>the</strong> National <strong>Land</strong> Policy was only intended to form <strong>the</strong> foundation, on<br />

which <strong>the</strong> new land legislation was to be drafted.<br />

The legislation<br />

Toge<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> and <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>, form <strong>the</strong> basic new land law for <strong>the</strong><br />

mainland <strong>of</strong> Tanzania. When passed in <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian parliament in 1999, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong><br />

Ordinance <strong>of</strong> 1923 was repealed, and <strong>the</strong> former reliance on English law was finally<br />

broken. (Wily, 2003:14) The acts simultaneously repealed ano<strong>the</strong>r ten existing laws, and<br />

six o<strong>the</strong>rs were amended. (Palmer, 1999)<br />

On <strong>the</strong> positive, <strong>the</strong> acts clarify many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> previously grey areas in <strong>the</strong> large body <strong>of</strong><br />

legislation that <strong>the</strong>y replace. They also define in law many procedures which had<br />

previously only been set down through administrative directives. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand,<br />

Sundet argues, <strong>the</strong> acts replicates many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> fundamental problems <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> system it<br />

43


eplaces by continuing to give considerable scope for discretion and administrative<br />

directives. (Sundet, 2005)<br />

The structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land acts<br />

Originally, <strong>the</strong> two land laws were drafted as one whole land legislation, but got split up<br />

because <strong>of</strong> its bulkiness. With this in mind, it is easy to realise that <strong>the</strong> laws are closely<br />

related, repeatedly referring to one ano<strong>the</strong>r. The <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> should be seen as <strong>the</strong> chief<br />

legislation among <strong>the</strong> two, covering fundamental principles, such as classifications <strong>of</strong><br />

land and definition <strong>of</strong> certain terms used in <strong>the</strong> acts. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, issues <strong>of</strong> mortgage as<br />

well as ownership between husband and wife are described only in <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>,<br />

although it is relevant for <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> as well. O<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong>se mutual issues,<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> covers land rights in general land, i.e. outside villages or reserved areas.<br />

This includes all urban areas. The <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, deals strictly with<br />

land within village areas. This includes <strong>the</strong> locally rooted systems for management and<br />

administration <strong>of</strong> village land, as well as land dispute settlement on village level.<br />

In addition to <strong>the</strong> acts, a few o<strong>the</strong>r laws touch <strong>the</strong> issue <strong>of</strong> village land: <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong><br />

Acquisition <strong>Act</strong> 1967, regulates in which way <strong>the</strong> state are allowed to acquire private<br />

land, including land held by villagers; <strong>the</strong> Courts (<strong>Land</strong> Dispute Settlements) <strong>Act</strong> 2002<br />

gives guidance on land dispute resolution; and <strong>the</strong> Forest <strong>Act</strong> 2002 enables villagers to<br />

declare <strong>the</strong>ir own village forest reserves on land within <strong>the</strong> village area. On top <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Local Government (District Authorities) <strong>Act</strong> 1982 is crucial, while it empowers<br />

village governments to design approved bye-laws in accordance with <strong>the</strong>ir position as<br />

land managers.<br />

5.1.1 <strong>Land</strong> categories<br />

The land acts separate land in three categories; general land, village land and reserved<br />

land. Transfer <strong>of</strong> portions <strong>of</strong> land between <strong>the</strong>se categories is possible following stated<br />

regulations (<strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> 1999: section 4), (<strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> 1999: sections 4-5).<br />

Additional, hazardous land is described (LA 1999: s.7), (VLA 1999: s.6) as portions <strong>of</strong><br />

land within <strong>the</strong> three categories, being protected mainly for environmental reasons, or to<br />

protect people from danger. The law exemplifies hazardous land by mentioning<br />

mangrove swamps and coral reefs, wetlands and <strong>of</strong>fshore islands, as well as land on steep<br />

slopes or river banks, which are likely to be exposed to erosion if not protected.<br />

General <strong>Land</strong><br />

By definition, general land is described as consisting <strong>of</strong> all land which is nei<strong>the</strong>r village<br />

land nor reserved land. (LA 1999: s.2) All urban areas fall under this section, except areas<br />

that are covered by laws constituting reserved land (See below), or that are considered<br />

hazard land. General land is governed by <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> and, hence, under <strong>the</strong> control and<br />

jurisdiction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> commissioner for lands. This ministerial key person has delegated<br />

much <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> powers to <strong>the</strong> district councils and district land <strong>of</strong>ficers in <strong>the</strong> 141 districts.<br />

The definition <strong>of</strong> general land in <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> is supplemented by <strong>the</strong> somewhat obscure<br />

statement, “General land… includes unoccupied village land.”<br />

The passage is debatable in itself, as is also <strong>the</strong> fact that it is left out in <strong>the</strong> corresponding<br />

definition in <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>. (Shivji, 1999(1)), (Wily, 2003:10) It unveils one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

ambiguities for which <strong>the</strong> acts have received much critique. (Sundet, 2005)<br />

44


<strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong><br />

<strong>Village</strong> land is declared as being <strong>the</strong> land falling under <strong>the</strong> jurisdiction and management<br />

<strong>of</strong> a registered village. As Tanzania consists <strong>of</strong> a vast countryside with only a few urban<br />

areas, most land in <strong>the</strong> country is village land. In order to fulfil <strong>the</strong> provisions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> acts,<br />

<strong>the</strong> village first has to acquire a certificate <strong>of</strong> village land. The certification procedure<br />

includes compulsory agreement upon <strong>the</strong> perimeter borders among neighbouring villages.<br />

When unambiguity is reached and <strong>the</strong> border is properly demarcated, a formal certificate<br />

<strong>of</strong> village land is issued in <strong>the</strong> name <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> president, and registered in <strong>the</strong> National<br />

Register <strong>of</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong>. (VLA 1999: s.7), (Wily, 2003:25ff)<br />

Each village is required to define three land-use categories within its own borders:<br />

1) communal village land, 2) individual and family land, 3) reserved land.<br />

(VLA 1999: s.12) Reserved land in this context is to be understood as land set aside for<br />

future individual or communal use, and needs to be distinguished from <strong>the</strong> national land<br />

category, ”reserved land”, mentioned above. (Wily, 2003:28)<br />

Reserved <strong>Land</strong><br />

Finally, reserved land is declared as land being reserved and governed for purposes<br />

subject to nine listed laws. (LA 1999: s.6) Here, environmental protection areas, such as<br />

national parks, forest reserves and wildlife reserves, including marine parks are ga<strong>the</strong>red,<br />

but also areas intended and set aside for spatial planning and future infrastructure<br />

development. (Wily, 2003:23)<br />

<strong>Land</strong> ownership<br />

One <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> main pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new legislation is <strong>the</strong> attempt to legally secure customary<br />

land rights. Having previously been vaguely defined as deemed rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy,<br />

according to <strong>the</strong> 1928 amendment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> Ordinance, customary land rights are now<br />

given equal status to granted rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy. For <strong>the</strong> first time, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong><br />

provides for <strong>the</strong> possibility to acquire written and registered documentation <strong>of</strong> customary<br />

land rights. (Wily, 2003:22) A title in village land is called a Customary Right <strong>of</strong><br />

Occupancy, whereas it in general land is called a Granted Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy. Within<br />

reserved land, both customary rights and granted rights can be issued, depending on <strong>the</strong><br />

character and purpose <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> reservation. Rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy within Tanzania are<br />

primarily issued to Tanzanian citizens or groups <strong>of</strong> citizens. Organisations, associations<br />

or companies interested in acquiring land are required to show that <strong>the</strong> majority <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

shareholders are Tanzanian citizens. The only legal exception from <strong>the</strong> prohibition <strong>of</strong><br />

allocating land to foreign companies or associations is for purposes <strong>of</strong> investment in<br />

accordance with <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian Investment <strong>Act</strong>, 1977. (LA 1999: s.19) Allocation <strong>of</strong><br />

village land is primarily given to residents in <strong>the</strong> village. Also non-resident persons and<br />

non-village organisations may apply for a land right, but will <strong>the</strong>n be submitted to certain<br />

conditions. (VLA 1999: s.22f), (Wily, 2003:36f)<br />

45


5.1.2 <strong>Land</strong> titles according to <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong><br />

Granted Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy (LA 1999: part V, VI)<br />

In areas outside <strong>of</strong> village land, granted rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy can be held by a single<br />

person, or a group <strong>of</strong> people, a company or an association. Granted rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy<br />

are mainly issued within urban areas, but can also be issued for general land in rural<br />

contexts, or within areas <strong>of</strong> reserved land. A significant difference between customary<br />

titles and granted titles is that <strong>the</strong> latter is always limited in time, having a maximum<br />

admittance <strong>of</strong> 99 years. According to <strong>the</strong> former directives, residential developments<br />

were allowed terms <strong>of</strong> 33 years, whereas commercial property and farms were allowed 66<br />

years, and finally, 99 years were intended mainly for agricultural purposes. (Ndjovu,<br />

2003:71)<br />

5.1.3 <strong>Land</strong> titles according to <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong><br />

Customary Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy (VLA, s.18f, s.23)<br />

Customary rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy arise when villagers are allotted, or in o<strong>the</strong>r ways get hold<br />

<strong>of</strong> land in accordance with <strong>the</strong> customary law 23 applicable in <strong>the</strong> area. Full customary<br />

rights exist equally, regardless whe<strong>the</strong>r written certificates are being issued, or not. (Wily,<br />

2003:22) In order to formally register someone’s interest in land, <strong>the</strong> land has to be<br />

adjudicated. This means to thoroughly investigate and confirm <strong>the</strong> tenancy <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> plot, as<br />

belonging to <strong>the</strong> claimant. The law does not require <strong>the</strong> borders to be surveyed, measured<br />

or mapped; instead a written description, or a simple sketch explaining <strong>the</strong> area with <strong>the</strong><br />

help <strong>of</strong> natural existing items, is enough to provide legal validity. (Wily, 2003:26)<br />

Customary rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy are, contrary to granted rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy, without limit<br />

in time.<br />

The legislation grants land security and legal recognition <strong>of</strong> tenancy to every land-holder<br />

regardless <strong>of</strong> formal certification. (LA 1999: s.4(3)) It is, though, only through <strong>the</strong><br />

holding <strong>of</strong> a registered Certificate <strong>of</strong> Customary Right <strong>of</strong> Occupancy, that <strong>the</strong> landholder<br />

can make factual use <strong>of</strong> all <strong>the</strong> extended potentials that <strong>the</strong> new legislation seeks to<br />

provide.<br />

5.1.4 <strong>Land</strong> management<br />

Decentralisation <strong>of</strong> decision making is an essential issue for <strong>the</strong> new legislation. This is<br />

so for reasons <strong>of</strong> efficiency, as well as to empower rural communities to manage <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

own affairs.<br />

Empowered villages<br />

In <strong>the</strong> earlier legislation, <strong>the</strong> village councils were recognized as owners <strong>of</strong> all land<br />

belonging to <strong>the</strong> village. During <strong>the</strong> post-villagisation period, <strong>the</strong> government confusingly<br />

started to issue 99-year termed <strong>Village</strong> Title Deeds to <strong>the</strong> villages. By that means, <strong>the</strong><br />

village councils were authorised to sub-lease land to village members. Additionally, <strong>the</strong>y<br />

had <strong>the</strong> power to allocate and alienate land without public control, which was sometimes<br />

23 Customary law means any rule, custom, tradition and practice that is established by usage and accepted as having <strong>the</strong> force <strong>of</strong> law<br />

by <strong>the</strong> community. Such customary laws are fully recognised by <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> as long as <strong>the</strong>ir practices do not conflict with<br />

<strong>the</strong> National <strong>Land</strong> Policy, 1995, or in any o<strong>the</strong>r respect works discriminative. (See chapter 2:2)<br />

46


greatly abused. (Wily, 2003:23) Today <strong>the</strong> ownership is withdrawn <strong>the</strong> village as a<br />

corporate body, and returned to <strong>the</strong> central government. Instead <strong>of</strong> acting as trustees on<br />

behalf <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village members, <strong>the</strong> village councils are now being fully accountable<br />

before <strong>the</strong> village assembly, as managers <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village land. (VLA 1999: s.8(12)), (Wily,<br />

2003:23) There exist, though, different opinions whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> villages actually have <strong>the</strong><br />

real power to autonomously manage <strong>the</strong>ir land. Instead <strong>of</strong> being vested in <strong>the</strong> village<br />

assembly, <strong>the</strong> radical title is namely formally vested in <strong>the</strong> president, being delegated to<br />

<strong>the</strong> commissioner for lands. (Shivji, 1999(1)) This ministerial key-person has <strong>the</strong> powers<br />

to decide upon, revoke or intervene into land matters. Some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se rights may also be<br />

delegated to <strong>the</strong> land <strong>of</strong>ficers at district level. (Wily, 2003:34)<br />

<strong>Village</strong> land administration<br />

Administration <strong>of</strong> general land is monitored by <strong>the</strong> commissioner for lands and his<br />

subordinates at district level, whereas for village land, <strong>the</strong> village council has been<br />

authorised to manage and administer land issues. (VLA 1999: s.8) Its role is to set up a<br />

system <strong>of</strong> land administration, which shall be as efficient, transparent and participatory as<br />

possible. (VLA 1999: s.3(1 i )) This setting is meant to promote local involvement from<br />

<strong>the</strong> villagers, and enable adaptation to <strong>the</strong> local customary laws. (VLA 1999: s.20(2))<br />

Being entrusted village land manager, <strong>the</strong> village council is required to establish a proper<br />

village land register, in which to keep record <strong>of</strong> all land being certified in <strong>the</strong> village.<br />

(VLA 1999: s.21) In reality, <strong>the</strong> registration is done by <strong>the</strong> village executive <strong>of</strong>ficer<br />

(VEO), a clerk previously appointed by <strong>the</strong> village council to deal with overall<br />

administrational tasks for <strong>the</strong> village. Nowadays, <strong>the</strong> VEO has got extended<br />

responsibilities. In his part-time function as village land <strong>of</strong>ficer and village registrar, <strong>the</strong><br />

VEO is performing duties at <strong>the</strong> request <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> government, handling <strong>the</strong> village land<br />

register. (VLA 1999: s.21) The VEO is as such, being paid by <strong>the</strong> government, and is<br />

required to have a certain administrative training. (Wily, 2003:29)<br />

In order to investigate boundaries and ownership <strong>of</strong> land, <strong>the</strong> village assembly is to elect<br />

an adjudication committee, which is headed by an adjudication <strong>of</strong>ficer operating as its<br />

secretary. A suitable person for this function is preferably appointed among <strong>the</strong> most<br />

respected persons in <strong>the</strong> village. Secondly, a village land council is to be established as a<br />

kind <strong>of</strong> informal land dispute tribunal, to help villagers resolve <strong>the</strong>ir land disputes on <strong>the</strong><br />

village level. The village land counsil has no formal legal power, o<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> power <strong>of</strong><br />

persuasion and negotiation. (VLA 1999: s.60) If <strong>the</strong> council fails to find acceptable<br />

solutions <strong>the</strong> parts will have to turn to a court <strong>of</strong> law. Finally, in order to ease <strong>the</strong> burden<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village council, a village land committee may be put toge<strong>the</strong>r. Contrary to <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

institutions, <strong>the</strong> village land committee is optional, and can only be given advisory<br />

powers on land issues in <strong>the</strong> village.<br />

Management <strong>of</strong> village land<br />

<strong>Village</strong> land shall be managed in accordance with customary law, and contribute to a<br />

sustainable development in land-use, natural resources and <strong>the</strong> environment. (VLA 1999:<br />

s.8(3)), (Wily, 2003:25ff) Managing village land includes making easily understood land<br />

rules and regulations concerning local land management. (VLA 1999: s.3(1)) The law<br />

also advices <strong>the</strong> village council to prepare management plans for each tract <strong>of</strong> communal<br />

village land. Supported by district land <strong>of</strong>ficers and district wildlife <strong>of</strong>ficers, <strong>the</strong> Forest<br />

47


<strong>Act</strong>, 2002, and <strong>the</strong> new regulations under <strong>the</strong> Wildlife Conservation <strong>Act</strong>, 1974, can help<br />

guiding villages in establishing <strong>Village</strong> Forest Reserves or Wildlife Management Areas<br />

within its village land. (Wily, 2003:28)<br />

<strong>Land</strong> use requirements<br />

The new land legislation brings no change in <strong>the</strong> way holding <strong>of</strong> land rights are<br />

conditional upon <strong>the</strong> factual occupation, and use, <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land. (VLA 1999: s.29) <strong>Land</strong> that<br />

is not occupied or used for at least five years shall be considered abandoned land, and<br />

may be reallocated by <strong>the</strong> village council. (VLA 1999: s.45) Before enforcing such<br />

measures, factors like customary practices, a long period <strong>of</strong> draught, and dependency <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> land by spouses or children shall be considered. (VLA 1999: s.35f)<br />

District level involvement<br />

The district council is, on behalf <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> commissioner for lands, first <strong>of</strong> all managing<br />

general land in <strong>the</strong> district. In respect <strong>of</strong> village land, <strong>the</strong> role <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> district authorities is<br />

merely monitory, assisting and guiding <strong>the</strong> villages with expert know-how and advisory<br />

functions. The principle <strong>of</strong> local autonomy allows <strong>the</strong> village councils to refuse <strong>the</strong> advise<br />

given by <strong>the</strong> district level. (VLA 1999: s.9(1)) The district land <strong>of</strong>ficer is responsible for<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> process in <strong>the</strong> district and is involved in <strong>the</strong> issuing <strong>of</strong> certificates and<br />

that registers are being built up. His major influence in land matters is being exercised<br />

through <strong>the</strong> necessary procedure <strong>of</strong> signing and sealing <strong>of</strong>fers and certificates, and <strong>the</strong><br />

keeping <strong>of</strong> registers for certificates <strong>of</strong> village land, as well as a district copy <strong>of</strong> each<br />

customary right <strong>of</strong> occupancy issued in <strong>the</strong> district.<br />

Being politically elected, <strong>the</strong> district council is <strong>the</strong> authority to which villagers can turn to<br />

complain when <strong>the</strong>y are dissatisfied with decisions made by <strong>the</strong>ir own village council.<br />

(Wily, 2003:33) Finally, <strong>the</strong> district may be delegated to decide upon <strong>the</strong> maximum<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> land a single person may hold in an area. This, in order to encourage equal<br />

access and distribution <strong>of</strong> land, taking into consideration local key factors such as:<br />

population density, relative scarcity <strong>of</strong> land, and land degradation in <strong>the</strong> area. (VLA<br />

1999: s.3(1)), (Regulation 75)<br />

5.2 The process <strong>of</strong> <strong>implementation</strong><br />

Already in 1998, an initial English version <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land bill was presented. After being<br />

fur<strong>the</strong>r elaborated, discussed and amended, <strong>the</strong> two acts were finally passed in <strong>the</strong><br />

Tanzanian national assembly in February 11, 1999. Waiting for <strong>the</strong> translation into<br />

Kiswahili, <strong>the</strong> acts did not come into force until May 1, 2001, when being gazetted along<br />

with numerous supplementary regulations. (Palmer, 1999), (Wily, 2003:1)<br />

It is obvious that <strong>the</strong> launching <strong>of</strong> such a formidable piece <strong>of</strong> legislation has to be given<br />

quite some time, and demand considerable resources, in order to be properly<br />

implemented. According to Liz Wily 24 at DFID, “Provision is made for <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>s to<br />

be under constant review, and that amendments are routinely anticipated“. (Palmer,<br />

1999) This implies that <strong>the</strong> comprehensiveness <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> legislation is still to be improved.<br />

24 Ms Liz Alden Wily is an independent land tenure and natural resources management adviser. She has been engaged in <strong>the</strong><br />

Tanzanian Ministry <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong>s, <strong>the</strong> British DFID, and IIED.<br />

48


Also <strong>the</strong> Ministry <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong>s acknowledges this fact by stating, “The enactment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new<br />

land laws marks <strong>the</strong> start (not <strong>the</strong> end) <strong>of</strong> a long process <strong>of</strong> land tenure reform, which<br />

will take place for several decades to come“. (Palmer, 1999)<br />

Key achievements<br />

The land acts, including <strong>the</strong>ir respective regulations have been printed and distributed in<br />

all 21 regions, and continues to be distributed to a growing number <strong>of</strong> districts and<br />

villages, as <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> proceeds. Additionally, <strong>the</strong> preparation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> (more than<br />

50) prescribed forms have been finished. Likewise, a legislation ushering in a more<br />

transparent system <strong>of</strong> land dispute resolution, as well as <strong>the</strong> passing <strong>of</strong> amendments<br />

enabling <strong>the</strong> mortgaging <strong>of</strong> land has been brought about.<br />

In 2002, a training manual for <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> was completed toge<strong>the</strong>r with a<br />

citizen's guide for <strong>implementation</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>, and guidelines for<br />

participatory village land use planning. (Symposium 2005, opening address, Sijaona) Still<br />

<strong>the</strong>re is an outspoken need to explain, encourage and inspire villagers to realise <strong>the</strong><br />

advantages <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new legislation. In order to reach illiterate people groups, <strong>the</strong>re are<br />

visions <strong>of</strong> using various media, e.g. radio, TV, films and dramas et cetera. (Symposium<br />

2005, paper 4, Kipobota & Mafoe) In early 2004, a ministerial <strong>implementation</strong> task force<br />

was put toge<strong>the</strong>r, with a mandate to evaluate requirements and to monitor <strong>implementation</strong><br />

in pilot districts. (Symposium, 2005, paper 1, Msangi,)<br />

The need for <strong>implementation</strong><br />

The acts are since May 2001 <strong>the</strong> operating land law <strong>of</strong> Tanzania, which means that<br />

knowledge in how to handle <strong>the</strong> legislation has to be spread all over <strong>the</strong> country as<br />

rapidly as possible.<br />

As <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> brings about ra<strong>the</strong>r thorough implications for <strong>the</strong> villages, <strong>the</strong><br />

legislation has not only to be spread, but also to be taught and properly understood.<br />

Among <strong>the</strong> practical advantages <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new legislation are, that <strong>the</strong> administration <strong>of</strong> land<br />

tenure management are built on existing institutions. 25 All villages have already<br />

functioning village councils and most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m also have a village executive <strong>of</strong>ficer<br />

(VEO) running <strong>the</strong> daily administrative work. Through <strong>the</strong> keeping <strong>of</strong> a formal village<br />

land register <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> extends <strong>the</strong> tasks <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> VEOs, both quantitatively and<br />

regarding administrative accuracy.<br />

<strong>Village</strong> administration<br />

Being turned into a government employee, <strong>the</strong> VEO has been given more responsibility.<br />

According to <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>, <strong>the</strong> VEO is required to have studied administrative<br />

courses during at least two years. This has lead to a shortage <strong>of</strong> VEOs qualified to<br />

perform <strong>the</strong> duties <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir roles as village land <strong>of</strong>ficers. The commissioner has <strong>the</strong>refore<br />

appointed land <strong>of</strong>ficers in 71 villages, some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m being responsible also for<br />

neighbouring villages. (Symposium, 2005, paper 1, Msangi) Additionally, land<br />

adjudication committees for land dispute resolution, and land allocation committees,<br />

advising <strong>the</strong> village council in land matters, have been appointed.<br />

25 The Tanzanian land reform differs in this matter from <strong>the</strong> land reform <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> neighbouring African nations, where <strong>the</strong> costly<br />

administration structure has to be built from <strong>the</strong> start. (Palmer 2000(1))<br />

49


Financial challenges<br />

Never<strong>the</strong>less, while all 11,000 village areas have to be informed, <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong><br />

programme is likely to require large efforts. In order to economise with <strong>the</strong> limited<br />

financial resources, as well as <strong>the</strong> limited staff available, <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> strategy has<br />

been to appoint seven regions to become pilot regions. In each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se regions, a singular<br />

district has been chosen to be built up, with support from <strong>the</strong> state, to become a model<br />

from which <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r districts and regions can learn and imitate. Initially, this has meant<br />

<strong>the</strong> construction <strong>of</strong> a proper district land registry; <strong>the</strong> restoration <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village <strong>of</strong>fices in<br />

<strong>the</strong> pilot villages to meet <strong>the</strong> required standard for housing <strong>the</strong> land register. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore,<br />

<strong>the</strong> formal process <strong>of</strong> issuing <strong>of</strong> certificates <strong>of</strong> village land, as well as certificates <strong>of</strong><br />

customary rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy has been initiated. So far, <strong>the</strong>se achievements have taken<br />

place solely in <strong>the</strong> pilot areas, but land allocation committees have been elected<br />

nationwide and village land councils, dealing with land disputes, have been appointed in<br />

most villages.<br />

Summary<br />

Since 2001, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> and <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> are <strong>the</strong> operating land law <strong>of</strong><br />

Tanzania. The <strong>implementation</strong> process is since spring 2004 showing visible progress.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> pilot areas, special training is given to village leaders, enabling <strong>the</strong>m to operate in<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir empowered roles as managers <strong>of</strong> village land, and to promote <strong>the</strong> process <strong>of</strong> issuing<br />

certificates <strong>of</strong> customary right <strong>of</strong> occupancy in <strong>the</strong>ir villages. The role <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village<br />

executive <strong>of</strong>ficer is being extended to include <strong>the</strong> duties <strong>of</strong> a village land <strong>of</strong>ficer,<br />

responsible for <strong>the</strong> land register in <strong>the</strong> village. Also, a number <strong>of</strong> committees are being<br />

put toge<strong>the</strong>r, to guide and to mediate in problematic land issues.<br />

50


6. Piloting <strong>the</strong> legislation<br />

interviews and observations<br />

Introduction<br />

In <strong>the</strong> beginning <strong>of</strong> 2004, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> Implementation Task Force was<br />

established within <strong>the</strong> Ministry <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong>s. Preparatory arrangement had <strong>the</strong>n already been<br />

done: printing <strong>the</strong> legislation and instruction booklets; designating pilot areas and helping<br />

constructing suitable buildings for <strong>the</strong> keeping <strong>of</strong> land registers in <strong>the</strong>se areas.<br />

Throughout <strong>the</strong> year 2004, <strong>the</strong> provisions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> legislation slowly began to be put into<br />

practise. This chapter is based on field interviews made in <strong>the</strong> first pilot area, about eight<br />

months after <strong>the</strong> visit <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> task force. The intention <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> visit was to observe<br />

indications <strong>of</strong> forthcoming tendencies in <strong>the</strong> footsteps <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> process. It<br />

is, though, clear that any truly reliable evaluation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new legislation ought to wait<br />

ano<strong>the</strong>r few years.<br />

6.1 Initial pilot area, <strong>the</strong> Mbozi district, Mbeya region<br />

The very first pilot area to implement <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> is <strong>the</strong> Mbozi district in <strong>the</strong><br />

Mbeya region 26 . In <strong>the</strong> township <strong>of</strong> Vwawa, a new district land <strong>of</strong>fice is constructed. This<br />

building also houses <strong>the</strong> new district land registry, as <strong>the</strong> new legislation is supposed to<br />

result in extended registration activity.<br />

In order to initiate <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> process, a team from <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong><br />

Implementation Task Force spent four weeks, from April through May 2004, in <strong>the</strong><br />

Mbozi district. Seminars were held at different levels, explaining how to implement and<br />

make use <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new legislation. Instructions on how to proceed with <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong><br />

were shared with all district land <strong>of</strong>ficers, DLO, within <strong>the</strong> region, as well as with o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

concerned <strong>of</strong>ficials. These DLOs are in <strong>the</strong>ir turn supposed to promote <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>implementation</strong> process in <strong>the</strong>ir respective district. Having thoroughly trained <strong>the</strong> DLOs,<br />

<strong>the</strong> team spent some days in <strong>the</strong> pilot villages, holding seminars for <strong>the</strong> village<br />

leaderships, and finally for <strong>the</strong> village assemblies. At village assemblies, all adults in <strong>the</strong><br />

village were ga<strong>the</strong>red to be informed and inspired about <strong>the</strong> implications and advantages<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new legislation. (Interview, Kami)<br />

Education given by CSOs<br />

After decades <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> de facto one-party regime, <strong>the</strong>re is now a great need to sensitise <strong>the</strong><br />

citizens all over Tanzania in understanding <strong>of</strong> democratic rights and values. The villagers<br />

need to learn to discern what to expect from a transparent system. In what way it is<br />

possible to hold elected bodies responsible for <strong>the</strong>ir management, and how to effectively<br />

deal with injustice, discrimination and signs <strong>of</strong> corruption. Domestic civil society<br />

organisations, CSOs, have shown to be very effective in reaching out to individuals and<br />

groups <strong>of</strong> ordinary citizens with training and teaching. 27 Some CSOs are successfully<br />

26 In <strong>the</strong> Mbozi district, <strong>the</strong> appointed pilot villages are: Halungu, Halambo, Shasya, Msia, Malolo, Ibembwa and Iganduka.<br />

27 A concept <strong>of</strong> sending <strong>Village</strong> Legal Workers to sensitise men and women in <strong>the</strong> villages <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir land rights, was launched by <strong>the</strong><br />

Swedish development consultant organisation ORGUT. The project was financially sponsored through <strong>the</strong> partly SIDA-funded <strong>Land</strong><br />

51


targeting ignorant and vulnerable groups, whose rights have been streng<strong>the</strong>ned through<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>, and who are <strong>the</strong>refore important to be reached. Such engagements<br />

have brought about that <strong>the</strong> Ministry <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong>s has started to recognise CSOs as important<br />

co-actors in <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> process. The Tanzanian CSOs are taking stand on <strong>the</strong><br />

land acts when discussing democracy and human rights in <strong>the</strong> villages, as well as when<br />

encouraging women’s legal self-confidence. They are using <strong>the</strong> land acts because this<br />

piece <strong>of</strong> legislation contains essential writings covering aspects <strong>of</strong> both equality and<br />

equity, and is <strong>the</strong>refore <strong>of</strong> fundamental importance for <strong>the</strong> social rights <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> villagers.<br />

Even <strong>the</strong> former Chairman <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Presidential <strong>Land</strong> Commission, <strong>the</strong> scholar Issa Shivji,<br />

recognises that <strong>the</strong> land acts are far from being just ano<strong>the</strong>r piece <strong>of</strong> legislation. (Shivji,<br />

1999(1)) His commitment to comment and continuously bring constructive criticism all<br />

along <strong>the</strong> preparation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land bill, shows that he finds <strong>the</strong>m to be very important.<br />

6.2 Analysing <strong>the</strong> future impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> legislation<br />

One <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> objectives <strong>of</strong> this study was to try to make a prognosis on <strong>the</strong> expected future<br />

impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land acts. In order to ga<strong>the</strong>r knowledge and opinions from <strong>the</strong> academic<br />

sphere, interviews were made with initiated staff at <strong>the</strong> University College <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong> and<br />

Architectural Studies, UCLAS, in Dar es Salaam. It also seemed necessary to try to<br />

discern how <strong>the</strong> legislation is going to be received in <strong>the</strong> villages, and how <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong><br />

<strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> meets <strong>the</strong> factual needs in <strong>the</strong> countryside. In order to find this out, interviews<br />

were made in <strong>the</strong> Mbozi district in south-western Tanzania.<br />

Trends in rural development<br />

The Tanzanian rural societies are, according to pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kombe (interview 2004-12-<br />

14:2), increasingly facing a new economic reality. This development has come as a<br />

consequence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> recent economic liberalisation, which opened up for global financial<br />

interests. New demands are coming up, which <strong>the</strong> present system is not at all prepared to<br />

handle. The fact that <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian agriculture is dominated by small-holding farms<br />

makes <strong>the</strong> rural societies vulnerable. Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kombe sees a danger in <strong>the</strong> ignorance and<br />

innocence among <strong>the</strong> villagers. External actors are entering former isolated areas to an<br />

extent which <strong>the</strong> rural population is not capable to meet. Most village councils, he says,<br />

lacks <strong>the</strong> knowledge and experience to see <strong>the</strong> long-term consequences <strong>of</strong>, for example<br />

selling <strong>of</strong>f portions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir land. It is <strong>the</strong>refore <strong>of</strong> crucial importance to train <strong>the</strong> villagers<br />

to handle <strong>the</strong> new reality.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kombe sees a danger in <strong>the</strong> migration <strong>of</strong> young, able workforce<br />

to <strong>the</strong> cities and urban areas. They are probably less likely to be able to earn <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

livelihood in <strong>the</strong> urban centres than on <strong>the</strong> fields. He realises that <strong>the</strong>re is no o<strong>the</strong>r way to<br />

prevent youths from leaving <strong>the</strong> countryside than to create opportunities for <strong>the</strong>m to stay<br />

in <strong>the</strong> villages.<br />

Management Programme (LAMP) in Simanjiro and Babati districts. The training was performed by domestic CSOs, and targeted on<br />

empowerment on <strong>the</strong> local level; to prepare villagers and pastoralists for <strong>the</strong>ir streng<strong>the</strong>ned rights and <strong>the</strong> coming opportunities to<br />

utilise <strong>the</strong> land. But also to introduce <strong>the</strong>m in <strong>the</strong> requirements <strong>of</strong> a modern legislation. One <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> findings from “The Symposium on<br />

Implementation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1999 <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>s“ was for <strong>the</strong> government to more involve, cooperate with and make use <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> resources and<br />

opinions that <strong>the</strong> different domestic CSOs provide.<br />

52


Strengths and weaknesses with <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy system<br />

When discussing <strong>the</strong> advantages <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy system, <strong>the</strong> opinions differ<br />

widely. Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kombe finds it to be about time to create a legal status for <strong>the</strong><br />

customary land tenure, thus inserting it into <strong>the</strong> modern economy, and securing its legal<br />

rights. “It should have been done years ago“, he says. Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kironde (interview<br />

2004-12-17) sees <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy system merely as a relic from colonial days.<br />

He warns for <strong>the</strong> upcoming confusion that threatens to appear when <strong>the</strong> 33-year terms <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> first rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy runs out within <strong>the</strong> next few years. “Today, <strong>the</strong>re is no clear<br />

direction in how to deal with this issue“, he says. Obviously, Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kironde is ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

concerned about <strong>the</strong> topic, having recently written articles to highlight its urgency. The<br />

question is whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> intention <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> system is to revoke <strong>the</strong> ownership period after its<br />

expiration, or to prolong it after a renewed application. Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kironde also questions<br />

<strong>the</strong> meaning <strong>of</strong> having tenancy conditions that are not looked after and properly policed.<br />

Mr Simba (interview 2004-12-14:1), on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, holds a positive attitude towards<br />

<strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy system. He appreciates that <strong>the</strong> government keeps <strong>the</strong> control over<br />

land issues through <strong>the</strong> procedure <strong>of</strong> granting admissions before formal dispositions and<br />

sales. “Through government control, <strong>the</strong> accessibility to land will be kept at low costs,<br />

which enables also poor people to get hold <strong>of</strong> land“, he argues. Although <strong>the</strong> introduced<br />

customary right <strong>of</strong> occupancy title moves <strong>the</strong> whole system closer to an ownership model<br />

through its lack <strong>of</strong> limit in time, it is still very much influenced by <strong>the</strong> state through its<br />

conditions and admission requirements.<br />

The influence <strong>of</strong> customary law<br />

Both pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kombe and pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kironde express concern that <strong>the</strong> submission to<br />

customary laws, being significant for <strong>the</strong> new legislation, will turn out to be a hindrance<br />

to <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong>. Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kombe refers to <strong>the</strong> ambivalent rural situation in<br />

Tanzania, where traditional villages are strongly relying on customary law, whereas<br />

villages affected by <strong>the</strong> land-tenure reforms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1960s and 70s, are not at all as bound<br />

to such customary rules and regulations. This means that <strong>the</strong> regulations <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong><br />

<strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> on <strong>the</strong> one hand is going to thoroughly influence and affect <strong>the</strong> management <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> non-traditional Ujamaa-villages, but on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, be submissive to <strong>the</strong> strong<br />

customary laws within traditional villages and pastoralist tribes. The division <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

countryside into <strong>the</strong>se two groups may become a reality hard to handle.<br />

Opportunities with <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong><br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kombe especially appreciates that <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> is mandating <strong>the</strong><br />

village governments to extend <strong>the</strong>ir management <strong>of</strong> village land. He also mentions <strong>the</strong><br />

possibility for small farmers to acquire money directly, without having to rely on<br />

subsidiaries from <strong>the</strong> state, to be a step in a positive direction. Additionally, he sees <strong>the</strong><br />

increased possibilities for large-scale production on general land to be an opportunity to<br />

create employment in <strong>the</strong> countryside. Mr Simba appreciates women’s equal rights to<br />

land, secured by <strong>the</strong> land acts, and recognises also <strong>the</strong> passage in <strong>the</strong> legislation<br />

concerning sustainability in <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> village land resources. He argues that <strong>the</strong>se<br />

regulations will prevent <strong>the</strong> open-access problematic <strong>of</strong> overgrazing, as well as <strong>the</strong><br />

cutting down <strong>of</strong> forests on village land in Tanzania. On this topic, <strong>the</strong> District <strong>Land</strong><br />

Officer <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Mbozi district, Mr Sichone (interview 2005-01-12), explains <strong>the</strong> need for<br />

53


long-term commitment to <strong>the</strong> spreading <strong>of</strong> a different mentality regarding sustainable<br />

land-management. With a touch <strong>of</strong> humour he states that “Africans have a difficult<br />

relationship to trees“, and is looking forward to <strong>the</strong> day when <strong>the</strong> villagers in his district<br />

realise <strong>the</strong> benefits <strong>of</strong> planting and nurturing an abundance <strong>of</strong> trees in and around <strong>the</strong><br />

villages.<br />

Challenges for <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong><br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kironde points out <strong>the</strong> classic difficulty for a national policy to be made<br />

comprehensible at village level. Theories needs to be converted into functional practice,<br />

in order to affect areas <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> everyday rural reality. Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kironde complains over<br />

lack <strong>of</strong> integration, meaning not only <strong>the</strong> enormous physical distance between <strong>the</strong> village<br />

council, being isolated out on <strong>the</strong> countryside, and <strong>the</strong> Ministry <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong>s, situated<br />

downtown in Dar es Salaam; but moreover, <strong>the</strong> narrow-minded mentality <strong>of</strong> some<br />

Tanzanian <strong>of</strong>ficials, which thinks too much in isolated sectors. Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kironde<br />

emphasises <strong>the</strong> need to work integrative, to view <strong>the</strong> legislation in a broad perspective,<br />

and to tackle <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> across <strong>the</strong> ministerial sections.<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kombe warns for a coming scenario, when land is becoming increasingly<br />

scarce. Due to speculative buying <strong>of</strong> land, accessibility to land for <strong>the</strong> poor will decrease.<br />

He means that <strong>the</strong> existing prerequisites to qualify for buying village land are all too<br />

easily overcome. The stipulations are hard to check, and moreover, <strong>the</strong> poverty in <strong>the</strong><br />

villages will make <strong>the</strong> regulations vulnerable. Poverty drives people to accept <strong>of</strong>fers to<br />

sell <strong>the</strong>ir land also at bad conditions. Quite <strong>the</strong> contrary, Mr Sichone reasons that <strong>the</strong> laid<br />

down regulations in <strong>the</strong> acts will turn out to be an effective tool to prevent wealthy<br />

investors to lay hands on large tracts <strong>of</strong> land at <strong>the</strong> expense <strong>of</strong> local peasants. Mr Simba<br />

also appreciates that <strong>the</strong> legislation is being equipped with control mechanisms for <strong>the</strong><br />

government.<br />

Dealing with abuse and corruption<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kombe argues that <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> will have difficulties to curb<br />

infringements like speculation and corruption. Even though <strong>the</strong>re are legal control<br />

mechanisms, speculation will be hard to check, and <strong>the</strong> policing resources checking on<br />

corrupt behaviour will most likely continue to be insufficient.<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kombe is also convinced that informal land markets will continue to exist<br />

regardless <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new legislation. Again, poverty will drive people to find ways to <strong>the</strong><br />

cheat <strong>the</strong> legal control mechanisms in order to trade land informally. As long as it is<br />

optional to register ones land in <strong>the</strong> villages, <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> informal land markets in<br />

rural areas should not be able to sabotage <strong>the</strong> formality in <strong>the</strong> land tenure system <strong>the</strong> way<br />

it did in Kenya. In <strong>the</strong> long run, though, <strong>the</strong> reliability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> registers may be threatened.<br />

Regarding corruption, Mr Sichone believes that <strong>the</strong> new policy <strong>of</strong> transparency in<br />

transactions will leave minimal room for corruptive action. All transactions will onwards<br />

have to be performed before <strong>the</strong> village council in order to be recognised as legally valid.<br />

The dilemma for commercial banks<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kombe and pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kironde both express uncertainty about how <strong>the</strong> banks<br />

are going to encounter <strong>the</strong> upcoming possibilities to mortgage village land. They question<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> opportunities will be accepted, and to what extent <strong>the</strong> reformed land law will<br />

54


create tangible land values everywhere in <strong>the</strong> country. Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kombe reasons that<br />

factors like accessibility to infrastructure probably will be decisive when determining <strong>the</strong><br />

value <strong>of</strong> rural land. It is <strong>the</strong>refore likely that rural land value will vary very much from<br />

area to area, he says. In <strong>the</strong> most remote areas, where land is rarely traded, only local land<br />

markets 28 will probably appear. Due to <strong>the</strong> weak financial security, few commercial<br />

banks would likely be interested in giving credits. The prospect <strong>of</strong> getting <strong>the</strong> lended<br />

money in return through outright sale in case <strong>of</strong> default is very small. The land<br />

commission draws attention to experience showing that alternative credit institutions to<br />

smallholders, such as co-operatives and informal credit systems within <strong>the</strong> community,<br />

have been “relatively more successful” than <strong>the</strong> possibility to use <strong>the</strong> land as collateral.<br />

(Commission report, 1994:120)<br />

In <strong>the</strong> productive areas, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, where land has been scarce already a long<br />

time, <strong>the</strong> opposite situation will likely be normative. Provided that <strong>the</strong> procedure for<br />

foreclosure <strong>of</strong> a loan with a right <strong>of</strong> occupancy as collateral is going to be well<br />

established and accepted, <strong>the</strong> commercial banks would here take low risks. Contemporary<br />

research indicates, though, that this procedure does not seem to work properly today.<br />

(Commission report, 1994:119f) The commercial banks have, since <strong>the</strong> liberalisation <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> national credit market, called for amendments in <strong>the</strong> law, as well as in <strong>the</strong> legal<br />

system, in order to enable and simplify <strong>the</strong>ir handling <strong>of</strong> land as an asset. Their concern<br />

has been <strong>the</strong> difficulty to pursuit defaulters, partly due to <strong>the</strong> slow process <strong>of</strong> litigation,<br />

but also due to an edgeless legislation in this matter. (Kyaruzi, 2002:1) It is <strong>the</strong>refore not<br />

yet made clear whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> banks can actually claim, and succeed in taking over a<br />

customary right <strong>of</strong> occupancy in case <strong>of</strong> default. And even if <strong>the</strong> process straightens up,<br />

<strong>the</strong> public resistance in <strong>the</strong> countryside against such enforcements is immense.<br />

Managing financial opportunities<br />

A more hypo<strong>the</strong>tical question, which gave a wide scope <strong>of</strong> answers was, for what purpose<br />

<strong>the</strong> villagers would probably use <strong>the</strong> money, gained from mortgaging <strong>the</strong>ir land.<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kironde airs a ra<strong>the</strong>r pessimistic view, that it would be too insecure for most<br />

farmers to invest in <strong>the</strong>ir own farm. He explains that <strong>the</strong> economic environment changes<br />

too rapidly for <strong>the</strong> farmers to be able to enjoy <strong>the</strong> fruits <strong>of</strong> any long-term investments.<br />

Ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> rainfall is too unreliable, or <strong>the</strong> world-market price <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> cash-crop is too<br />

unstable. Also Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kombe believes <strong>the</strong> farmers would invest in something that<br />

guarantees <strong>the</strong> return. Referring to statements from his fa<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> family farm would be a<br />

too insecure object to invest in, yielding a too low return. According to pr<strong>of</strong>essor<br />

Kironde, past experiences have shown that most people are not good borrowers. Some<br />

would probably invest to get a quick return through speculation, while o<strong>the</strong>rs would<br />

spend money on social needs. Mr Simba believes that <strong>the</strong> money would likely be spent on<br />

improvements <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> housing and on education for <strong>the</strong> children.<br />

Many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se arguments correspond to what <strong>the</strong> research <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land commission has<br />

found. It claimed, well before <strong>the</strong> passing <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land acts that previously given credits<br />

have benefited only a small fraction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> well-to-do farmers. “Such credits are very<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten used to finance non-agricultural activities such as building and business -ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

than invested in agriculture.“ (Commission report, 1994:120)<br />

28 The term “local land market” is here referring to areas where land transactions are solely taking place between sellers and buyers<br />

within <strong>the</strong> same village, or among <strong>the</strong> immediate surrounding villages.<br />

55


6.3 Interviews from <strong>the</strong> pilot area<br />

During a research journey 29 in <strong>the</strong> Mbozi district, several interviews were made with<br />

district <strong>of</strong>ficials as well as village chairmen. First, <strong>the</strong> District <strong>Land</strong> Officer, Mr<br />

Bramsiden Laimos Sichone shared his experience from <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> process so<br />

far; <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> former <strong>Village</strong> Chairman in Halungu, Mr Simon Mbuzi gave valuable<br />

information, and finally <strong>the</strong> recently elected 30 <strong>Village</strong> Chairman <strong>of</strong> Halambo village, Mr<br />

Stephan Mnozya, aired his ideas about <strong>the</strong> future.<br />

Presentation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Mbozi district<br />

The Mbozi district is situated in <strong>the</strong> mountainous south-western part <strong>of</strong> Tanzania. The<br />

principal town, Vwawa, is hosting <strong>the</strong> district headquarter and <strong>the</strong> district land <strong>of</strong>fice. The<br />

district consists <strong>of</strong> 164 villages. On <strong>the</strong> plateau, <strong>the</strong> high altitude creates ideal climatic<br />

conditions for growing high-quality c<strong>of</strong>fee, which is considered a highly valuable cash<br />

crop. Here <strong>the</strong> soil is fertile and <strong>the</strong> rainfall relatively rich and reliable. Altoge<strong>the</strong>r, this<br />

makes farming land attractive and <strong>the</strong> demand for land is already higher than <strong>the</strong> supply.<br />

Consequently, land value in Halambo and Halungu has, during <strong>the</strong> last five years or so,<br />

increased about tenfold. <strong>Land</strong> scarcity will presumably soon be one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> biggest<br />

problems in <strong>the</strong> area.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> swampy areas <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> valley, rice is <strong>the</strong> characteristic subsistence crop. Here, land is<br />

abundant and <strong>the</strong> land value is still relatively low. Mr Sichone explains that it is not<br />

unusual that farmers expand <strong>the</strong>ir farm through buying land also outside <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir own<br />

village. Some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m sell portions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir inherited land in valuable areas, in order to<br />

achieve a much larger plot in areas where land is still cheap. This behaviour occurred<br />

even before <strong>the</strong> passing <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> acts, through entirely informal procedures <strong>of</strong> landtransactions.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> Mbozi district, customary laws do not seem to have much influence in<br />

land matters. At least, <strong>the</strong>y do not conflict with <strong>the</strong> interests <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land acts.<br />

(Interviews, Sichone, Mbuzi, Mnozya)<br />

Expectations on <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong><br />

Since <strong>the</strong> task force’s information and training tour in <strong>the</strong> district, in mid-2004, <strong>the</strong><br />

villagers are, according to Mr Sichone, yearning for <strong>the</strong> promised possibilities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new<br />

legislation: ”<strong>Village</strong> councillors and chairmen are pressing to get all things in order for<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir village to go on with <strong>the</strong> issuing <strong>of</strong> individual certificates.” It seems to be <strong>the</strong><br />

possibility to mortgage <strong>the</strong> land that attracts <strong>the</strong> main interest in <strong>the</strong> villages. But also <strong>the</strong><br />

improvements in land-security are well received. As <strong>the</strong> issuing <strong>of</strong> a certificate requires<br />

clarified and acknowledged property borders, quite many land-conflicts will have to be<br />

dealt with in <strong>the</strong> process. Having managed this challenge nationwide, <strong>the</strong> security <strong>of</strong><br />

tenure will most likely increase considerably, which is one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> objectives <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>implementation</strong>.<br />

Before <strong>the</strong> issuing <strong>of</strong> individual certificates is possible, a critical requirement for a village<br />

is to have gained a Certificate <strong>of</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong>. Through this document, <strong>the</strong> demarcated<br />

village borders will be indisputable, and it is only within this area that individual<br />

29 The research journey was carried out during <strong>the</strong> 12 th and 13 th <strong>of</strong> January 2005<br />

30 Local elections in Tanzania were held in November 2004. This resulted in that some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> already trained village leaders, like Mr<br />

Mbuzi, had to resign from <strong>the</strong> village leadership, thus causing a loss <strong>of</strong> trained resources and knowledge in how to go about <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>implementation</strong>.<br />

56


certificates <strong>of</strong> customary rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy can be issued. At <strong>the</strong> time <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> interview,<br />

36 out <strong>of</strong> 164 villages in <strong>the</strong> district had already got <strong>the</strong>ir village certificates attended.<br />

Mr Sichone imagines a situation where, ”Within four to five years time, everything will<br />

be in full swing”, meaning that all villages in <strong>the</strong> districts at that time will have had <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

village land certified and secured, and that certification and mortgaging <strong>of</strong> individual land<br />

is proceeding satisfactory.<br />

As a requirement for this positive view <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> future development, Mr Sichone underlines<br />

that everything is depending on whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> government continues to fulfil its<br />

commitment to support <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong>. They need to both secure continuous<br />

financial support and develop <strong>the</strong> required institutional and legislative infrastructure.<br />

Lack <strong>of</strong> resources<br />

According to voices from The Symposium on Implementation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1999 <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>s, <strong>the</strong><br />

financial conditions seem to be what challenges <strong>the</strong> new legislation and <strong>the</strong> whole land<br />

reform <strong>the</strong> most. The permanent secretary at <strong>the</strong> Ministry <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong>s admits <strong>the</strong> principal<br />

constraint <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> whole <strong>implementation</strong> to be shortage <strong>of</strong> resources <strong>of</strong> all kinds. ”The cost<br />

<strong>of</strong> full <strong>implementation</strong> nationwide is staggering.” (Symposium, 2005, opening address,<br />

Sijaona)<br />

The shortage <strong>of</strong> resources also includes lack <strong>of</strong> skilled staff <strong>of</strong> different pr<strong>of</strong>essions. As a<br />

result <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> process, <strong>the</strong>re seems to be an increasing need <strong>of</strong> surveyors,<br />

land valuers and educated administrative staff. Each village has to be surveyed before<br />

achieving its certificate <strong>of</strong> village land, which is a prerequisite for <strong>the</strong> whole chain <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>implementation</strong> activities. As a part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> process <strong>of</strong> issuing individual certificates, each<br />

plot has to be valued by an authorised land valuer. <strong>Land</strong> valuers have up to now primarily<br />

been active in urban regions; but in <strong>the</strong> footsteps <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>, Mr Sichone<br />

sees a nationwide demand for this pr<strong>of</strong>ession. Additional pr<strong>of</strong>essions experiencing<br />

immediate shortage <strong>of</strong> staff seem to be administrative staff trained in register keeping. Mr<br />

Sichone has vainly been searching a register assistant for <strong>the</strong> district land <strong>of</strong>fice in<br />

Vwawa. A person trained and able to administer <strong>the</strong> new and quickly growing district<br />

land register is needed, but it seems to be a difficult task to attract such skilled labour<br />

from <strong>the</strong> cities, where <strong>the</strong>y are to be found, to remote municipalities all over <strong>the</strong> country.<br />

Physical resources<br />

Regardless if <strong>the</strong> land acts require only <strong>the</strong> simplest form <strong>of</strong> title registers, and <strong>the</strong><br />

administration is built upon already existing institutions; all <strong>the</strong>se achievements will fail<br />

to materialise as long as <strong>the</strong> required local investments are unaffordable for <strong>the</strong> villages.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> pilot areas, state support has been granted to finance construction <strong>of</strong> reasonable<br />

housing for <strong>the</strong> registers, as well as purchase <strong>of</strong> filing cabinets, records, forms and<br />

documents. This has led to that districts and villages adjacent to <strong>the</strong> pilot areas have<br />

called for external financing and central support as well. (Symposium, 2005, paper 4,<br />

Kipobota & Mafoe) Even though it is meant for every district to cover <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>implementation</strong> within <strong>the</strong>ir budgets, <strong>the</strong> question <strong>of</strong> financing will continue to be central<br />

for <strong>the</strong> prolongation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong>.<br />

57


The new tasks <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village executive <strong>of</strong>ficer<br />

With regard to <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> administration, <strong>the</strong> duties <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village executive<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficer (VEO) now also include being <strong>the</strong> land <strong>of</strong>ficer in <strong>the</strong> village. As such, <strong>the</strong> VEO is<br />

henceforth a government employee. Thus, <strong>the</strong> qualifications <strong>of</strong> this village key person<br />

have been extended to include at least a two-year administrative education. As a result <strong>of</strong><br />

this rapid change, quite a few existing VEOs are not qualified to simultaneously act as<br />

land <strong>of</strong>ficers. The commissioner for lands has <strong>the</strong>refore initially appointed land <strong>of</strong>ficers<br />

in 71 villages with extended authority also over neighbouring villages. (Symposium,<br />

2005, paper 1, Msangi) Mr Sichone sees as <strong>the</strong> primary new task <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> VEO to mobilise<br />

<strong>the</strong> village to development; to maximise <strong>the</strong> efforts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> villagers, and to try to affect<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir ideas <strong>of</strong> efficiency. He emphasises that <strong>the</strong> result <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village is very much<br />

depending on <strong>the</strong> individual attitude and efficiency <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> VEO himself. Successful<br />

villages will be found to have skilful VEOs, and non-corruptive village councils.<br />

<strong>Land</strong> market<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> pilot villages in <strong>the</strong> Mbozi district are situated on <strong>the</strong> highly productive,<br />

c<strong>of</strong>fee-growing highland plateau, none <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m are yet facing real land-scarcity problems.<br />

They all still have commonly held spare land for <strong>the</strong> young adults in <strong>the</strong> village to apply<br />

for. So far, merely local land markets exist, but, according to <strong>the</strong> view <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village<br />

leaderships, land holding villagers are free to sell <strong>of</strong>f land also to outsiders. Dispositions<br />

do exist, and <strong>the</strong> price development <strong>of</strong> farmland is raging. In Halambo village, land that a<br />

few years ago amounted to 5-10 000 Tanzanian shillings per acre is now sold for 80-<br />

100 000 Tanzanian shillings per acre. (Interview, Mnozya)<br />

Managing financial opportunities<br />

There appears to be consensus among <strong>the</strong> interviewed village leaders that investments in<br />

land are going to be <strong>the</strong> top priority when achieving money from <strong>the</strong> loans, using land as<br />

collateral. There are plans <strong>of</strong> buying fertilisers and pesticides, as well as to invest in<br />

irrigation schemes in <strong>the</strong> villages. Mr Sichone explains that <strong>the</strong> ideas are not new.<br />

Investments were previously done through state co-operatives in <strong>the</strong> 1960s, but as <strong>the</strong>fts<br />

<strong>of</strong> commonly held fertilisers and equipment became widespread, <strong>the</strong> whole system<br />

eventually collapsed. Nowadays, farmers voluntarily ga<strong>the</strong>r in groups <strong>of</strong> 10-30 people in<br />

order to help one ano<strong>the</strong>r improve <strong>the</strong>ir land. In Halambo village, a common investment<br />

fund has been built up, aiming at helping improve <strong>the</strong> common land interests <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

farmers.<br />

Among <strong>the</strong> older farmers, memories <strong>of</strong> previous errors are still kept in mind. Mr Sichone<br />

describes some consequences <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> plentiful harvests <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1970s, when pr<strong>of</strong>its were<br />

quickly squandered through short-sighted purchase <strong>of</strong> capital goods and alcohol. It was<br />

also more common than today to have large costly families with many wives and children<br />

in abundance. Hopefully people have learnt from <strong>the</strong>ir former mistakes, and are prepared<br />

to take on a more long-sighted and responsible conduct than before, he says. In order to<br />

achieve this, it is crucial to share <strong>the</strong> experiences with <strong>the</strong> young generation and educate<br />

and train <strong>the</strong>m in excellent management.<br />

58


Speculations for <strong>the</strong> future<br />

The new legislation has doubtlessly ignited prospects for <strong>the</strong> future in this particular<br />

region. Among successful farmers, <strong>the</strong>re are expectations <strong>of</strong> an increasing wealth. They<br />

realise that <strong>the</strong> ideal climatic conditions and <strong>the</strong> fertile soil in <strong>the</strong>ir part <strong>of</strong> Tanzania hold<br />

unreleased potentials. But, in order to benefit from <strong>the</strong>m, <strong>the</strong> farmers have to invest in<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir land, and for this, money is needed. At last, it seems like <strong>the</strong> new legislation will<br />

help unleash this possibility, and <strong>the</strong> response in <strong>the</strong> villages has been overwhelming. Mr<br />

Mbuzi in Halungu village is convinced that <strong>the</strong> financial situation will be better for those<br />

who are able to plan and handle money, but will grow worse for those who lack financial<br />

discipline or ability to plan long-term.<br />

Acquire a certificate<br />

Improved<br />

Money available<br />

financial<br />

through mortgaging<br />

output<br />

<strong>the</strong> land<br />

Money available for education,<br />

improved housing, illness treating,<br />

hospital fees etc.<br />

Increase<br />

<strong>the</strong> harvest<br />

Figure 6.1<br />

The ideal chain <strong>of</strong> conduct<br />

Investments and<br />

improvements<br />

in <strong>the</strong> farm<br />

Mr Mnozya in Halambo village believes that as <strong>the</strong> land value continues to increase,<br />

people will be keen on keeping <strong>the</strong>ir land to <strong>the</strong>mselves. ”Outsiders will not find land<br />

here”, he says. Not <strong>the</strong> least due to population growth, <strong>the</strong>re will in <strong>the</strong> near future be<br />

scarcity <strong>of</strong> land in <strong>the</strong> villages. As a result, <strong>the</strong> tradition <strong>of</strong> free allocation <strong>of</strong> land from <strong>the</strong><br />

village land reserve to <strong>the</strong> young adults will end. Instead, <strong>the</strong>y will have to migrate to<br />

neighbouring areas where <strong>the</strong> pressure on land is lower. A few <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m will get educated<br />

and find jobs in urban areas; o<strong>the</strong>rs will migrate to <strong>the</strong> towns anyway. In <strong>the</strong> distant<br />

Babati district, District <strong>Land</strong> Officer, Mr Mrutu asserts that <strong>the</strong> upcoming landless<br />

generation is an entirely new phenomenon in Tanzania, but will continue to increase in<br />

attractive areas.<br />

The expected increase in <strong>the</strong> produce <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village farms, and <strong>the</strong> subsequent growing<br />

wealth will also lead to improved transportation and, in <strong>the</strong> long run, <strong>the</strong> breaking <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

village isolation.<br />

Agricultural development<br />

Even though borrowed money will enable fertilisers, pesticides and investments in<br />

irrigation schemes, Mr Mbuzi expects <strong>the</strong> cultivation methods to stay more or less <strong>the</strong><br />

same. There will continue to be an overwhelming majority <strong>of</strong> small-holding farms with a<br />

large input <strong>of</strong> human labour. Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kironde is convinced that <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian farmer is<br />

59


innovative, and has through trial and error already found out <strong>the</strong> crops that are most<br />

suitable and best adapted for <strong>the</strong> prevailing conditions. Mr Kami, expert in land<br />

legislation and connected to <strong>the</strong> village land <strong>implementation</strong> task force, holds a contrary<br />

opinion. Instead, he argues that <strong>the</strong> average villager is resistant to change and needs to be<br />

supported with ideas about <strong>the</strong> choice <strong>of</strong> crops and how to improve <strong>the</strong>ir farming<br />

methods. Mr Kami is not a follower <strong>of</strong> coercive teaching; instead he nurtures a vision to<br />

spread successful examples and improvements through a variety <strong>of</strong> Medias. He is<br />

convinced that <strong>the</strong>re are lots to gain through simple, and not necessarily so costly<br />

improvements in how <strong>the</strong> farmers are cultivating <strong>the</strong>ir land. (Interview, Kami)<br />

In <strong>the</strong> Babati district, <strong>the</strong> district land and forest <strong>of</strong>fice has established a permanent farmexhibition,<br />

where village councils and groups <strong>of</strong> farmers can be shown improved<br />

methods <strong>of</strong>, for example, how to abridge and prevent problems <strong>of</strong> land erosion, or how to<br />

more efficiently make use <strong>of</strong> limited areas <strong>of</strong> land. There, different solutions <strong>of</strong> agr<strong>of</strong>orestry<br />

is tested, and an arboretum showing <strong>the</strong> character and local suitability <strong>of</strong><br />

different sorts <strong>of</strong> hardwood is established.<br />

Summary<br />

There is huge expectation among <strong>the</strong> villagers on <strong>the</strong> future rural land development in<br />

Tanzania, but also a justified reluctance towards <strong>the</strong> promises <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> legislation. The<br />

<strong>implementation</strong> will be costly and is <strong>the</strong>refore likely to become a ra<strong>the</strong>r lengthy process.<br />

On top <strong>of</strong> this, lack <strong>of</strong> skilled people might pose hindrances on <strong>the</strong> way forward. The<br />

<strong>implementation</strong> process is still in a premature phase, but optimistic expectations assert<br />

that within ten years, everything will be in full swing.<br />

60


7. Final discussion<br />

In <strong>the</strong> previous writing we have laid a foundation, upon which to discuss <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian<br />

land tenure system in a comparative manner. The following, concluding chapter will<br />

<strong>the</strong>refore deal with and discuss <strong>the</strong> strengths and weaknesses <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>, as<br />

well as <strong>the</strong> likeliness for a successful <strong>implementation</strong>.<br />

Thus far, we have briefly surveyed <strong>the</strong> history <strong>of</strong> Tanzanian land politics, including: <strong>the</strong><br />

customary view; <strong>the</strong> emergence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong> occupancy system; and <strong>the</strong> transformation<br />

<strong>of</strong> Tanzanian land tenure since <strong>the</strong> national independence. In order to discern <strong>the</strong><br />

disparities between tenancy and ownership when connected to land, we have been<br />

acquainted with <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> property rights. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, we have looked into <strong>the</strong><br />

specific character <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> African rural societies and land tenure. Opinions questioning <strong>the</strong><br />

superiority <strong>of</strong> individualisation <strong>of</strong> land have been reflected. Finally, <strong>the</strong> new Tanzanian<br />

land legislation has briefly been presented, focussing on <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>. It has to<br />

be stressed, that <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> is by no means completed.<br />

On <strong>the</strong> contrary, <strong>the</strong> major achievement is still to be done. Being aware <strong>of</strong> this, any<br />

present-day evaluation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> future result can merely be <strong>of</strong> speculative nature.<br />

7.1 Right <strong>of</strong> occupancy versus freehold tenure<br />

When comparing <strong>the</strong> bundle <strong>of</strong> rights attached to freeholds with those <strong>of</strong> Tanzanian rights<br />

<strong>of</strong> occupancy (See chapter 4), <strong>the</strong>se seem to have much in common. Superficially, <strong>the</strong><br />

empowered right <strong>of</strong> occupancy in <strong>the</strong> land acts aims to equip and authorise <strong>the</strong> landholder<br />

with property rights being similar to <strong>the</strong> property rights <strong>of</strong> a corresponding<br />

freehold. Beside <strong>the</strong> exclusive rights to cultivate, expel outsiders and erect buildings, also<br />

dispositional rights are made equal to those <strong>of</strong> a freehold. Among <strong>the</strong>se are rights to<br />

transfer <strong>the</strong> ownership by inheritance, by sale or as a gift. Rights for villagers to<br />

mortgage, lease out or sub-lease <strong>the</strong> land rights are also provided for in <strong>the</strong> land acts.<br />

The forerunner Nyerere<br />

When studying <strong>the</strong> writings <strong>of</strong> Julius Nyerere, this empowerment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong><br />

occupancy-instrument hardly consists <strong>of</strong> any new ideas. In his article on national land<br />

from 1958, Nyerere argues that <strong>the</strong> genuine solution to <strong>the</strong> land question ought to be land<br />

given to everybody under certain regulations and instructions, laid down in <strong>the</strong> leasehold<br />

agreement. He maintains that land shall remain <strong>the</strong> property <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> public, but<br />

never<strong>the</strong>less, guarantee for <strong>the</strong> leaseholder not to be interfered with, in his right to use <strong>the</strong><br />

land. Nyerere proposes a leasehold system, enjoying “all <strong>the</strong> advantages <strong>of</strong> a freeholder<br />

<strong>of</strong> land but does not experience <strong>the</strong> disadvantages faced by <strong>the</strong> latter.“ The disadvantages<br />

that Nyerere refers to, is <strong>the</strong> unavoidable favouring <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> wealthy, and <strong>the</strong> social<br />

inequality, that he foresees as a result <strong>of</strong> a free land market.<br />

Already some 50 years before <strong>the</strong> land acts, Nyerere’s vision was clear. At that time, he<br />

seems to have been a strong believer in <strong>the</strong> power <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> individual initiative, “Once you<br />

give a man sufficient land for all his requirements, and assure him that he will not be<br />

61


evicted from his land, and that capital will be available to him, you have actually given<br />

him all he needs to translate his energy and sweat into definite things to satisfy his<br />

requirements.“ (Nyerere, 1958:56f) Also <strong>the</strong> financial reality was thought through,<br />

“In addition, he is allowed to use his land as security if he wishes to raise a loan.“<br />

Regrettably, some fifteen years later, state controlled compulsory resettlements were<br />

parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial land policy. It turned out to be a decade-lasting reform program that,<br />

probably contrary to its initial intentions, uprooted peoples from <strong>the</strong>ir homelands, and<br />

robbed <strong>the</strong>m <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir power <strong>of</strong> initiative. (See chapter 2)<br />

7.2 Criticising <strong>the</strong> land acts<br />

State control<br />

In our search to find differences between <strong>the</strong> two land systems, we have to look closer at<br />

<strong>the</strong> power <strong>of</strong> state control over land issues. In <strong>the</strong> following, two <strong>the</strong>mes are discussed:<br />

<strong>the</strong> centralised administration, and public interference in individual property rights.<br />

The fact that <strong>the</strong> radical title to all land is vested in <strong>the</strong> president, with <strong>the</strong> commissioner<br />

for lands as <strong>the</strong> ultimate land manager, (Shivji, 1999(1),Wily, 2003:33) means that<br />

different permissions have to pass through a costly and time-consuming bureaucratic<br />

procedure. Considering <strong>the</strong> very slow pace <strong>of</strong> communication between villages and <strong>the</strong><br />

central administration, this procedure will most likely frustrate village development.<br />

It also appears that <strong>the</strong> desired efficient management is likely to be hampered by political<br />

struggle over land resources. It seems like <strong>the</strong> relation between village land use and <strong>the</strong><br />

state, can be seen ra<strong>the</strong>r as a relation <strong>of</strong> management and administration, than <strong>of</strong> rights<br />

and obligations. (Chaula, 2004:27) This inherent lack <strong>of</strong> independence for <strong>the</strong> villages<br />

has been one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> major points <strong>of</strong> critique against <strong>the</strong> structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new legislation.<br />

The influential scholar Issa Shivji has long argued <strong>the</strong> faultiness <strong>of</strong> not allowing <strong>the</strong><br />

villages true independence and local participation by vesting village land in <strong>the</strong>ir own<br />

organs, <strong>the</strong> village assemblies. Doing this would enable <strong>the</strong> land users to enjoy <strong>the</strong> full<br />

rights <strong>of</strong> use, control and management over <strong>the</strong>ir land, whereas <strong>the</strong> task <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> public<br />

administration would solely be to support <strong>the</strong>m with advice and technical assistance.<br />

(Shivji, 1999(1)) Under <strong>the</strong> present top-administered structure, Shivji argues, <strong>the</strong> village<br />

council administrates village land ra<strong>the</strong>r as an agent for <strong>the</strong> commissioner, than as an<br />

organ <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village, accountable to <strong>the</strong> village assembly. With <strong>the</strong> experience and<br />

perspective <strong>of</strong> having been <strong>the</strong> chairman <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> former land commission, Shivji points out<br />

that land administered by a central bureaucracy, has led to problems associated with<br />

corruption, nepotism, unconscionable allocations and uncertainty. (Shivji, 1999(2))<br />

It remains obscure how <strong>the</strong> weaknesses <strong>of</strong> inefficiency, delay and corruption will be dealt<br />

with through <strong>the</strong> new legislation.<br />

In freehold systems aswell, <strong>the</strong> state enjoys legal authority to, under certain<br />

circumstances, intervene in individual property rights. Although <strong>the</strong>re is great variation<br />

among societies, <strong>the</strong> limits for such interventions are still ra<strong>the</strong>r fixed and predictable.<br />

Circumscription <strong>of</strong> rights for reasons <strong>of</strong> national or public interests are fairly common. In<br />

a state governed by law, such circumscriptions may, by no means, be based on arbitrary<br />

62


principles, but must be supported by formal law. Even compulsory acquisition can be<br />

made possible, although only under <strong>the</strong> constitutional obligation to <strong>of</strong>fer due<br />

compensation. With <strong>the</strong> tragic experiences from a furious villagisation process, Tanzania<br />

has got a long way to go before justification in this matter will finally be reached. Even<br />

though land security is greatly improved through <strong>the</strong> land acts, <strong>the</strong> legislation still lacks<br />

serious writings defining and limiting intrusion on individual or communal property<br />

rights.<br />

Protectionism<br />

In order to protect villages from foreign intrusion, preserving its ownership structure, <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> formally allows transferring <strong>of</strong> rights to land only between citizens<br />

already resident in <strong>the</strong> village. This condition includes anyone who intends to make <strong>the</strong><br />

village his residence, or a non-village body, which has <strong>the</strong> village as its main place <strong>of</strong><br />

business. (Wily, 2003:35) This regulation is negotiable, and outsiders may with <strong>the</strong><br />

consent from <strong>the</strong> village council be allowed to acquire village land. According to <strong>the</strong> law,<br />

a prospective land-holder must, though, absolutely be “A Tanzanian citizen <strong>of</strong> African<br />

descent“, (LA 1999: s.2) which is to be interpreted as an expression <strong>of</strong> protectionism.<br />

Until <strong>the</strong> financial liberalisation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1980s and 90s, similar restrictions were common<br />

also in western land legislations. But, as a result <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increasing liberalisation and<br />

globalisation, <strong>the</strong>se restrictions have mostly been abandoned. Realising that one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

intentions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> is to protect and preserve <strong>the</strong> vulnerable village<br />

structure and <strong>the</strong> customary land tenure, this protectionism seems fully understandable.<br />

7.3 Discussing <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong><br />

Will <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> be fully implemented?<br />

As mentioned earlier, <strong>the</strong> work <strong>of</strong> implementing <strong>the</strong> legislation must be seen in a longrange<br />

perspective. Questions and difficulties have to be worked out gradually and<br />

methodically. An important part <strong>of</strong> this process is to confront <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oretically elaborated<br />

ideas with reality. Ever since <strong>the</strong> initial phase <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> process to create a functional land<br />

policy and legislation, polemic debates have been a successful means in Tanzania.<br />

Institutes, CSOs, and individual debaters have taken place in <strong>the</strong> public debate, where <strong>the</strong><br />

politicians sometimes have had to defend and reconsider <strong>the</strong>ir opinions. The last-minute<br />

amendment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land bill before finally being enacted in February 1999 signifies this<br />

development. But also in <strong>the</strong> current process <strong>of</strong> implementing <strong>the</strong> land acts, it is <strong>of</strong><br />

decisive importance that critical questions continue to be raised. The ministerial<br />

administration has to be made aware <strong>of</strong> difficulties and hazards that need to be addressed,<br />

as well as to be informed about successful initiatives and pragmatic solutions.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> following discussion, some crucial questions will be addressed, that have come to<br />

mind during interviews with <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>essors, as well as during <strong>the</strong> visits to <strong>the</strong> villages.<br />

Financial resources<br />

The issue <strong>of</strong> financial resources is tw<strong>of</strong>old. First, <strong>the</strong>re is <strong>the</strong> national level with concern<br />

for summoning <strong>the</strong> needed resources at large; and secondly, <strong>the</strong> limited financial<br />

resources at village level. There is no doubt that <strong>the</strong> realisation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong><br />

63


depends on <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> resources that are being granted. Unfortunately, <strong>the</strong>re seems to<br />

be a passive attitude among <strong>the</strong> district <strong>of</strong>ficials <strong>of</strong> awaiting superior instructions, despite<br />

<strong>the</strong> fact that it is required <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> districts <strong>the</strong>mselves to budget and take responsibility for<br />

<strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> process in <strong>the</strong>ir area. (Symposium 2005, paper 4,<br />

Kipobota & Mafoe) One reason might be that <strong>the</strong>ir already strained budgets lack<br />

resources for taking any initiatives at all. Time will tell if <strong>the</strong> excessive administrational<br />

procedures are becoming too costly. Doubtlessly, <strong>the</strong> government is relying on financial<br />

support from foreign donors, but it would; never<strong>the</strong>less, be to repeat a historical mistake<br />

to put <strong>the</strong> nation in a situation <strong>of</strong> severe debt and dependence, by building a resourcedemanding<br />

administrational structure. This is namely <strong>the</strong> unpleasant situation for some <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> South-East Asian countries that have accepted to be strongly influenced by advice<br />

from donors and <strong>the</strong> World Bank. (Palmer, 2000(2))<br />

Next question at issue concerns <strong>the</strong> limited financial resources <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> villagers. It is yet to<br />

be evaluated, whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> achieving certificates <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> customary held land is<br />

going to be considered worthwhile for <strong>the</strong> majority <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> villagers. As <strong>the</strong> law protects<br />

<strong>the</strong> security <strong>of</strong> tenure for registered and for unregistered land alike, <strong>the</strong> main gain from<br />

achieving certificates would be <strong>the</strong> possibility to apply for a loan, using <strong>the</strong> land as<br />

security. In order to do this, <strong>the</strong> land first has to be valued by a recognised land-valuer,<br />

and quite many forms have to be administered. This will take time and cost money. On<br />

top <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> different administrational costs, <strong>the</strong> holder <strong>of</strong> a certificate is levied an annual<br />

land rent which those without certificates continue to be exempted from.<br />

Interviews with village chairmen and village land <strong>of</strong>ficers make clear that <strong>the</strong> foremost<br />

expectation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> is <strong>the</strong> opening up <strong>of</strong> a<br />

possibility to mortgage <strong>the</strong> land. Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Kironde at <strong>the</strong> UCLAS warns for false<br />

expectations. He is convinced that <strong>the</strong> commercial banks will only be interested in giving<br />

loans to small holding farmers in good and productive areas, where land is estimated to<br />

high values. Hence, villagers in poorer areas will probably never be able to avail<br />

<strong>the</strong>mselves <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se legal improvements. (Interview, Kironde)<br />

Administrational complexity<br />

Connected to <strong>the</strong> above mentioned issue <strong>of</strong> centralised administration, comes <strong>the</strong> question<br />

<strong>of</strong> unnecessary administrational complexity. The <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> requires commodious<br />

administrational handling <strong>of</strong> documents; an exchange <strong>of</strong> applications, <strong>of</strong>fers, admissions<br />

and certificates between <strong>the</strong> villages and <strong>the</strong> district authorities, and sometimes even with<br />

authorities at national level. Considering <strong>the</strong> underdeveloped means <strong>of</strong> communication,<br />

where most villages lack both electricity and telephone, it is questionable whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong><br />

flow <strong>of</strong> documents for permits, approvals and signatures, will ever come to work in a<br />

smooth and efficient manner. Ano<strong>the</strong>r aspect is that similar structures are ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

vulnerable for administrational power struggles and corruption. In order to avoid such<br />

inconveniences, large efforts will have to be put on transparency and accountability at all<br />

levels. The uttered critique <strong>of</strong> this process, for being unnecessary bureaucratic, seems<br />

legitimate. Especially when considering <strong>the</strong> previous oral tradition on <strong>the</strong> countryside,<br />

which have resulted in a lack <strong>of</strong> record-keeping accustomedness at village level, and a<br />

general unfamiliarity <strong>of</strong> using forms. (Wily, 2003:8), (Sundet, 2005:129f)<br />

An adjacent issue is <strong>the</strong> keeping <strong>of</strong> accurate registers. The Kenyan experience has shown<br />

64


that <strong>the</strong> customary way <strong>of</strong> behaviour is resilient. (Palmer, 2000(2)) When people do not<br />

see <strong>the</strong> immediate advantage <strong>of</strong> a more costly and complex method, <strong>the</strong>y keep to <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

usual, informal way <strong>of</strong> performing land division and disposition <strong>of</strong> rights. If <strong>the</strong> registerkeeping<br />

is not performed correctly, it will not take long to make <strong>the</strong> land register<br />

unreliable, which would ruin <strong>the</strong> whole system.<br />

Merging social factors with business economy<br />

Nyerere´s presumption that land in itself should have no value has merely shown to be a<br />

naive vision. In a society influenced by monetary values, where everything, even time, is<br />

given monetary value, tangible things like goods and rights, are being preferred. When<br />

merging cultures <strong>the</strong> way that is being done in <strong>the</strong> global economy <strong>of</strong> our time, it requires<br />

respect and sensitivity to give fair weight to each culture being involved. By failing to<br />

accomplish this, <strong>the</strong> many different minorities will find <strong>the</strong>mselves losing what has<br />

previously been considered valuable in <strong>the</strong>ir culture. For <strong>the</strong>m, social values, such as<br />

affiliation to a group, or <strong>the</strong> ability to practise a pr<strong>of</strong>ession and maintain social functions<br />

hold financially immeasurable values. In customary cultures, <strong>the</strong>se vital functions are<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten closely connected to land-holding, and are not possible to be measured and<br />

monetary compensated for. Even if an abundant monetary compensation would be given<br />

for land being sold, most beneficiaries would not be accustomed how to turn <strong>the</strong> money<br />

into something equally useful as what is lost. This social aspect <strong>of</strong> land holding contains<br />

emotional factors opposing a pure monetary logic, but may, never<strong>the</strong>less, be fully and<br />

equally rational.<br />

Differing land values and opportunities<br />

Now, <strong>the</strong> gap in wealth and income between citizens sharing <strong>the</strong> same land legislation<br />

makes <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> money differ very much from person to person. <strong>Land</strong> prices that<br />

would mean a fortune for one person, may barely be a month’s salary for someone else.<br />

Continuing to reason in terms <strong>of</strong> business-economy, <strong>the</strong> willingness to buy or sell<br />

property depends on <strong>the</strong> alternative use <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land. In fertile, agricultural areas, or where<br />

land holds o<strong>the</strong>r valuable qualities, <strong>the</strong> financial land-value will always be high; whereas<br />

in drier, remote areas, land will be <strong>of</strong> no o<strong>the</strong>r use than for extensive farming or<br />

traditional cattle keeping. In <strong>the</strong>se latter areas, where land is abundant, <strong>the</strong> idea <strong>of</strong> land<br />

being without monetary value may still have legitimacy. Here, <strong>the</strong> turnover <strong>of</strong> land<br />

transactions is low and solely local land markets exist. Consequently, <strong>the</strong> esteemed value<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land will be significantly lower, which will affect <strong>the</strong> willingness <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> banks to<br />

give loans according to <strong>the</strong> provisions in <strong>the</strong> land acts. Hence, <strong>the</strong> most popular<br />

component <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> legislation, <strong>the</strong> mortgaging opportunity, would in larger parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Tanzanian countryside, have almost no worth at all. It is <strong>the</strong>refore questionable whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

<strong>the</strong> population in <strong>the</strong>se vast areas will find it worthwhile to make any efforts to adapt to<br />

<strong>the</strong> new legislation. In order to somewhat equally attract <strong>the</strong> entire rural population, <strong>the</strong><br />

land acts would be in need <strong>of</strong> a greater variety <strong>of</strong> incentives that can also address landholders<br />

in financially not so attractive areas.<br />

65


Future scenarios<br />

In order to estimate <strong>the</strong> outcome <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong>, <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> following<br />

few areas are crucial; funding <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> process; <strong>the</strong> registering activity; <strong>the</strong><br />

teaching and inspiring activities; <strong>the</strong> willingness <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> banks to give loans; <strong>the</strong> question<br />

<strong>of</strong> justice and equity in land allocation and land holding, and finally; administrative cost<br />

efficiency.<br />

Below, two scenarios are imagined in order to somewhat pull <strong>the</strong> scattered considerations<br />

toge<strong>the</strong>r. First, an ideal prospective development is sketched, followed by a somewhat<br />

bizarre worst-case scenario.<br />

Scenario 1. An ideal development<br />

In an ideal scenario, <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> process develops well, spreading <strong>the</strong> teaching in<br />

<strong>the</strong> land laws and <strong>the</strong> gained experience from <strong>the</strong> first pilot areas across <strong>the</strong> entire nation<br />

like waves on <strong>the</strong> water. VEOs and o<strong>the</strong>r administrational staff are being employed and<br />

educated in sufficient numbers. Each DLO establishes good relations with <strong>the</strong> village<br />

leaderships in his district. The DLOs see <strong>the</strong>mselves as skilful servants, helping and<br />

encouraging <strong>the</strong> villagers to proceed with <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> process. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong>y<br />

are cooperative and take initiatives to develop <strong>the</strong>ir own district, as well as to assist<br />

neighbouring districts with advice and helpful experience. The exchange with <strong>the</strong> CSOs<br />

is creative and dynamic. They are encouraged to fulfil <strong>the</strong>ir tasks to reach out at <strong>the</strong><br />

grassroots level; informing, explaining and functioning as non-governmental mediators<br />

between villagers and <strong>the</strong> administration. For all <strong>the</strong>se activities, <strong>the</strong>re is sufficient<br />

funding, resulting from a continuous examination <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> expenses and how to improve <strong>the</strong><br />

cost efficiency. The register-keeping function is accurate, due to <strong>the</strong> fact that each<br />

transaction concerning trade and dispositions are continuously being reported and updated.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> pledged provision for increased land security concerning<br />

customary land rights is being fulfilled. This improvement can be sensed through an<br />

increasing boldness among <strong>the</strong> villagers to persist in claiming <strong>the</strong>ir land rights against<br />

intrusion. Their complaints before <strong>the</strong> district authority are observed and taken seriously.<br />

The social function <strong>of</strong> land holding is preserved, creating incentives for <strong>the</strong> poor to keep<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir land, as well as for landless young people to acquire land suitable for farming or<br />

business. Agreements between pastoralists and farmers are being worked out and<br />

mutually respected. By means <strong>of</strong> taxation, <strong>the</strong> holding <strong>of</strong> unused land will not be<br />

advantageous anymore. As a consequence, <strong>the</strong> well-known phenomena <strong>of</strong> absent<br />

landowners and telephone farmers will drastically decrease. This positive development<br />

<strong>of</strong>fsets landlessness while attractive lands that have previously been locked up will be<br />

released. The expected outcome from <strong>the</strong> mortgaging possibilities is fulfilled. The banks<br />

are recognising certificates <strong>of</strong> customary rights <strong>of</strong> occupancy as secure documents and<br />

are allowing loans to farmers that have been able to present plans for improvement and<br />

development <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir land.<br />

Scenario 2. A worst-case development<br />

Imagining a worst-case development, would first <strong>of</strong> all include a half-way halt in <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>implementation</strong> process, due to drained financial resources. This has been <strong>the</strong> case in <strong>the</strong><br />

neighbouring Uganda. (Palmer, 2000(1)) From this unpleasant position, <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian<br />

government would have no place to retreat. The legislation would still be <strong>the</strong> only<br />

66


working land law, although not able to be empowered.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> registration activity and <strong>the</strong> administrational handling are vulnerable<br />

areas. Imagine that <strong>the</strong> application procedure and administrational handling turns out to<br />

be unacceptably lengthy. This would lead to that villagers get weary <strong>of</strong> waiting for <strong>the</strong><br />

promised certificates or for o<strong>the</strong>r instruments that are required to make use <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

empowered titles. Possibly, <strong>the</strong> district and village administrations will not succeed to<br />

build <strong>the</strong> registering structure <strong>the</strong> way it is required. The accuracy <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> registers will<br />

<strong>the</strong>refore fail to be reliable, which means that <strong>the</strong> registering instrument turns out to be<br />

more or less useless as foundation for land security. The reluctance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> banks to allow<br />

loans using land as security sparkles a wave <strong>of</strong> disapproval and distrust among <strong>the</strong><br />

villagers. This development spreads throughout <strong>the</strong> nation and smo<strong>the</strong>rs <strong>the</strong> initial public<br />

enthusiasm towards <strong>the</strong> possibilities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land acts. The certificates show to be <strong>of</strong><br />

almost no real value and hardly any villagers are any longer interested in achieving <strong>the</strong>m.<br />

Instead, people are consciously avoiding participating in <strong>the</strong> fulfilment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong><br />

<strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>. The villagers return to act <strong>the</strong> way <strong>the</strong>y are used to when handling trade and<br />

dispositions <strong>of</strong> land. Being deeply frustrated by <strong>the</strong> situation, <strong>the</strong> government decides to<br />

interpret <strong>the</strong> obscure phrase defining general land strongly at <strong>the</strong> expense <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> villages.<br />

Previously communally held, “unoccupied or unused village land“ is being withdrawn<br />

<strong>the</strong> influence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> village councils and instead incorporated into <strong>the</strong> general-land<br />

category, and placed directly under <strong>the</strong> authority <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> commissioner for lands.<br />

Finally, even if none <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se hazards will be fulfilled, and <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> turns out<br />

to be very successful, <strong>the</strong>re will still be a constant struggle to prevent and avoid<br />

opportunities for corruption and misuse <strong>of</strong> powerful positions, especially as <strong>the</strong> law<br />

supports strong top-down devolution <strong>of</strong> authority.<br />

Concluding thoughts<br />

According to Ms Wily, <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian land acts are basically sound. She even goes on to<br />

call <strong>the</strong>m “The best land law passed in Africa in terms <strong>of</strong> ´vesting authority and control<br />

over land at <strong>the</strong> local level´“. (Palmer, 1999) Whe<strong>the</strong>r this is true or not, will be for <strong>the</strong><br />

future to examine. Also many o<strong>the</strong>r presumptions connected to <strong>the</strong> land legislation have<br />

to be passed through reality, before it is possible to know how <strong>the</strong>y will actually be<br />

received. The cited interviews reflect <strong>the</strong> positions and ideas <strong>of</strong> a limited number <strong>of</strong><br />

individuals. They draw conclusions from <strong>the</strong>ir bases <strong>of</strong> knowledge, experience and points<br />

<strong>of</strong> view. Despite this inherent subjectivity, it is likely indisputable that <strong>the</strong> decisive<br />

factors <strong>of</strong> success for <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> will be: i) <strong>the</strong> future decisions and policies <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> national leadership: ii) <strong>the</strong> collective choices and actions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> villagers <strong>the</strong>mselves,<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r to support <strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> or to reject it; iii) <strong>the</strong> factors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> surrounding<br />

world, that like previous land reforms will influence <strong>the</strong> financial environment in which<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>implementation</strong> is being launched.<br />

Finally, every country has its individual specifics. Moreover, <strong>the</strong>re are even to some<br />

extent differences within <strong>the</strong> country itself, which makes any land legislation an<br />

inherently national issue. It is possible to learn from <strong>the</strong> experiences and mistakes <strong>of</strong><br />

o<strong>the</strong>r nations, but <strong>the</strong> national law itself will have to meet country-specific issues, and be<br />

adapted to country-specific conditions and problems. The previous <strong>Land</strong> Ordinance was<br />

put upon Tanzania from above, creating a legal framework that never fully recognised<br />

large parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Tanzanian country specifics. In this aspect, <strong>the</strong> land acts seem to be<br />

67


etter tailored, although it is also criticised for having obvious weaknesses. A relevant<br />

factor in this discussion is that this important piece <strong>of</strong> legislation is created in a<br />

democratic environment, and will <strong>the</strong>refore be able to be fur<strong>the</strong>r moulded through <strong>the</strong><br />

coming years <strong>of</strong> public debate. Counted as work-pieces, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> and <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong><br />

<strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> are undoubtedly indicating a promising future for Tanzania.<br />

68


8. References<br />

Published literature<br />

Fitzpatrick, M. 2002, Tanzania. Lonely Planet, Victoria (Australia)<br />

Friis-Hansen, E. 1986, Changes in land tenure and land use since villagisation and <strong>the</strong>ir impact on peasant<br />

agricultural production in Tanzania. Centre for Development Research, Copenhagen & Dar es Salaam<br />

Havnevik, K. & Hårsmar, M. 1999, Diversified Future -An Institutional Approach to Rural Development in<br />

Tanzania, Almqvist & Wiksell International, Stockholm<br />

Hydén, G. 1972, Socialism och samhällsutveckling i Tanzania, Bo Cavefors Bokförlag<br />

James, R.W. 1971. <strong>Land</strong> Tenure and Policy in Tanzania, East African Publishing Bureau, Nairobi<br />

James, R.W. & Fimbo, G.M. 1973, Customary <strong>Land</strong> Law <strong>of</strong> Tanzania, East African Publishing Bureau, Dar<br />

es Salaam<br />

Lunden, P. 1990, Tanzania reiser seg, NORAD (Norway)<br />

Maliyamkono, T.L. & Bagachwa, M.S.D. 1990, The Second Economy in Tanzania, East African Studies,<br />

Heinemann, Nairobi<br />

Ndjovu, C.E. 2003. Compulsory Purchase in Tanzania, PhD <strong>the</strong>sis, Royal Institute <strong>of</strong> Technology (KTH),<br />

Stockholm<br />

Perry, M. 1997, Western Civilization -a Brief History. Houghton Mifflin, Boston<br />

Pejovich, S. 1990, The Economics <strong>of</strong> Property Rights: Towards a Theory <strong>of</strong> Comparative Systems, Kluwer<br />

Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, <strong>the</strong> Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands<br />

Wily, Liz A. 2003, Community-based land tenure management. International Institute for Environment and<br />

Development (IIED), Issue paper no.120, Tanzania<br />

Published articles<br />

Alchian, A. & Demsetz, H. 1973, The Property Rights Paradigm, The Journal <strong>of</strong> Economic History, Vol.13<br />

(March 1973:16-27)<br />

Bromley, D.W. 1992, The Commons, Common Property, and Environmental Policy, Environmental and<br />

Resource Economics, 2:1-17<br />

Demsetz, H. 1967, Toward a Theory <strong>of</strong> Property Rights, American Economic Review, 57 (May 1967:347-<br />

59)<br />

Hardin, G. 1968, The Tragedy <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Commons, Science, Vol 162:1243-48<br />

Nyerere, J.K. 1958, National Property. From: (1966), Freedom and Unity, a selection from writings and<br />

speeches 1952-1965, Oxford University Press, Dar es Salaam, pp.53-58<br />

Shaw, W.H. 2003, ´They Stole Our <strong>Land</strong>´: debating <strong>the</strong> expropriation <strong>of</strong> white farms in Zimbabwe, Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Modern African Studies, 41:1 (2003), pp 75-89<br />

69


Magazine and newspaper articles<br />

Kyaruzi, I. 2002, Poor legal framework hinders banking sector, Business Times (Dar es Salaam), 6 th <strong>of</strong><br />

September 2002, p.1<br />

Mweta, N. 2004, Setting out land sector policy priorities, reasons…, Business Times (Dar es Salaam), 27 th<br />

<strong>of</strong> February 2004, p.5<br />

Nevin, T. 2004, The Great Trek North, African Business, July 2004, pp.28-29<br />

Palmer, R. 1997, <strong>Land</strong> and <strong>the</strong> need for cooperation in East Africa, published in <strong>the</strong> East African, 10-16 th<br />

<strong>of</strong> March 1997<br />

Obtained under: oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/africa_east.htm<br />

Last visited: December 2005<br />

Shivji, I. (1999-1), Lift <strong>the</strong> Whip –Palaver: The <strong>Land</strong> Bills, published in The African (Tanzania Edition), 6 th<br />

<strong>of</strong> February 1999<br />

Obtained under: oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/africa_east.htm#Tanzania<br />

Last visited: December 2005<br />

Internet articles<br />

van den Brink, R. 2003, <strong>Land</strong> Policy and <strong>Land</strong> Reform in Sub-Saharan Africa: Consensus, Confusion and<br />

Controversy. Preliminary draft (April 2, 2003)<br />

Obtained under: oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/africa_gen.htm<br />

Last visited: December 2005<br />

Heldgaard, I, Portrait <strong>of</strong> Tanzania, MS<br />

Obtained under: tanzania.ms.dk/Tanzania/tanportuk.htm<br />

Last visited: February 2005<br />

Palmer, R. 1999, The Tanzanian <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>s, 1999; An Analysis <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Analyses, (March 1999)<br />

Obtained under: oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/africa_east.htm#Tanzania<br />

Last visited: December 2005<br />

Palmer, R. 1998, Oxfam GB´s <strong>Land</strong> Advocacy Work in Tanzania and Uganda: The End <strong>of</strong> an Era?<br />

Obtained under: oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/africa_east.htm#Tanzania<br />

Last visited: December 2005<br />

Palmer, R. 2000(1), Learning Lessons from <strong>Land</strong> Reform in Africa, publ. In ZERO Newsletter January.<br />

2000.<br />

Obtained under: oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/africa_gen.htm<br />

Last visited: December 2005<br />

Palmer, R. 2000(2), The World Bank,Civil Society and <strong>Land</strong> Reform,<br />

Obtained under: oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/africa_gen.htm<br />

Last visited: December 2005<br />

Quan, J. 2000, Box on <strong>the</strong> Evolution <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> World Bank´s <strong>Land</strong> Policy, from chapter <strong>of</strong> a book, Evolving<br />

<strong>Land</strong> Rights, Policy and Tenure in Africa, edited by Toulmin, E. & Quan, J., published by IIED and NRI<br />

Obtained under: oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/africa_gen.htm<br />

Last visited: December 2005<br />

Shivji, I. (1999-2), The <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>s 1999: A Cause for Celebration or a Celebration <strong>of</strong> a Cause?, Keynote<br />

address to <strong>the</strong> Workshop on <strong>Land</strong> held at Morogoro, 19-20 February 1999<br />

Obtained under: oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/africa_east.htm#Tanzania<br />

Last visited: December 2005<br />

70


Legislation<br />

<strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>, 1999, (<strong>Act</strong> No.4 <strong>of</strong> 1999), The United Republic <strong>of</strong> Tanzania, Tanzania<br />

<strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>, 1999, (<strong>Act</strong> No.5 <strong>of</strong> 1999), The United Republic <strong>of</strong> Tanzania, Tanzania<br />

Official documents<br />

Ministry <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong>s, Housing and Urban Development, 1994, Report <strong>of</strong> The Presidential Commission <strong>of</strong><br />

Inquiry Into <strong>Land</strong> Matters, Volume 1: <strong>Land</strong> Policy and <strong>Land</strong> Tenure Structure, Dar es Salaam, Tanzania<br />

Ministry <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong>s and Human Settlement Development, 1997, National <strong>Land</strong> Policy, 2 nd Edition, Dar es<br />

Salaam, Tanzania<br />

World Bank, 1974, <strong>Land</strong> Reform. World Bank Development Series. Washington D.C.<br />

Deininger, K. 2003, <strong>Land</strong> Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduction. World Bank and Oxford University<br />

Press<br />

Dissertations and academic material<br />

Chaula, A. 2004, Titling <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> in Tanzania, Dissertation, June 2004, UCLAS, Dar es Salaam<br />

Jafari et al, 2003, Issues in Implementing <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>, 1999 and <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>, 1999, Project<br />

Report, June 2003, UCLAS, Dar es Salaam<br />

Josefsson, E, and Åberg, P, 2005. An Evaluation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> Laws in Tanzania, Masters Thesis at <strong>the</strong> MSc<br />

Programme in Economics, Luleå University <strong>of</strong> Technology, Sweden<br />

Obtained under: http://epubl.ltu.se/1404-5508/2005/057/LTU-SHU-EX-05057-SE.pdf<br />

Last visited: December 2005<br />

Zainab, P. 2004, Capacity Building in Implementing <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> and <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> <strong>of</strong> 1999, Dissertation,<br />

June 2004, UCLAS, Dar es Salaam<br />

Workshop papers and o<strong>the</strong>r material<br />

Report on <strong>the</strong> Proceedings <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Symposium on Implementation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1999 <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>s, 1-2 nd March 2005,<br />

Courtyard Hotel, Dar es Salaam<br />

-Paper 1: Overview <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Status <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Implementation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1999 <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>s, by A.Msangi, Commissioner<br />

for <strong>Land</strong>s<br />

-Paper 2: Practical Experience in <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> <strong>of</strong> 1999, by E. Gayewi, Coordinator, Ujamaa<br />

Community Resources Trust (UCRT)<br />

-Paper 3: Strategic Plan for <strong>the</strong> Implementation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>s (SPILL) <strong>of</strong> 1999, by Pr<strong>of</strong>.Hayuma,<br />

Advisor to <strong>the</strong> Permanent Secretary <strong>of</strong> MLHSD<br />

-Paper 4: Community Based Experience <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Implementation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1999 <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>s, by C.Kipobota &<br />

G.Mafoe, Legal and Human Rights Centre (LHRC)<br />

-Paper 5: The 1999 <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> and <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong>: a technical analysis <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> practical implications <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Act</strong>s,by G.Sundet, REPOA<br />

Obtained under: oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/africa_east.htm#Tanzania<br />

Last visited: December 2005<br />

Palmer, R. 2004, <strong>Land</strong> as a Global Issue –A Luta Continua, Paper for Oxfam-Zambia Copperbelt<br />

Livelihoods Improvement Programme <strong>Land</strong> Workshop, 29-30 March 2004<br />

Obtained under: oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/africa_gen.htm<br />

Last visited: December 2005<br />

71


Quan, J. 2003, Reflections on <strong>the</strong> development policy environment for land and property rights, Workshop<br />

background paper (draft) prepared for <strong>the</strong> International Workshop on Fundamental Rights in Balance: New<br />

Ideas on <strong>the</strong> Rights to <strong>Land</strong>, Housing and Property, Institute <strong>of</strong> Development Studies, University <strong>of</strong><br />

Sussex, 16-18 October 2003<br />

Obtained under: oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/africa_gen.htm<br />

Last visited: December 2005<br />

Utrikespolitiska Institutet, <strong>Land</strong>guiden Tanzania, Kapitel: Politiskt system, Modern Historia, Ekonomi<br />

Obtained under: landguiden.se/pubCountryText.asp?country_id=166<br />

Last visited: October 2004<br />

Carney, D. & Boyd, C., DFID: <strong>Land</strong> Tenure, Key Sheets for Sustainable Livelihoods, April 1999<br />

Oral sources<br />

Interview 2004-12-04 with Mr Jonson Kami, Legal Expert within <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong> Implementation<br />

Task Force, Ministry <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong>s, Dar es Salaam<br />

Interview 2004-12-13 with Mr Fidelis Kashumba Mutakyamilwa, Chairman <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Village</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Act</strong><br />

Implementation Task Force, Ministry <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong>s, Dar es Salaam<br />

Interview 2004-12-14 :1 with Mr Israel Celestine Simba, <strong>Land</strong> Law Specialist at <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong><br />

Management and Valuation at <strong>the</strong> University College <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong> and Architectural Studies (UCLAS), Dar es<br />

Salaam<br />

Interview 2004-12-14 :2 with Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Wilbard T. Kombe, Department <strong>of</strong> Urban and Rural Planning,<br />

URP, at <strong>the</strong> University College <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong> and Architectual Studies (UCLAS), Dar es Salaam<br />

Interview 2004-12-17 with Pr<strong>of</strong>essor J.M. Lusugga Kironde, Department <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong> Management and<br />

Valuation, LMV, at <strong>the</strong> University College <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong> and Architectual Studies (UCLAS), Dar es Salaam<br />

Interview 2005-01-12 with Mr Bramsiden Laimos Sichone, District <strong>Land</strong> Officer in <strong>the</strong> Mbozi district,<br />

Mbeya region<br />

Interview 2005-01-13 :1 with Mr Simon Mbuzi, former <strong>Village</strong> Chairman (up to <strong>the</strong> December 2004<br />

elections) in <strong>the</strong> Halungu village, Mbozi district<br />

Interview 2005-01-13 :2 with Mr Stephan Mnozya, <strong>Village</strong> Chairman in <strong>the</strong> Halambo village, Mbozi<br />

district<br />

Interview 2005-01-31:1 with Mr Chedieli E. Mrutu, District <strong>Land</strong> Officer in <strong>the</strong> Babati district, Arusha<br />

region<br />

Interview 2005-01-31:2 with Mr Halifa Bou, <strong>Village</strong> Executive Officer in <strong>the</strong> Mwinkatsi village, Babati<br />

district<br />

72

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!