30.09.2014 Views

Tax Reform for Fairness, Simplicity and Economics Growth

Tax Reform for Fairness, Simplicity and Economics Growth

Tax Reform for Fairness, Simplicity and Economics Growth

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Volume I<br />

Overview<br />

Office of the Secretary <br />

Department of the Treasury<br />

November 1984


THESECRETARYOFTHETREASURY<br />

WASHINGTON DC 20220<br />

November 27, 1984<br />

Dear Mr. President: <br />

I am pleased to submit the Treasury Department's Report<br />

on Fundamental <strong>Tax</strong> Simplification <strong>and</strong> <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong> that you<br />

requested in your State of the Union address in January. It<br />

contains proposals <strong>for</strong> a broad-based income tax that would<br />

allow us to lower marginal tax rates <strong>for</strong> individuals by an<br />

average of 20 percent <strong>and</strong> the corporate rate from 46 percent<br />

to 33 percent. The proposals would make the tax system<br />

simpler, fairer, <strong>and</strong> more economically efficient.<br />

The present U.S. income tax is complex, it is <br />

inequitable, <strong>and</strong> it interferes with economic choices of <br />

households <strong>and</strong> businesses. It is also widely perceived to <br />

be unfair. Because this perception undermines taxpayer<br />

morale, it may be as important as the actual defects of the <br />

system. <br />

In your State of the Union address, you said: <br />

"To talk of meeting the present situation by increasing <br />

taxes is a B<strong>and</strong>-Aid solution which does nothing to cure <br />

an illness that has been coming on <strong>for</strong> half a century, <br />

to say nothing of the fact that it poses a real threat <br />

to economic recovery.... <br />

There is a better way: Let us go <strong>for</strong>ward with an<br />

historic re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>for</strong> fairness, simplicity <strong>and</strong> incentives<br />

<strong>for</strong> growth. I am asking Secretary Don Regan <strong>for</strong> a plan<br />

<strong>for</strong> action to simplify the entire tax code so all<br />

taxpayers, big <strong>and</strong> small, are treated more fairly.... I<br />

have asked that specific recommendations, .;onsistent<br />

with those objectives, be presented to me by December<br />

1984."<br />

Further we believe we have followed your m<strong>and</strong>ate of May<br />

1984 to design a sweeping <strong>and</strong> comprehensive re<strong>for</strong>m of the <br />

entire tax code. The Treasury Department study focused on <br />

four options: a pure flat tax, a modified flat tax, a tax <br />

on income that is consumed, <strong>and</strong> a general sales tax,<br />

including a value-added tax <strong>and</strong> retail sales taxes. <br />

iii


The objectives of our study included: lower marginal <br />

tax rates; reduced interference with private economic <br />

decisions; simplicity; revenues equal to those of the <br />

existing tax system; fairness <strong>for</strong> families; equal treatment <br />

of all sources <strong>and</strong> uses of income; an unchanged distribution <br />

of tax burdens across income classes; <strong>and</strong> encouragement to <br />

economic growth. <br />

We believe that our proposals <strong>for</strong> a modified flat tax <br />

best reconcile these competing objectives. They include <br />

some features that are similar to those in flat tax pro­<br />

posals that have been offered by members of Congress, but <br />

our proposals are much more comprehensive. <br />

The adoption of these re<strong>for</strong>ms should have far reaching<br />

<strong>and</strong> positive effects on the U.S. economy. Rate reductions <br />

of the magnitude we propose will open wide the doors of <br />

opportunity to those who are willing to work, to save <strong>and</strong> <br />

invest, arid to innovate. With investment decisions being<br />

determined by economic consequences, rather than by the tax <br />

system, capital will be allocated more efficiently across <br />

industries, <strong>and</strong> growth will accelerate. <br />

If tax re<strong>for</strong>m is not adopted, the complexities, inequities,<br />

<strong>and</strong> distortions of the present system will increase<br />

<strong>and</strong> continue to hinder our nation's progress. Moreover,<br />

taxpayer morale will continue to deteriorate, <strong>and</strong> the socalled<br />

tax gap will grow.<br />

The proposals presented in this Report <strong>for</strong>m an integrated<br />

package. In some cases neutrality between competing<br />

industries can be achieved only if the special preferences<br />

benefitting each industry are eliminated. In other cases,<br />

changes are mutually dependent <strong>and</strong> must occur together to<br />

avoid inequities, distortions, <strong>and</strong> extraordinarily complex<br />

administrative rules arid increased compliance costs to taxpayers.<br />

Most importantly, any change in the package inevitably<br />

means that the proposed rate structure must be<br />

redesigned in order to keep tax burdens constant -- in total<br />

<strong>and</strong> across income classes. Each credit, deduction or<br />

deferral of tax that is retained in current law means that<br />

tax rates higher than those proposed in the Report will be<br />

necessary to attain the same level of revenues, Moreover,<br />

if any special tax benefits are left intact, it will be more<br />

difficult to resist appeals by others <strong>for</strong> special treatment.<br />

These proposals are bold, <strong>and</strong> they will be controver­<br />

sial. Those who benefit from the current tax preferences<br />

that distort the use of our nation's resources, that compli­<br />

cate paying taxes <strong>for</strong> all of us, <strong>and</strong> that create inequities <br />

iv


<strong>and</strong> undermine taxpayer morale will complain loudly <strong>and</strong> seek <br />

support from every quarter. But a far greater number of <br />

Americans will benefit from the suggested rate reduction <strong>and</strong> <br />

simplification. The achievement of fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m <br />

-- <strong>and</strong> the manifest benefits it would entail -- will require<br />

extraordinary leadership.<br />

I am fully convinced that these proposals constitute the <br />

substance of tax simplification <strong>and</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m that this nation <br />

so badly needs. I look <strong>for</strong>ward to working with you <strong>and</strong> <br />

others to secure their enactment. <br />

Respectfully, <br />

Donald T. Regan <br />

The President <br />

The White House <br />

Washington, D.C.<br />

20500 <br />

V


Summary of Proposals <br />

Introduction <br />

The present U.S. tax system desperately needs simplification <strong>and</strong> <br />

re<strong>for</strong>m. It is too complicated, it is unfair, <strong>and</strong> it retards savings,<br />

investment, <strong>and</strong> economic growth. <br />

under the current progressive tax system, all taxpayers face <br />

higher marginal tax rates in order to make up <strong>for</strong> the revenue lost by <br />

numerous special preferences, exceptions, <strong>and</strong> tax shelters used by a <br />

relatively small number of taxpayers. <br />

AS a result, the tax system is complex <strong>and</strong> inequitable. It<br />

reduces economic incentives, hampers economic growth, <strong>and</strong> is perceived<br />

to be so unfair that taxpayer morale <strong>and</strong> voluntary compliance have<br />

been seriously undermined.<br />

As requested by President Reagan in his 1984 State of the Union<br />

Address, the Treasury Department has completed a thorough review of<br />

the U.S. tax system. This summary outlines the Department's<br />

proposals <strong>for</strong> a fundamental re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>and</strong> simplification of the income<br />

tax system which wouLd raise approximately the same amount of revenues<br />

as current law with lower tax rates imposed on a broader tax base.<br />

The Treasury Department is proposing a new income tax system<br />

which is broad-based, simple, <strong>and</strong> fair. It reflects the enormous <br />

public input generated by a series of public hearings held throughout<br />

the country. <br />

The Treasury Department's recommendation reflects the broad <br />

political consensus of the American people that the present system is <br />

too complicated <strong>and</strong> favors special interests at the expense of the <br />

general public. While much more comprehensive <strong>and</strong> far-reaching than <br />

other proposals, it resembles several plans <strong>for</strong> tax re<strong>for</strong>m advanced by<br />

members of Congress, especially the Kemp-Kasten <strong>and</strong> Bradley-Gephardt<br />

plans. This bipartisan congressional consensus augurs well <strong>for</strong> quick<br />

action by the Congress. <br />

<strong>Tax</strong> Simplification <strong>and</strong> <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong> <strong>for</strong> Individuals <br />

The Treasury Department proposals combine lower tax rates,<br />

increased personal exemptions, <strong>and</strong> zero bracket amounts with the <br />

repeal O L modification of a number of existing deductions, exclusions <br />

<strong>and</strong> credits. The proposal does not generally change the distribution <br />

of individual tax burden across income classes, though it does reduce <br />

tax burdens more than proportionally <strong>for</strong> taxpayers with the lowest <br />

incomes. <br />

vii


Rate Structure <br />

The Treasury Department proposal replaces the present 14 brackets<br />

of tax rates ranging from 11 to 50 percent with a simple three-bracket<br />

system with tax rates set at 15, 25 <strong>and</strong> 35 percent. (See Tables S-1<br />

<strong>and</strong> S-2.)<br />

<strong>Fairness</strong> <strong>for</strong> Families <br />

In order to provide greater fairness <strong>for</strong> families, the Treasury<br />

Department proposal will increase the personal exemption <strong>for</strong> all<br />

taxpayers <strong>and</strong> their dependents to $2,000 <strong>and</strong> increase the zero bracket<br />

amounts to $2,800 <strong>for</strong> singles, $3,800 <strong>for</strong> joint returns, <strong>and</strong> $3,500<br />

<strong>for</strong> heads of households.<br />

These adjustments will virtually eliminate from taxation families <br />

with incomes below the poverty level. The individual tax brackets,<br />

the personal exemption, <strong>and</strong> the zero bracket amount would continue to <br />

be indexed. <br />

Impact on Individuals <br />

Under the proposal, 78 percent of all taxpayers will experience<br />

either no tax change or a tax decrease, <strong>and</strong> 22 percent will face<br />

higher taxes. Of those facing a tax increase, more than half will<br />

experience a tax increase of less than one percent of income.<br />

On average, marginal tax rates will be reduced by about 20<br />

percent <strong>and</strong> individual tax liabilities will be reduced by an averaqe<br />

of 8.5 percent. Because of the increased tax-free threshold, the<br />

average tax reductions are greater at the bottom of the income scale.<br />

<strong>Tax</strong> liabilities of families with incomes below $10,000 will be reduced<br />

by an average of 32.5 percent, <strong>and</strong> the reduction in taxes <strong>for</strong> families<br />

with incomes of $10,000 to $15,000 will be 16.6 percent.<br />

Broadening the Base <br />

In order to broaden the base, simplify the tax system, <strong>and</strong> <br />

eliminate special preferences <strong>and</strong> abuses, the Treasury Department<br />

proposals would modify or repeal a number of itemized deductions,<br />

exclusions, <strong>and</strong> special tax credits. <br />

These changes generally involve special preferences which are not <br />

used by the majority of individual taxpayers <strong>and</strong> include various <br />

fringe benefits, wage replacement payments, preferred uses of income,<br />

business deductions <strong>for</strong> personal expenses such as entertainment, <strong>and</strong> <br />

other areas of abuse. <br />

For most taxpayers who do itemize deductions, the marginal rate <br />

reductions <strong>and</strong> the increased personal exemption will offset the <br />

benefits lost from the various proposed re<strong>for</strong>ms. However, those <br />

taxpayers who consistently make above-average use of deductions <strong>and</strong> <br />

exclusions to shelter their income in order to avoid paying a fair <br />

share of the tax burden will face an increase in taxes. <br />

viii


The Treasury Department proposal retains the existing itemized <br />

deductions above certain floors <strong>for</strong> medical expenses <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> casualty<br />

losses. <br />

The home mortgage interest deduction is retained <strong>for</strong> a taxpayer’s<br />

principal residence. Certain other interest deductions,<br />

includins consumer interest <strong>and</strong> interest on second homes, are allowed<br />

up to $5;000 in excess of investment income.<br />

The itemized deduction <strong>for</strong> charitable contributions is retained,<br />

but allowed only <strong>for</strong> charitable contributions in excess of two -percent<br />

of adjusted gross income.<br />

The deduction <strong>for</strong> contributions to an Individual Retirement<br />

Account is retained <strong>and</strong> increased from $2,000 to $2,500 per employee<br />

The current $250 spousal IRA limit would be increased to $2,500 <strong>for</strong><br />

spouses working in the home.<br />

The Social Security benefit exclusion, which generally excludes <br />

from taxation Social Security benefits, would be retained. <br />

The existing child care credit would be replaced with a child <br />

care deduction. <br />

The earned income tax credit would be retained <strong>and</strong> indexed <strong>for</strong> <br />

inflation. <br />

A new, single credit <strong>for</strong> the elderly, blind <strong>and</strong> disabled would be<br />

provided, <strong>and</strong> the current exclusions <strong>for</strong> workers’ compensation, <strong>and</strong><br />

?or black lung <strong>and</strong> certain veterans’ disability payments would be<br />

folded into the credit.<br />

The two-earner deduction, no longer necessary under the revised <br />

rate brackets, would be repealed. <br />

The current exclusions <strong>for</strong> employer-provided pension <strong>and</strong> profit-<br />

sharing plans are retained as are the treatment of certain hard-to-<br />

value fringe benefits specifically addressed in the Deficit Reduction <br />

Act Of 1984. <br />

The exclusion of health insurance benefits would be retained, but<br />

capped at $70 per month <strong>for</strong> singles <strong>and</strong> $175 per month <strong>for</strong> a family.<br />

This change would affect only about 30 percent of all employees with<br />

such plans.<br />

The special exclusion of group-term life insurance <strong>and</strong> the <br />

special treatment of cafeteria plans would be repealed, as would the <br />

exclusion of other employer-provided fringe benefits, such as <br />

educational benefits, legal services, <strong>and</strong> dependent care. <br />

The tax-exempt threshold <strong>for</strong> unemkloyment compensation, currently <br />

set at $18,000 <strong>for</strong> a joint return, would be repealed. It is not fair <br />

that those receiving unemployment compensation pay no tax, while those <br />

ix


with equal incomes who work pay tax. With the personal exemption <strong>and</strong> <br />

zero bracket amount increased to $11,800 <strong>for</strong> a family of four, the <br />

impact of this change on low <strong>and</strong> moderate income taxpayers would be <br />

minimal. <br />

Itemized deductions <strong>for</strong> all state <strong>and</strong> local taxes would be <br />

repealed. These deductions are claimed on only a minority of tax <br />

returns, <strong>and</strong> disproportionately benefit higher income individuals in <br />

high-tax states <strong>and</strong> localities. <br />

The use of business deductions <strong>for</strong> personal expenses would be <br />

curtailed. Deductions <strong>for</strong> entertainment would be denied, <strong>and</strong> deduc­<br />

tions <strong>for</strong> business meals would be limited. <br />

Income Distribution <br />

The Treasury Department proposals are designed to be basically<br />

neutral from a distributional point of view. The table below shows<br />

that the distribution of individual income tax burdens does not differ<br />

significantly from that under current law.<br />

Percent of Total Income <strong>Tax</strong>es Paid <br />

Income Class (0001 Current Law Treasury Proposal<br />

$ 0-10<br />

10-15<br />

15-20<br />

20-30<br />

30-50<br />

50-100<br />

100-200<br />

200+<br />

Average <strong>Tax</strong> Rates <br />

0.5% 0.3% <br />

1.8 1.6 <br />

3.3 3.1 <br />

10.3 10.2<br />

24.3 24.1<br />

32.8 33.1<br />

12.3 12.6<br />

14.9 15.0<br />

The proposed tax re<strong>for</strong>ms will reduce individual tax liabilities<br />

<strong>for</strong> all income classes by an average of 8.5 percent. However, those<br />

at the bottom of the income scale will receive substantial tax reductions,<br />

<strong>and</strong> those with incomes up to $50,000 will experience aboveaverage<br />

reductions in tax liability, as the following table shows.<br />

X


Average <strong>Tax</strong> Rate by Income Class <br />

Income Class (000) Current Law Treasury Proposal Change<br />

$ 0-10 1.4% 0.9% -32.5%<br />

10-15 3.2 2.7 1 -16.6<br />

15-20 4.6 4.0 -12.1<br />

20-30 6.2 5.7 - 9.1<br />

30-50 7.8 7.0 - 9.3<br />

50-100 9.4 8.7 - 7.4<br />

100-200 13.2 12.3 - 6.4<br />

200+ 20.9 19.3 - 8.0<br />

marginal <strong>Tax</strong> Rates <br />

The Treasury proposal would reduce marginal tax rates by an <br />

average of nearly 20 percent. Although marginal tax rates are reduced <br />

by a larger percent <strong>for</strong> those at the top, these income groups will <br />

experience smaller than average tax reductions, as shown in the <br />

preceding table. Marginal tax rates fall furthest at the top of the <br />

income distribution because that is where the tax base is increased by<br />

the largest fraction. <br />

Marginal <strong>Tax</strong> Rate by Income Class <br />

Income Class (000) Current Law Treasury Proposal Change<br />

$ 0-10 4.2% 3.7% -11.9%<br />

1045 9.4 8.5 - 9.6<br />

15-20 12.4 11.0 -11.3<br />

20-30 16 .O 14.0 -12.5<br />

30-50 20.9 16.5 -21.1<br />

50-100 27.6 22.1 -19.9<br />

100-200 37.5 30.5 -18.7<br />

200+ 46.1 33.2 -28.0<br />

<strong>Tax</strong> Simplification <br />

The Treasury proposal repeals or consolidates about 65 provisions<br />

in the tax Code. It eliminates the need <strong>for</strong> at least 16 tax <strong>for</strong>ms <strong>and</strong><br />

10 lines from the 1040 <strong>for</strong>m.<br />

The proposed changes will reduce the number of individual <br />

taxpayers who itemize their deductions from 36 percent to fewer than <br />

25 percent of all individual taxpayers. <br />

In addition, the Internal Revenue Service is proceeding to<br />

develop a return-free tax system. Under such a system, the IRS would,<br />

at the election of the taxpayer, compute the tax liability of most<br />

taxpayers based on withholding <strong>and</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mation reports. Institution<br />

of a return-free tax system could eliminate the actual filing of tax<br />

returns <strong>for</strong> half or more than half of all taxpayers.<br />

xi


<strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong> of Capital <strong>and</strong> Business Income <br />

The taxation of capital <strong>and</strong> business income in the United States <br />

is deeply flawed. It lacks internal consistency, <strong>and</strong> it is ill-suited <br />

to periods when inflation rates have varied <strong>and</strong> been unpredictable.<br />

It contains subsidies to particular <strong>for</strong>ms of investment that distort <br />

choices in the use of the nation's scarce capital resources. It <br />

provides opportunities <strong>for</strong> tax shelters that allow wealthy individuals <br />

to pay little tax, undermine confidence in the tax system, <strong>and</strong> further <br />

distort economic choices. Equity investment in the corporate sector <br />

is placed at a particular disadvantage by the double taxation of <br />

dividends. Resulting high marginal tax rates discourage saving,<br />

investment, invention, <strong>and</strong> innovation. Moreover, high marginal rates <br />

encourage ef<strong>for</strong>ts to obtain additional special tax benefits which, if <br />

successful, further erode the tax base <strong>and</strong> necessitate higher rates in <br />

a never-ending cycle. <br />

The Treasury Department's tax re<strong>for</strong>ms would rationalize the <br />

taxation of income from business <strong>and</strong> capital. An overriding objec­<br />

tive is to subject real economic income from all sources to the same <br />

tax treatment. <br />

Implementation of the re<strong>for</strong>ms proposed by the Treasury Department<br />

would cause improved reallocations of economic resources. The lower<br />

tax rates made possible by base-broadening <strong>and</strong> the more realistic<br />

rules <strong>for</strong> the measurement of income <strong>and</strong> calculation of tax liabilities<br />

will increase the attractiveness of industries that suffer under the<br />

weight of the current unfair <strong>and</strong> distortionary tax regime. Both<br />

established industries <strong>and</strong> new "high-tech" industries will benefit<br />

from tax re<strong>for</strong>m. But the ultimate beneficiaries will be the American<br />

public. No longer will the nation's scarce economic resources--its<br />

l<strong>and</strong>, its labor, its capital, <strong>and</strong> its inventive genius--be allocated<br />

by the tax system, instead of by market <strong>for</strong>ces. The result will be<br />

more productive investment, greater opportunities <strong>for</strong> employment, more<br />

useful output, <strong>and</strong> faster economic growth.<br />

Lower Corporate <strong>Tax</strong> Rates <br />

The Treasury Department's proposals would allow the corporate tax<br />

rate to be reduced to 33 percent. All corporations would be subject<br />

to this single rate, which is 2 percentage points below the proposed<br />

top individual rate.<br />

Capital Gains <br />

Capital gains on assets he16 <strong>for</strong> at least a prescribed period have <br />

long benefitted from preferential tax treatment. Partial exclusion of <br />

capital gains has been justified by the need to avoid taxing<br />

fictitious gains that merely reflect inflation. <br />

The Treasury Department approach to the inflation problem is more <br />

direct--<strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e more equitable <strong>and</strong> more neutral. Under it the <br />

xii


asis (original cost) of assets used in calculating gains would be<br />

adjusted <strong>for</strong> inflation, so that only real gains would be subject to<br />

tax. With this inflation adjustment <strong>and</strong> a rate structure with only a<br />

few wide income brackets in place, there would be little need <strong>for</strong><br />

preferential tax treatment of realized capital gains. Investment in<br />

capital assets will continue to enjoy the substantial benefits of<br />

deferral of tax until gains are realized. At even moderate rates of<br />

inflation, the taxation of real gains as ordinary income at the<br />

proposed rates is more generous than the taxation of nominal gains at<br />

the current preferential rates. The reduced rates proposed in this<br />

report would alleviate any problems of lock-in <strong>and</strong> bunching.<br />

Capital Consumption Allowances <br />

The investment tax credit (ITC) <strong>and</strong> the accelerated cost recovery <br />

system (ACRS) were introduced to stimulate investment <strong>and</strong> prevent<br />

capital consumption allowances from being eroded by inflation. Since <br />

the present tax system does not adjust the basis of depreoiable assets <br />

<strong>for</strong> inflation, these provisions were required to prevent confiscatory<br />

taxation of income from capital. <br />

At the lower rates of inflation prevailing today, the ITC <strong>and</strong> ACRS <br />

allow investment in depreciable assets to be recovered far more <br />

rapidly than under a neutral system of income taxation. As a result,<br />

the tax system favors industries that invest heavily in depreciable <br />

assets such as equipment over others such as high technology indus­<br />

tries, service industries, <strong>and</strong> the trade sector that invests more <br />

heavily in inventories. <br />

Because the advantages of the ITC <strong>and</strong> ACRS are "front-loaded,"<br />

these provisions are of relatively little value to new <strong>and</strong> rapidly<br />

growing firms or to ailing industries, neither of which can fully<br />

utilize their benefits. New firms are penalized <strong>and</strong> there are incen­<br />

tives <strong>for</strong> tax-motivated mergers. The result is reduced competitive­<br />

ness <strong>and</strong> less incentive <strong>for</strong> innovation. The front-loading of tax <br />

benefits also leads to the proliferation of tax shelters, many of <br />

which are abusive <strong>and</strong> create severe administrative burdens <strong>for</strong> the <br />

Internal Revenue Service. <br />

To assure that capital consumption allowances will be more nearly<br />

appropriate, regardless of the rate of inflation, the Treasury Depart­<br />

ment proposes that the investment tax credit be repealed, that the <br />

basis of depreciable assets be indexed <strong>for</strong> inflation, <strong>and</strong> that <br />

depreciation allowances <strong>for</strong> tax purposes be set to approximate<br />

economic depreciation. <br />

Relief <strong>for</strong> Double <strong>Tax</strong>ation of Dividends <br />

Under present law equity income originating in the corporate <br />

sector is taxed twice--first as corporate profits <strong>and</strong> then as divi­<br />

dends. This double taxation of dividends discourages saving <strong>and</strong> <br />

discriminates against investment in the corporate sector. The <br />

Treasury Department proposes that the United States do what many other <br />

xiii


developed countries do, continue to levy the corporate income tax on <br />

earnings that are retained, but provide partial relief from double <br />

taxation of dividends. The proposal allows corporations to deduct a <br />

portion of the dividends paid out of previously-taxed earnings. <br />

subsidies <strong>for</strong> Specific Industries <br />

Certain industries benefit from special tax preferences that have <br />

no place in a comprehensive income tax. These include the energy <strong>and</strong> <br />

financial sectors. Moreover, the exclusion of interest on bonds <br />

issued by state <strong>and</strong> local governments <strong>for</strong> private purposes detracts <br />

from the fairness of the tax system, as well as distorting capital<br />

flows. <br />

Energy<br />

To be consistent with the goal of increased reliance on <br />

free-market <strong>for</strong>ces underlying both this Administration's energy policy<br />

<strong>and</strong> these proposals <strong>for</strong> fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m, the Treasury<br />

Department proposes that expensing of intangible drilling costs <strong>and</strong> <br />

percentage depletion should be replaced by cost depletion. The <br />

proposed rules are identical to proposed changes in the general rules <br />

<strong>for</strong> income measurement <strong>for</strong> all multi-period production, which require <br />

cost capitalization in order to match deductions with taxable <br />

receipts. <br />

Consistent with our objective to make the tax system neutral, the <br />

Treasury Department proposes to accelerate the phase-out of the <br />

Windall Profits <strong>Tax</strong> to 1988. <br />

Financial Institutions <br />

The Treasury proposal repeals the preferential tax treatment <br />

available to most types of financial institutions. Besides being<br />

unfair <strong>and</strong> distortionary, relative to the taxation of the rest of the <br />

economy, these tax preferences create distortions within the financial <br />

sector that are inconsistent with the Administration's ef<strong>for</strong>ts to <br />

deregulate financial markets. Equity <strong>and</strong> neutrality dem<strong>and</strong> that all <br />

financial institutions be taxed uni<strong>for</strong>mly, on all of their net income. <br />

These special preferences are especially inappropriate in a world in <br />

which the corporate tax rate is lowered <strong>and</strong> both individuals <strong>and</strong> other <br />

corporations are taxed more nearly on their economic income. <br />

These special preferences are especially inappropriate in a world in <br />

which the corporate tax rate is lowered <strong>and</strong> both individuals <strong>and</strong> other <br />

corporations are taxed more nearly on their economic income. <br />

State <strong>and</strong> Local Government .Bonds <br />

Interest ord debt issued by state <strong>and</strong> local governments <strong>for</strong> public<br />

purposes, such as schools, roads <strong>and</strong> sewers ("public purpose municipal<br />

bonds"), has long been exempt from tax. State <strong>and</strong> local governments<br />

have recently axp<strong>and</strong>ed the use of tax-exempt bonds in ways that do not<br />

have any "public" purpose. Proceeds from tax-exempt bonds have been<br />

xiv


used <strong>for</strong> economic development (via industrial development bonds or<br />

IDBS), <strong>for</strong> low-interest mortgages on owner-occupied housing, <strong>for</strong><br />

student loans, <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> private hospital <strong>and</strong> educational facilities.<br />

In addition, state <strong>and</strong> local governments have routinely invested<br />

proceeds of tax-exempt bonds in higher-yielding taxable securities to<br />

earn arbitrage profits.<br />

The Treasury Department proposal would subject to tax the future<br />

issuance of all "private purpose" tax-exempt bonds <strong>and</strong> tighten the<br />

restrictions on arbitrage.<br />

The elimination of private purpose bonds should be of financial <br />

benefit to state <strong>and</strong> local governments. Reducing the volume of <br />

tax-exempt bonds will improve the market <strong>for</strong> public purpose bonds,<br />

thus reducing interest costs to governments. <br />

Curtailment of <strong>Tax</strong> Shelters<br />

As a result of the growth in tax shelter activity, there has been<br />

a significant erosion in the base of the Federal income tax, particularly<br />

among taxpayers with the highest incomes. Estimates from the<br />

1983 Treasury individual tax model indicate that partnership losses<br />

may shelter as much as $35 billion of all individual income from<br />

taxation. Roughly 82 percent of this total, or $28.6 billion in<br />

partnership losses were reported by taxpayers with gross incomes<br />

(be<strong>for</strong>e losses) of $100,000 or more, <strong>and</strong> 60 percent, or $21.0 billion,<br />

were reported by taxpayers with incomes in excess of $250,000. By<br />

comparison, these groups reported 9 percent <strong>and</strong> 4 percent, respectively,<br />

of all gross income be<strong>for</strong>e losses reported by individuals.<br />

Several of the Treasury Department's proposals--<strong>for</strong> example, lower<br />

tax rates, taxation of real capital gains as ordinary income, capital<br />

consumption allowances that approximate economic depreciation,<br />

indexing of net interest expense, matching expenses <strong>and</strong> receipts from<br />

multiperiod production, <strong>and</strong> tax treatment of certain large<br />

partnerships as corporations--will greatly reduce the attractiveness<br />

of tax shelters. Yet opportunities <strong>for</strong> tax shelters will remain,<br />

<strong>and</strong> several proposals are being made to further reduce these<br />

opportunities.<br />

xv


."..<br />

U<br />

c<br />

3<br />

0<br />

w n m d m<br />

m<br />

-<br />

n~<br />

mo<br />

xu<br />

4 mc<br />

0 E4 .3<br />

w<br />

rl<br />

m <br />

VI<br />

0 <br />

.... .. .. <br />

a<br />

0 4 m <br />

6% 0 <br />

a<br />

mo<br />

'i)<br />

C 114<br />

ma<br />

4 <br />

m<br />

2<br />

m<br />

c x<br />

+l 4 m ..<br />

a 0<br />

U U<br />

- c m 3<br />

f f i m<br />

A 2 C U<br />

4 5 4 c<br />

015 rl ma<br />

i o 0 44<br />

P c a 4<br />

m 4 m =a<br />

m u<br />

5 a<br />

C 0 .. ..<br />

3 X<br />

w<br />

VI<br />

W 0<br />

U a,<br />

m "a r l m<br />

ffi R E<br />

m m o<br />

x x x u<br />

m<br />

mc<br />

E4 hrl<br />

u1 <br />

0 <br />

C .. .I<br />

.I ..<br />

i <br />

0<br />

m<br />

"3 d ?<br />

4 a a<br />

m<br />

VI u)<br />

a a 0 m<br />

E u a m<br />

0 LI<br />

u 2: 3<br />

6%<br />

x a,<br />

m 1.<br />

C<br />

U<br />

Y<br />

3<br />

m ;<br />

CCI<br />

.3 c<br />

V I P m ?h<br />

c 44 m u<br />

4 m 4 Y "3<br />

I =a a 3<br />

U U 40<br />

m 001<br />

"I4"<br />

ffi m ulx<br />

w<br />

m<br />

rl WE4 .<br />

D<br />

A75<br />

E m Uw m<br />

.rl 3 m o u<br />

v) QE w m<br />

ow<br />

mo<br />

x u u 5<br />

mc w U<br />

E43 uw m<br />

I 3 w w<br />

Luo<br />

w \<br />

0 -I<br />

xv i


0 m m m<br />

d N m<br />

k<br />

5 l l l l l l l l l l l l l O<br />

0 m m m<br />

d N m<br />

L1 <br />

5 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0<br />

0 Ln m m<br />

4 N m<br />

000000000000000<br />

ddommmmr-wmmdmmrm<br />

P m o N PO m m w 's,N.,N,~.N GI<br />

.......I..<br />

.k<br />

~m-rr-md-rwmmdr-LnOmO<br />

v) dddd~mm-rwmg<br />

LA <br />

4 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0<br />

xvii


Comuarison of Current Law<br />

<strong>and</strong>-Treasury Proposal Highlights<br />

1986 Current Law Treasury Proposal<br />

INDIVIDUAL TAX RATES i4 rate brackets 3 rate brackets<br />

from 11 to 50% 15, 25 & 35%<br />

EXEMPTIONS<br />

Self, spouse<br />

Dependents<br />

$1,090<br />

$1,090<br />

$2,000<br />

$2,000<br />

$2,510 $2,800<br />

$3,710 $3,800<br />

$2,510 $3,500<br />

INDEXED RATE BRACKETS, Yes Yes<br />

EXEMPI'IONS AND ZBA<br />

PERSONAL DEDUCTIONS<br />

Mortgage Interest Yes Yes, <strong>for</strong> principal<br />

residences<br />

Other personal intecest Limited to $5.000<br />

over investment income<br />

Medical expenses Yes (above 5% of Yes (above 5% Of AGI)<br />

AGI)<br />

Charitable contributions Yes Yes (above 2% Of AGI) but<br />

no deduction <strong>for</strong><br />

unrealized gains on contributed<br />

property.<br />

State <strong>and</strong> local income tax Yes NO<br />

Other State <strong>and</strong> local Yes NO, unless incurred in<br />

taxes<br />

income-producing activity I<br />

Iwo-earner deduction Yes NO<br />

OI'IiER INDIVIDUAL IIEMS<br />

Earned Income Credit Yes Yes, indexed<br />

Child Care Credit Yes Deduction<br />

Unemployment Compensation <strong>Tax</strong>ed if AGI over <strong>Tax</strong>ed<br />

$12.000 ($18,000<br />

if marcied)<br />

Workers' Compensation Not taxed <strong>Tax</strong>ed, but eligible <strong>for</strong><br />

special credit <strong>for</strong> elderly<br />

<strong>and</strong> disabled<br />

Entertainment expenses Deducted NO<br />

Business Meals <strong>and</strong><br />

Deducted<br />

Capped<br />

Travel Expenses<br />

Income shifting<br />

to children <strong>and</strong><br />

Pemissible Curtailed<br />

via trusts<br />

xviii


RETIREMENT SAVINGS<br />

IRA<br />

spousal IRA<br />

$2,000 $2,500 <br />

$ 250 $2,500 <br />

corporate pensions<br />

social Security<br />

FRINGE BENEFITS<br />

Health insurance<br />

Group life <strong>and</strong> legal<br />

insurance<br />

CAPITAL AND BUSINESS INCOME<br />

Corporate <strong>Tax</strong> Rates<br />

<strong>Tax</strong> deferred<br />

Generally not taxed<br />

Excluded<br />

Excluded<br />

Graduated, up to 46%<br />

<strong>Tax</strong> deferred <br />

Generally not taxed <br />

Capped Exclusion <br />

<strong>Tax</strong>ed <br />

33% flat rate<br />

Dividend relief<br />

$lOO/ZOO exclusion Exclusion repealed: 50%<br />

dividend-paid deduction<br />

Depreciation<br />

ACRS<br />

Economic depreciation,<br />

indexed<br />

Investment <strong>Tax</strong> Credit<br />

' capital gains<br />

6% - 10% Repealed<br />

60% excluded Indexed, taxed as ordinary<br />

income<br />

Interest income/expense<br />

Rehabilitation <strong>and</strong> energy<br />

credits<br />

Inventory accounting<br />

LIFO con<strong>for</strong>mity required<br />

FIFO<br />

Uni<strong>for</strong>m production<br />

cost rules<br />

Bad debt reserve<br />

deduction<br />

Installment sales<br />

OIL INDUSTRY<br />

Percentage depletion<br />

Expensing of intangible<br />

drilling costs<br />

Windfall profits tax<br />

FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS<br />

special bad debt deduction<br />

Deduction or interest<br />

to carry tax-exempts<br />

Exemption of credit<br />

unions<br />

Fully taxed/deducted.<br />

Yes<br />

Yes <br />

Not Indexed <br />

NO<br />

Yes<br />

Deferral<br />

Yes<br />

Yes<br />

Yes<br />

Yes<br />

Yes<br />

Yes<br />

Indexed, partially<br />

excludable/nondeductible <br />

NO<br />

NO<br />

Indexed<br />

Yes<br />

NO<br />

No deferral if<br />

receivables pledged<br />

No: Indexed cost<br />

depletion<br />

NO<br />

Accelerate phase-out<br />

NO<br />

NO<br />

NO<br />

Deferral <strong>for</strong> life insurance Yes<br />

investment income <strong>and</strong><br />

annuity income<br />

NO<br />

MUNICIPAL. BONDS<br />

Public purpose<br />

rax-exempt<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>-exempt<br />

Private purpose <strong>Tax</strong>-exempt <strong>Tax</strong>ed<br />

xix


summary of proposals<br />

TABLE OF CONTENTS <br />

Volume One <br />

Page <br />

vi i <br />

Chapter 1: THE NEED FOR TAX REFORM: BACK TO BASICS 1<br />

The Federal Income <strong>Tax</strong> in 1954 <br />

The Decline in <strong>Simplicity</strong><br />

Erosion of the <strong>Tax</strong> Base <br />

Economic Distortions <br />

Inequities 5<br />

Unfair Treatment of the Family 5<br />

Inflation <strong>and</strong> the Income <strong>Tax</strong> 6<br />

The Rise of <strong>Tax</strong> Shelters 6<br />

The Decline in <strong>Tax</strong>payer Morale 9<br />

Needed: <strong>Tax</strong>es That are Broad-based,<br />

Simple, <strong>and</strong> Fair<br />

11 <br />

Chapter 2: GOALS OF FUNDAMENTAL TAX REFORM 13<br />

Economic Neutrality 13<br />

Lower <strong>Tax</strong> Rates 13<br />

Revenue Neutrality 14<br />

Equal Treatment of Equals 14<br />

<strong>Fairness</strong> <strong>for</strong> Families 14<br />

<strong>Fairness</strong> Across Income Classes 14<br />

<strong>Simplicity</strong> 15<br />

Perceived <strong>Fairness</strong> 16<br />

An Inflation-Proof <strong>Tax</strong> Law 17<br />

Neutrality Toward Business Form 10<br />

Economic <strong>Growth</strong> 10<br />

Trade-offs 10<br />

Fair <strong>and</strong> Orderly Transition 19<br />

Addendum: Implications <strong>for</strong> Spending 20<br />

Chapter 3: THE FOUR OPTIONS 21<br />

I. The Pure Flat <strong>Tax</strong> . 21<br />

A. Advantages of the Flat <strong>Tax</strong> 21<br />

B. Distributional Inequity of the Pure Flat <strong>Tax</strong> 21<br />

11. Reconcili,ation: The Modified Flat <strong>Tax</strong> 23<br />

A. Questions Common to Income <strong>and</strong> Consumed Income<br />

<strong>Tax</strong> 25<br />

8. Advantages of a Comprehensive Measure of<br />

Income 25<br />

C. Distributional Neutrality 26<br />

D. Issues in Income Measurement 26<br />

xxi


Page <br />

E. Disparities in Effective <strong>Tax</strong> Rates 21 <br />

F. Simplification 28 <br />

111. Consumed Income <strong>Tax</strong> 30 <br />

A. Administrative Advantages 30 <br />

B. Economic Advantages 31 <br />

C. Transition Problems 31 <br />

D. Perception Problems 32 <br />

E. Complexity <strong>for</strong> Individuals 32 <br />

F. The Dilemma of Gifts <strong>and</strong> Bequests 33 <br />

G. International Aspects 33 <br />

IV. Sales <strong>Tax</strong><br />

33 <br />

Chapter 4: SUMMARY OF TREASURY DEPARTMENT PROPOSALS <br />

AND THEIR EFFECTS<br />

31 <br />

I. The Proposals in Brief 31 <br />

A. Individuals 31 <br />

B. <strong>Tax</strong>ation of Capital <strong>and</strong> Business Income 40 <br />

C. Economic Effects 42 <br />

D. Transition 43 <br />

11. Effects on Revenues 44 <br />

111. Effects on Income Distribution <strong>and</strong> Incentives 46 <br />

APPENDIX 4-A: Explanation of Concept of Economic Income<br />

Used in Distribution Tables 51<br />

APPENDIX 4-B: Provisions Included in the Distributional <br />

Analysis in Tables 4-3 <strong>and</strong> 4-4<br />

Chapter 5: INCOME TAX REFORM AND SIMPLIFICATION FOR <br />

INDIVIDUALS AND FAMILIES<br />

61 <br />

63 <br />

I. Summary 63 <br />

11. Rate Reduction 63 <br />

111. <strong>Fairness</strong> <strong>for</strong> Families 66 <br />

IV. Fair <strong>and</strong> Neutral <strong>Tax</strong>ation 73 <br />

A. Excluded Sources of Income 13 <br />

1. <br />

2. <br />

3. <br />

4. <br />

5.<br />

6. <br />

I.<br />

Fringe Benefits 13<br />

Retirement Savings 74<br />

Wage Replacements 75<br />

Scholarships <strong>and</strong> Fellowships 76<br />

Capital Gains<br />

I6<br />

Interest Indexing<br />

I1<br />

Dividends Received Exclusion<br />

I1<br />

B. Preferred Uses of Income I7<br />

1. State <strong>and</strong> Local <strong>Tax</strong>es 78 <br />

2. Charitable Contributions 81 <br />

3. Interest Expense 83 <br />

4. Simplification Benefits 83 <br />

xxii


Page <br />

C. Abuses 84 <br />

1. Mixed Personal <strong>and</strong> Business Expenses 84 <br />

2. Income Shifting 85 <br />

IV. Simplification 86 <br />

A. A Return-Free System 86 <br />

B. Other Simplification <strong>for</strong> Individuals 86 <br />

V. Reducing Noncompliance ai <br />

A. The <strong>Tax</strong> Gap 87 <br />

B. Amnesties 91 <br />

APPENDIX 5-A: List of Proposed <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong>s: Income <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

<strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong> <strong>and</strong> Simplification <strong>for</strong> Individuals<br />

93 <br />

Chapter 6:<br />

BASIC TAXATION OF CAPITAL AND BUSINESS INCOME 97 <br />

I. Summary 97 <br />

11. Lower Corporate <strong>Tax</strong> Rates 97 <br />

111. <strong>Tax</strong>ing Real Economic Income 98 <br />

A. Capital Gains 100 <br />

8. Capital Consumption Allowances 105 <br />

C. Inventories 109 <br />

D. Indexing Interest 111 <br />

IV. Retirement Savings<br />

116 <br />

V. Neutrality Toward Form of Business Organization 117 <br />

A. Relief <strong>for</strong> Double <strong>Tax</strong>ation of Dividends 118 <br />

8. <strong>Tax</strong> Treatment of Large Partnerhips 120 <br />

APPENDIX 6-A: List of Proposed <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong>s: Basic <strong>Tax</strong>ation of <br />

Capital <strong>and</strong> Business Income<br />

123 <br />

Chapter 7:<br />

INDLJSTRIES - SPECIFIC SUBSIDIES, TAX SHELTERS,<br />

AND OTHER TAX ISSUES<br />

125 <br />

I. Introduction 125 <br />

11. General Issues of Income Measurement 126 <br />

A. Multiperiod Production 126 <br />

9. Use of Cash Method of Accounting 128 <br />

C. Bad Debt Deductions 129 <br />

D. Installment Sales 129 <br />

E. Corporate Minimum <strong>Tax</strong> 130 <br />

111. Subsidies <strong>for</strong> Specific Industries 130 <br />

A. Energy <strong>and</strong> Other Minerals 130 <br />

9. Financial Institutions 132 <br />

C. Debt of State <strong>and</strong> Local Governments 135 <br />

D. Special Rules 137 <br />

IV. Further Curtailment of <strong>Tax</strong> Shelters<br />

138 <br />

A. Limiting Interest Deductions 140 <br />

B. At-Risk Rul.es 141 <br />

V. International Issues 142 <br />

xxiii


Page <br />

VI. Other <strong>Tax</strong> Issues 144<br />

A. Transfer <strong>Tax</strong>ation 144<br />

B. Penalties 146<br />

C. Expiring Provisions 146<br />

D. Social Security Issues 146<br />

E. Items Not Included in the <strong>Tax</strong> <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong> Proposal 147<br />

APPENDIX I-A: List of Proposed <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong>s: Industry-Specific<br />

Subsidies, <strong>Tax</strong> Shelters <strong>and</strong> Other <strong>Tax</strong> Issues 149<br />

Chapter 8: COMPARISON WITH OTHER TAX REFORM PLANS 153<br />

I. Individual Income <strong>Tax</strong> 154<br />

A. Income <strong>Tax</strong> Rates 154<br />

8. <strong>Fairness</strong> <strong>for</strong> Families 154<br />

C. Fair <strong>and</strong> Neutral <strong>Tax</strong>ation 156<br />

1. Excluded Sources of Income 156<br />

2. Preferred Uses of Income 151<br />

D. <strong>Tax</strong> Abuses 158<br />

E. Simplification 158<br />

1. The Return-Free System 159<br />

2. Other Simplification 158<br />

11. Basic <strong>Tax</strong>ation of Business <strong>and</strong> Capital Income 159<br />

A. Corporate <strong>Tax</strong> Rates 159<br />

8. Investment <strong>Tax</strong> Credit 160<br />

C. Income Measurement: Inflation Adjustment 160<br />

D. Retirement Savings 161<br />

E. Neutrality Toward Form of Business<br />

Organization 162<br />

111. Industry - Specific Subsidies, <strong>Tax</strong> Shelters, <strong>and</strong><br />

Other <strong>Tax</strong> Issues 163<br />

A. General Issues of Income Measurement 163<br />

B. Subsidies to Specific Industries 164<br />

1. Energy <strong>and</strong> Natural Resources 164 <br />

2. Financial Institutions 165<br />

3. Insurance Investment Income 165<br />

4. State <strong>and</strong> Local Debt <strong>and</strong> Investments 165<br />

5. Other Specific Subsidies 166<br />

C. Further Curtailment of <strong>Tax</strong> Shelters 166<br />

D. International Issues 166<br />

IV. Other <strong>Tax</strong> Issues 16 7<br />

A. <strong>Tax</strong>ation of Transfers 16 '7<br />

8. Expiring Provisions 168<br />

APPENDIX 8-A: Comparison of Treasury Proposal with<br />

Congressional <strong>Tax</strong> <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong> Bills 169<br />

APPENDIX 8-B: Summary of <strong>Tax</strong> <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong> Bills Introduced<br />

During the 98th Congress 185<br />

xxiv


Chapter 9: CONSUMED INCOME TAX<br />

Page <br />

191 <br />

I. Consumed Income <strong>Tax</strong> Base, Rates, <strong>and</strong> <br />

Administration<br />

192 <br />

A. The <strong>Tax</strong> Base 192 <br />

B. <strong>Tax</strong> Rates 194 <br />

C. Administration 194 <br />

11. Advantages of A Consumed Income <strong>Tax</strong> 195 <br />

A. Administrative Advantages 195 <br />

B. Economic Advantages 198 <br />

C. Equity Advantages 199 <br />

111. Disadvantages of a Consumed Income <strong>Tax</strong> 200 <br />

A. Administrative Disadvantages 200 <br />

B. Economic Disadvantages 205 <br />

C. Equity Disadvantages 209 <br />

D. Transition Problems 210 <br />

IV. Conclusions<br />

211 <br />

Chapter 10: VALUE-ADDED TAX AND RETAIL SALES TAX<br />

213 <br />

I. Introduction 213 <br />

11. Alternative Forms of Sales <strong>Tax</strong> 213 <br />

A. Retail Sales <strong>Tax</strong> 213 <br />

B. Value-Added <strong>Tax</strong> 214 <br />

C. Advantages of Uni<strong>for</strong>m Rates 216 <br />

D. Sales <strong>Tax</strong>es unworthy of Consideration 211 <br />

111. Pros <strong>and</strong> Cons of a National Sales <strong>Tax</strong> 219 <br />

A. Advantages of a Sales <strong>Tax</strong> 219 <br />

B. Disadvantages of a Sales <strong>Tax</strong> 220 <br />

1. <strong>Growth</strong> of Government 220 <br />

2. Regressivity 221 <br />

3. Effect on Prices 221 <br />

4. Administrative Costs 221 <br />

5. Federal Pre-Emption 221 <br />

IV. Relevance of the European Experience<br />

222 <br />

v. <strong>Tax</strong> Base <strong>and</strong> Revenue Potential 222 <br />

VI. Reducing Regressivity<br />

223 <br />

VII. Value-Added <strong>Tax</strong> versus Retail Sales <strong>Tax</strong><br />

224 <br />

vIII.Implementation<br />

226 <br />

IX. Conclusions<br />

226 <br />

APPENDIX A: Effective Dates <strong>and</strong> Transition Rules 229 <br />

APPENDIX B:<br />

Fundamental <strong>Tax</strong> <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong>: <br />

Change in Receipts by Source<br />

APPENDIX C: summary of International Comparisons<br />

xxv<br />

245 <br />

255


Page <br />

TABLES <br />

1-1 <br />

3-1 <br />

3-2 <br />

3-3<br />

4-1 <br />

4-2 <br />

4-3 <br />

4-4 <br />

4A-1 <br />

5-1 <br />

5-2 <br />

5-3 <br />

5-4 <br />

5-5 <br />

6-1 <br />

How <strong>Tax</strong> Shelter Losses Reduce Gross Income <br />

Percentage Distributions of Individual Income <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

Liability Under Current Law, Pure Flat <strong>Tax</strong> <strong>and</strong> <br />

the Treasury Department Proposal, by Economic <br />

Income Class of Families <br />

Changes in <strong>Tax</strong> Resulting from a Pure Flat <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

<strong>and</strong> the Treasury Department Propsoal Distributed <br />

by Family Economic Income Class <br />

Illustration of Gisparities in Effective <strong>Tax</strong><br />

Rates<br />

Proposed <strong>Tax</strong> Rates <strong>for</strong> 1986 <br />

Unified Budget Receipts <br />

Distribution of Adjusted Gross Income, <strong>Tax</strong>able <br />

Income, Income <strong>Tax</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>Tax</strong> Rates Under Present <br />

Law <strong>and</strong> Under <strong>Tax</strong> <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong> Proposal <br />

Distributio of Families by Change in <strong>Tax</strong> as <br />

a Percent of Income Comparing the <strong>Tax</strong> <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong> <br />

Proposal with 1986 Present Law <br />

Economic Income Equals <br />

Proposed <strong>Tax</strong> Rate Schedule <strong>and</strong> 1986 Current <br />

Law Rate Schedules <br />

Comparision of Personal Exemptions <strong>and</strong> Zero <br />

Bracket Amounts Under Current Law <strong>and</strong> Treasury<br />

Proposal <br />

Comparision of the Poverty Threshold <strong>and</strong> the <br />

<strong>Tax</strong> Free Level of Income Under Current Law <br />

<strong>and</strong> the Treasury Proposal <br />

Floors <strong>for</strong> Deductions on Individual Income <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

Returns <br />

Income <strong>Tax</strong> Gap -- 1981<br />

Effective <strong>Tax</strong> Rates or. Realized Capital Gains<br />

Under Current Law <strong>for</strong> 50 Percent Bracket<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>payer with Different Real Rate of Return<br />

Assumptions<br />

10 <br />

22 <br />

24 <br />

29 <br />

38 <br />

45 <br />

41 <br />

54 <br />

59 <br />

65 <br />

67 <br />

'70<br />

79 <br />

88 <br />

103 <br />

xxvi


Page <br />

6-2 <br />

6-3 <br />

6-4 <br />

6-5 <br />

676 <br />

6-7 <br />

7-1 <br />

10-1 <br />

A- 1 <br />

c-1 <br />

Effective <strong>Tax</strong> Rates on Equity-Financed<br />

Investments with Various Rates of Inflation <br />

For a 46 Percent <strong>Tax</strong>payer Under Current Law <br />

Effective <strong>Tax</strong> Rates on Equity Finance Investments <br />

in Equipment <strong>and</strong> Structures by Industry with <br />

Various Rates of Inflation <strong>for</strong> a 46 Percent <br />

<strong>Tax</strong>payer Under Current Law <br />

Effective Corporate <strong>and</strong> Personal Income <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

Rates on Equity Financed Investment <br />

Effective Corporate Income <strong>Tax</strong> Rates <br />

Inventories as Percent of Total Physical Assets <br />

<strong>and</strong> Depreciable Assets <br />

Fractional Exclusion Rate Table <br />

Effective <strong>Tax</strong> Rate on Income Deferred by a <br />

50 Percent <strong>Tax</strong>payer <strong>for</strong> Different Deferral <br />

Periods <strong>and</strong> Interest Rates <br />

Illustration of a Retail Sales <strong>Tax</strong> <strong>and</strong> a <br />

Value-Added <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

Effective Dates <strong>and</strong> Transition Rules <br />

Summary Comparision of Selected Aspects of <br />

Different Countries' <strong>Tax</strong> Systems <br />

107 <br />

108 <br />

110 <br />

112 <br />

113 <br />

115 <br />

127 <br />

215 <br />

233 <br />

258 <br />

xxvii


FIGURES <br />

Page <br />

1-1 <strong>Growth</strong> in Partnerships, 1965-1982 8<br />

4-1 Average Rates of <strong>Tax</strong> on Family Economic<br />

Income Under Current Law <strong>and</strong> the Proposal 48<br />

4-2 Percent Change in <strong>Tax</strong> Under the Proposal by<br />

Family Economic Income 49<br />

4-3 Marginal Rates of <strong>Tax</strong> Under Current Law <strong>and</strong><br />

the Proposal 51<br />

4-4 Percentage Change in <strong>Tax</strong>able Income Resulting<br />

From the Treasury Proposal 52<br />

4-5 Families With <strong>Tax</strong> Change as a Percent of All<br />

Families by Family Economic Income 55<br />

4A-1 Distribution of <strong>Tax</strong> Returns by Adjusted Gross<br />

Income Class <strong>and</strong> Families by Economic Income Class 60<br />

5-1 Comparison of <strong>Tax</strong> Free Income Levels Under<br />

Current Law <strong>and</strong> Under the Proposal -- For<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>payers Under Age 65 68<br />

5-2 Comparison of <strong>Tax</strong> Free Income Levels Under<br />

Current Law (1986) <strong>and</strong> Under the Proposal --<br />

For <strong>Tax</strong>payers Under <strong>and</strong> Over Age 65 12<br />

7-1 Volume of Long Term <strong>Tax</strong>-Exempt Bonds Issued<br />

in 1983 136<br />

9-1 Lifetime Pattern of Income <strong>and</strong> Consumption<br />

(Average Income <strong>and</strong> Consumption, Distributed<br />

by Age of Family Head) 207<br />

xxviii


Chapter 1 <br />

THE NEED FOR TAX REFORM: BACK TO BASICS<br />

The present income tax is badly in need of fundamental <br />

simplification <strong>and</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m. It is too complicated, it is unfair, <strong>and</strong> <br />

it interferes with economic choices <strong>and</strong> retards saving, investment <strong>and</strong> <br />

growth. <br />

In a real sense, the U.S. income tax has grown without any<br />

conscious design or overall planning since it was enacted in 1913. It<br />

was originally imposed at low rates <strong>and</strong> applied to fewer than 400,000<br />

individuals with very high incomes. The need to finance World War I1<br />

<strong>and</strong> exp<strong>and</strong>ed non-defense expenditures turned the individual income tax<br />

into a levy paid by most Americans. <strong>Tax</strong> rates were increased during<br />

World War 11, <strong>and</strong> at their peak individual income tax rates reached 94<br />

percent. The original income tax had serious flaws, <strong>and</strong> while some of<br />

these have been corrected over time, others have grown worse. With<br />

over 90 million individual tax returns now being filed, it is<br />

important to address these problems.<br />

It is one thing to decide to tax "income," <strong>and</strong> quite another to<br />

decide how to define taxable income. If inadequate attention is<br />

devoted to establishing a uni<strong>for</strong>m <strong>and</strong> consistent definition of income,<br />

some sources <strong>and</strong> uses of income will escape tax, <strong>and</strong> others will be<br />

taxed twice, as in the United States. The result may or may not be a<br />

simple tax system, but it is certain that the tax system will contain<br />

inequities <strong>and</strong> interfere with the economic behavior of taxpayers.<br />

The U.S. income tax is not used simply to raise revenue. Instead,<br />

it is used to subsidize a long list of economic activities through<br />

exclusions from income subject to tax, adjustments to income,<br />

business deductions unrelated to actual expenses, deferral of tax<br />

liability, deductions <strong>for</strong> personal consumption expenditures, tax<br />

credits, <strong>and</strong> preferential tax rates. In some cases, deviations from a<br />

comprehensive definition of income originated in incomplete<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the concept of income or in outmoded ideas about the<br />

proper fiscal relationship between the Federal Government <strong>and</strong> state<br />

<strong>and</strong> local governments. But whatever its origin, in many cases bad<br />

public policy has become accepted -- virtually enshrined -- as<br />

appropriate.<br />

For seven decades, the Treasury Department has fought to protect<br />

Federal revenues <strong>and</strong> the fairness <strong>and</strong> economic neutrality of the tax <br />

system from those seeking to create <strong>and</strong> exploit gaps <strong>and</strong> <br />

inconsistencies in the definition of taxable income. As loopholes<br />

have been discovered or created, exploited, <strong>and</strong> then plugged,<br />

techniques of tax avoidance have become increasingly sophisticated <strong>and</strong> <br />

the complexity of the income tax has grown, in a never-ending cycle.


- 2 -<br />

The resulting tax system is both unfair <strong>and</strong> needlessly complex.<br />

Moreover, it interferes with economic behavior <strong>and</strong>, thus, prevents<br />

markets from allocating economic resources to their most productive<br />

uses. Perhaps worse, the complexity <strong>and</strong> inequity of the tax system<br />

undermine taxpayer morale -- a valuable, yet fragile, national asset<br />

<strong>and</strong> a prerequisite <strong>for</strong> a tax system based on voluntary compliance.<br />

During the past year, the Treasury Department has undertaken a<br />

thorough review of the U.S. tax system. The object has been to<br />

determine how to reduce the complexities, inequities, <strong>and</strong> economic<br />

distortions i n the tax system <strong>and</strong> make it more conducive to economic<br />

growth. Although the present report was prepared internally by the<br />

Treasury Department, it draws heavily on a vast national storehouse of<br />

knowledge about the tax system <strong>and</strong> its effects on the economy. The<br />

report also reflects in<strong>for</strong>mation, views, <strong>and</strong> concerns which the<br />

Treasury Department received from taxpayers in the course of public<br />

hearings, meetings, <strong>and</strong> discussions, <strong>and</strong> in correspondence <strong>and</strong> in more<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal written statements.<br />

The Federal Income <strong>Tax</strong> in 1954 <br />

To underst<strong>and</strong> better the need <strong>for</strong> tax re<strong>for</strong>m, it is useful to com­<br />

pare our present income tax system with the one that prevailed in the <br />

late 1950s, after enactment of the 1954 Internal Revenue Code. Though<br />

the 1954 income tax system exhibited some serious problems, it was <br />

relatively simple, it was more nearly neutral toward many economic <br />

decisions, <strong>and</strong> most citizens probably thought it was reasonably fair. <br />

Today the American economy is far more complex than it was 30<br />

years ago. The financial affairs of the typical American family are<br />

far more complicated than in previous generations. Ownership of both<br />

financial <strong>and</strong> nonfinancial assets is more widespread <strong>and</strong> varied.<br />

Families have a greater quantity <strong>and</strong> variety of income, both taxed <strong>and</strong><br />

untaxed. Business transactions are more complicated, financial<br />

intermediation is more highly developed, <strong>and</strong> taxpayers are more<br />

sophisticated <strong>and</strong> better advised. We also know more about the adverse<br />

effects of taxation than 30 years ago. There<strong>for</strong>e, it would not be<br />

desirable -- nor would it be possible -- simply to reinstate an<br />

earlier tax law that was not designed to deal with the more complex<br />

economy of the 1980s. But a useful perspective on the current need<br />

<strong>for</strong> tax re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>and</strong> simplification can be gained by considering how the<br />

tax law -- <strong>and</strong> its impact on taxpayers -- has changed over the past<br />

three decades.<br />

One important defect of the 1954 income tax was a schedule of <br />

marginal rates that reached 91 percent <strong>for</strong> a small number of <br />

taxpayers. Besides creating severe disincentives <strong>for</strong> saving, invest­<br />

ment, <strong>and</strong> work ef<strong>for</strong>t, the confiscatory rates may have spawned many of <br />

the vexing tax avoidance schemes that now riddle the income tax. But <br />

the advantages of the earlier income tax were also manifest. <br />

Virtually all taxpayers below the top 10 percent of the income <br />

distribution paid tax at an essentially uni<strong>for</strong>m marginal rate of about


- 3 - <br />

20 percent. Only at the very top of the income distribution did rates<br />

become steeply progressive. The income tax was still being used<br />

primarily to raise public revenues, <strong>and</strong> not to guide households <strong>and</strong><br />

private business enterprises into a multitude of activities -- some of<br />

dubious value -- through preferential tax treatment. With notable<br />

exceptions, the income tax was levied on a base that included most<br />

income. The erosion of that base by a multitude of exclusions,<br />

adjustments, deductions, <strong>and</strong> credits not required to measure income<br />

accurately had not reached its present stage.<br />

Compared to today, the 1954 income tax was simpler, more neutral,<br />

<strong>and</strong> fairer, in many respects. Perhaps as importantly, it was probably<br />

seen to be fair by most taxpayers, <strong>and</strong> the perception of fairness<br />

helped maintain the voluntary compliance so crucial to the American<br />

system of taxation.<br />

The Decline in <strong>Simplicity</strong> <br />

In 1954 the income tax was simpler <strong>for</strong> most taxpayers, in part<br />

because incomes were lower <strong>and</strong> the financial affairs of most families<br />

were simpler. There was little need <strong>for</strong> most taxpayers to work<br />

through a variety of complicated <strong>for</strong>ms -- <strong>and</strong> even more complicated<br />

instructions -- to determine eligibility <strong>for</strong> a particular tax benefit.<br />

Only 25 percent of taxpayers itemized deductions in 1955, compared to<br />

35 percent in 1982. Thus, fewer taxpayers found it necessary to save<br />

receipts verifying a multitude of expenditures accorded tax-preferred<br />

status. There was also little need to engage the services of a tax<br />

professional to file an individual income tax return. <strong>Tax</strong> planning --<br />

the rearrangement of one's economic affairs to minimize taxes -- was<br />

the concern of only a few. Most taxpayers did not even feel the need<br />

to consider the tax consequences of major decisions, much less<br />

everyday transactions.<br />

Today the proliferation <strong>and</strong> expansion of exclusions, adjustments<br />

to income, deductions, <strong>and</strong> credits create a major burden of paperwork<br />

<strong>and</strong> make part-time bookkeepers of many Americans. At present, about<br />

100 different Federal tax <strong>for</strong>ms are used by individuals. Many<br />

decisions -- f3r example, whether <strong>and</strong> how to make a charitable<br />

contribution, whether to participate in insurance plans offered by an<br />

employer, <strong>and</strong> whether to contribute to a political party -- all have<br />

tax consequences. Ordinsry citizens are confronted with the alternatives<br />

of using a professional tax preparer, becoming knowledgeable in<br />

arcane tax law, running afoul of the tax administration, or possibly<br />

passing up available tax benefits. Today, over 40 percent of all<br />

individual income tax returns -- <strong>and</strong> some 60 percent of all long <strong>for</strong>ms<br />

(<strong>for</strong>m 1040s) -- are prepared by paid professionals. So-called tax<br />

shelters, once known only to the wealthy, are now attracting<br />

increasing numbers of middle-income Americans, many of whom do not<br />

have access to sophisticated tax advice <strong>and</strong> are misled by the<br />

misrepresentations of unscrupulous promoters of illegal shelters,<br />

often with disastrous effects. Legislative response to the tax


shelter problem over the last 15 years has involved a patchwork of<br />

solutions that has generally increased the complexity of the tax<br />

system without correcting the underlying causes of tax shelters.<br />

Erosion of the <strong>Tax</strong> Base <br />

In 1954, the income tax did favor certain economic activities over<br />

others. For example, even then, tax experts criticized the fact that<br />

income from oil <strong>and</strong> gas properties, interest on state <strong>and</strong> local<br />

securities, <strong>and</strong> appreciation on capital assets were accorded preferential<br />

tax treatment. These "loopholes," as they were called,<br />

created inequities <strong>and</strong> distorted the use of the Nation's resources.<br />

By comparison, most interest, dividend, <strong>and</strong> labor income was taxed in<br />

full, <strong>and</strong> few <strong>for</strong>ms of personal expenditure were tax deductible. The<br />

most important itemized deductions were <strong>for</strong> state <strong>and</strong> local taxes,<br />

charitable contributions, interest payments, <strong>and</strong> medical expenses;<br />

some of these had valid or easily understood justifications.<br />

The last three decades have seen enormous erosion of the tax base.<br />

Compensation has increasingly taken the <strong>for</strong>m of tax-free fringe<br />

benefits <strong>and</strong> legally taxable "perks" that many taxpayers improperly<br />

treat as tax-exempt. Interest on bonds issued by state <strong>and</strong> local<br />

governments has long been tax exempt, but recently these governments<br />

have increasingly used tax-exempt bonds to finance private investments.<br />

The investment tax credit greatly reduces the effective<br />

tax rate on income generated by business equipment, <strong>and</strong> accelerated<br />

depreciation <strong>and</strong> the deduction <strong>for</strong> interest expense combine to<br />

eliminate most taxes on income from debt-financed investments in real<br />

estate. In extreme cases these <strong>and</strong> other features of the tax law<br />

create losses <strong>for</strong> tax purposes that can be used to shelter other<br />

income. Exclusions, itemized deductions, <strong>and</strong> the deduction value of<br />

credits offset about 34 percent of personal income in 1982, as opposed<br />

to only 18 percent in 1954.<br />

Economic Distortions <br />

The lack of a comprehensive income tax base has two obvious <strong>and</strong> <br />

important adverse effects on the ability of the marketplace to <br />

allocate capital <strong>and</strong> labor to their most productive uses. First, the <br />

smaller the tax base, the higher tax rates must be to raise a given <br />

amount of revenue. High tax rates discourage saving <strong>and</strong> investment,<br />

stifle work ef<strong>for</strong>t, retard invention <strong>and</strong> innovation, encourage<br />

unproductive investment in tax shelters, <strong>and</strong> needlessly reduce the <br />

Nation's st<strong>and</strong>ard of living <strong>and</strong> growth rate. <br />

Second, tax-preferred activities are favored relative to others,<br />

<strong>and</strong> tax law, rather than the market, becomes the primary <strong>for</strong>ce in <br />

determining how economic resources are used. Over the years, the tax <br />

system has come to exert a pervasive influence on the behavior of <br />

private decision-makers. The resulting tax-induced distortions in the <br />

use of labor <strong>and</strong> capital <strong>and</strong> in consumer choices have severe costs in <br />

terms of lower productivity, lost production, <strong>and</strong> reduced consumer <br />

satisfaction.


The existing taxation of capital <strong>and</strong> business income is<br />

particularly non-neutral. It favors capital-intensive industries over<br />

others, such as services. The tax system favors industries that are<br />

unusually dependent on equipment over those -- such as wholesale <strong>and</strong><br />

retail trade -- that rely more heavily on other <strong>for</strong>ms of capital,<br />

including inventories <strong>and</strong> structures. High technology companies are<br />

put at a particular disadvantage. Since they do not require large<br />

capital investments that benefit from preferential tax treatment they<br />

bear the full brunt of high tax rates. A tax system that interferes<br />

less with market <strong>for</strong>ces in the determination of what business should<br />

produce -- <strong>and</strong> how -- would be more conducive to productive investment<br />

<strong>and</strong> economic growth.<br />

Inequities <br />

Erosion of the tax base also creates inequities. Most obviously,<br />

it is unfair that two households with equal incomes should pay<br />

different amounts of tax, simply because one receives or spends its<br />

income in ways that are tax-preferred. There is, <strong>for</strong> example, no<br />

reason that employees should be allowed to escape tax on fringe<br />

benefits <strong>and</strong> entertainment provided by their employers, while others<br />

must buy the same benefits <strong>and</strong> entertainment with after-tax dollars.<br />

Even at moderate income levels, taxpayers with similar incomes can<br />

incur tax liabilities that differ by thous<strong>and</strong>s of dollars. Moreover,<br />

gaps in the tax base create inequities across income classes, as well<br />

as within income classes. Some of the most important tax preferences<br />

-- those that give rise to tax shelters -- benefit primarily those<br />

with high incomes.<br />

Unfair Treatment of the Family <br />

Thirty years ago the personal exemption <strong>for</strong> the taxpayer, spouse,<br />

<strong>and</strong> each dependent was $600, <strong>and</strong> there was a st<strong>and</strong>ard deduction of 10<br />

percent of adjusted gross income, up to $1,000. Thus a family of four<br />

would pay no tax until income exceeded $2,675. Even though the personal<br />

exemption is now $1,000 <strong>and</strong> a larger "zero-bracket amount" has<br />

replaced the st<strong>and</strong>ard deduction, inflation has resulted in a substantial<br />

decline in the real value of the "tax-free amount," the level<br />

of income at which tax is first paid. Some families with incomes<br />

below the poverty level have become subject to tax. <strong>Tax</strong> burdens have<br />

increased relatively more <strong>for</strong> large families with many dependents than<br />

<strong>for</strong> other taxpayers.<br />

The tax law was designed <strong>for</strong> a society in which dependents are<br />

generally present as part of a family with both parents present. Some<br />

groups with greater-than-average proportions of poor families, such as<br />

the elderly <strong>and</strong> the disabled, receive special tax treatment, but this<br />

treatment is often arbitrary <strong>and</strong> r<strong>and</strong>om, <strong>and</strong> depends on the source of<br />

the income, not on the need of the family. Until recently, the<br />

working poor have almost always been excluded from such special<br />

treatment. The special burdens faced by many single heads of<br />

households -- especially those caring <strong>for</strong> dependents <strong>and</strong> trying to<br />

work at the same time -- have been addressed inadequately.<br />

459-370 0 - 84 - 2


Inflation <strong>and</strong> the Income <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

- 6 - <br />

The U.S. income tax was not designed to be immune from inflation.<br />

Thus when inflation accelerated in the 1970s, taxpayers with constant<br />

real incomes were pushed into progressively higher tax brackets. The<br />

proportion of income paid to the government increased, even when real<br />

income did not, <strong>and</strong> higher tax rates created serious disincentives.<br />

Historically, "bracket creep,'' as this effect is called, could only be<br />

offset by periodic congressional action to increase the personal<br />

exeqption, zero-bracket amount (ZBA), <strong>and</strong> bracket limits. But bracket<br />

creep sensitized the public to the problem of high <strong>and</strong> rising tax<br />

rates, <strong>and</strong> the Economic Recovery <strong>Tax</strong> Act of 1981 made a major step in<br />

tax re<strong>for</strong>m by reducing tax rates <strong>and</strong> curing bracket creep. Even<br />

though many taxpayers are still subject to needlessly high marginal<br />

tax rates, the personal exemption, ZBA, <strong>and</strong> bracket limits will be<br />

indexed, starting in 1985. However, another important cause of<br />

inflation-induced tax increases remains uncorrected.<br />

During inflationary times, taxes are collected on totally<br />

fictitious income. Capital gains taxes are paid when the prices of<br />

assets merely rise with inflation. Business firms are not allowed<br />

tax-free recovery of their real capital investments in inventories <strong>and</strong><br />

depreciable assets. Moreover, high interest rates that merely reflect<br />

expected inflation overstate the real income of recipients of interest<br />

<strong>and</strong> inflate deductions <strong>for</strong> real interest expense.<br />

The interaction of inflation <strong>and</strong> taxes creates further inequities<br />

<strong>and</strong> distortions. The overstatement of real interest income <strong>and</strong><br />

deductions arbitrarily increases the tax burden on savers <strong>and</strong> rewards<br />

borrowers. Resource allocation is distorted by effective tax rates on<br />

some types of capital income that can easily exceed 100 percent.<br />

During the 1970s, the combination of high rates of inflation <strong>and</strong> a tax<br />

system that was not inflation-proof caused an increase in the taxinduced<br />

bias in favor of investment in owner-occupied housing; this<br />

probably aggravated the shortage of funds <strong>for</strong> business capital<br />

<strong>for</strong>mation.<br />

The combination of lower rates of inflation, the Accelerated Cost<br />

Recovery System of depreciation, <strong>and</strong> the lower tax rates on long-term<br />

capital gains have relieved some of the problem. Even so, the present<br />

tax system does not accurately measure real income from business or<br />

capital under most circumstances. Moreover, the tax treatment of<br />

business inventories <strong>and</strong> of debtors <strong>and</strong> creditors remains dependent on<br />

the rate of inflation.<br />

The Rise of <strong>Tax</strong> Shelters<br />

The well-advertised boom in the tax shelter industry in recent <br />

years has had particularly adverse effects. Some shelters involve <br />

little more than thinly veiled, if sophisticated, tax fraud, But even <br />

perfectly legal tax shelters distort the allocation of scarce capital<br />

because they produce highly visible inequities in taxation. Perhaps <br />

most importantly of all, they undermine taxpayer confidence in the


- 7 -<br />

integrity <strong>and</strong> fairness of the tax system. <strong>Tax</strong> shelter losses <br />

typically result from a combination of current deductions <strong>for</strong> future <br />

expenses, deferral of taxable income, <strong>and</strong> conversion of ordinary<br />

income to preferentially taxed long-term capital gains. Thus,<br />

shelters allow taxpayers to defer tax liability far into the future. <br />

<strong>Tax</strong> deferral is equivalent to an interest-free loan from the Federal <br />

Government. <br />

Recent data on tax returns of partnerships, a commonly used<br />

vehicle <strong>for</strong> tax shelters, indicate the nature <strong>and</strong> magnitude of the<br />

problem. In 1981 partnerships operating in the United States reported<br />

aggregate losses in excess of aggregate profits. This is not a<br />

cyclical phenomenon; partnership losses have increased steadily,<br />

relative to profits, <strong>for</strong> two decades. (See Figure 1-1.) Yet there is<br />

no reason to believe that Americans are losing more <strong>and</strong> more money<br />

each year by investing in these enterprises. Rather, many partnership<br />

investments are profitable on an after-tax basis, becausq they<br />

generate accounting losses that can be used to reduce or eliminate tax<br />

on other income (that is, to shelter other income from tax). But many<br />

shelter activities that offer attractive after-tax yields have little<br />

social value, as evidenced by be<strong>for</strong>e-tax yields that are low <strong>and</strong><br />

sometimes even negative.<br />

Partnerships in two industries that are favorites with tax shelter<br />

investors -- oil <strong>and</strong> gas <strong>and</strong> real estate -- are a case in point. In<br />

1982, of the $60 billion in aggregate losses reported by all partnerships,<br />

$31.6 billion were attributable to losses reported by oil <strong>and</strong><br />

gas <strong>and</strong> real estate partnerships, even though partnerships reporting<br />

losses in these two industries had a positive net cash flow of $1.6<br />

bi 11ion.<br />

Between 1963 <strong>and</strong> 1982, the number of taxpayers who claimed<br />

partnership losses on their individual returns increased by 400<br />

percent, from 412,000 to 2.1 million, even though the total number of<br />

individual tax returns filed during the same period increased by only<br />

50 percent. As a result of this growth in tax shelter activity, there<br />

has been a significant erosion in the base of the Federal income tax,<br />

particularly among taxpayers with the highest incomes. In 1983, partnership<br />

losses claimed by individual taxpayers may have sheltered as<br />

much as $35 billion of individual income from taxation. An estimated<br />

82 percent of this total ($28.6 billion in partnership losses) was<br />

reported by taxpayers whose gross income be<strong>for</strong>e losses was $100,000 or<br />

more, <strong>and</strong> 60 percent ($21.0 billion) was reported by taxpayers with<br />

gross income be<strong>for</strong>e losses in excess of $250,000. By comparison,<br />

these groups reported 9 percent <strong>and</strong> 4 percent, respectively, of all<br />

gross income be<strong>for</strong>e losses reported by individuals.<br />

A sample of taxpayer returns illustrates quite strikingly the way<br />

in which tax shelter accounting losses can be used to shelter<br />

substantial amounts of income from tax. A group of 88 taxpayers who<br />

held interests in certain non-abusive tax shelters -- shelters whose<br />

legitimacy was not being questioned by the Internal Revenue Service --<br />

were chosen <strong>for</strong> statistical analysis. Though this sample was not


--a -


- 9 -<br />

selected scientifically, there is no reason to believe it is not<br />

representative; certainly it indicates the nature of the problem.<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>payers in this sample reported positive income that is gross<br />

income be<strong>for</strong>e losses -- of $17 million, or an average of $193,000. On<br />

average, each of these taxpayers owned interests in 6 partnerships,<br />

<strong>and</strong> a total of $6.4 million in net partnership losses was reported on<br />

the 88 returns. When these losses are added to other business <strong>and</strong><br />

investment-related losses of almost $8.7 million, the taxpayers in the<br />

sample reported gross income of only $1.9 million. Thus, accounting<br />

losses from tax shelter partnerships reduced the gross income of<br />

taxpayers in the sample by almost 40 percent, <strong>and</strong> other losses reduced<br />

income by an additional 49 percent. (See Table 1-1.) The taxable<br />

income of these individuals was further reduced by adjustments to<br />

gross income <strong>and</strong> by itemized deductions.<br />

Of the 08 returns sampled, 19 returns, with an average gross<br />

income be<strong>for</strong>e loss (positive income) of $243,710, reported a total<br />

income tax payment of $500 or less; 37 returns, with an average gross<br />

income be<strong>for</strong>e loss of $172,113 reported a total tax payment of $6,000<br />

or less. By comparison, a typical family of four, with positive<br />

income of $45,000, but no tax shelter losses, would pay $6,272 in<br />

taxes. The extent to which tax shelter losses can be used to<br />

dramatically reduce tax liabilities is further documented by estimates<br />

from the 1983 Treasury tax model which show that 9,000 taxpayers with<br />

gross incomes be<strong>for</strong>e losses of $250,000 or more paid no tax as a<br />

direct result of partnership losses, while 59,000 taxpayers with that<br />

much positive income were able to reduce their tax payments by at<br />

least one-half.<br />

The Decline in <strong>Tax</strong>payer morale<br />

The United States has long been proud of the “taxpayer morale” of<br />

its citizens -- the willingness to pay voluntarily the income taxes<br />

necessary to finance government activities. <strong>Tax</strong>payer morale ulti-.<br />

mately depends, however, on the belief that taxes are fair. If the<br />

basis <strong>for</strong> this belief comes under suspicion, voluntary compliance with<br />

the tax laws is jeopardized. Thus, the perceived lack of fairness of<br />

the income tax may be as important as actual complexities, economic<br />

distortions, <strong>and</strong> inequities. <strong>Tax</strong>payers resent paying substantially<br />

more tax than their neighbors who have equal or higher incomes. This<br />

is true even if the neighbor reduces taxes through commonly available<br />

<strong>and</strong> perfectly legal exclusions, adjustments, deductions, <strong>and</strong> credits,<br />

rather than by questionable or illegal means. Nany witnesses at tax<br />

re<strong>for</strong>m hearings the Treasury Department held throughout the country<br />

during June 1984 enphasized that tax should be collected on virtually<br />

all income, with little regard to how the income is earned or spent.<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>ation can be thought to be unfair because the basic tax structure<br />

is defective, as well as because taxpayers who do not comply with the<br />

law are not penalized. The proliferation <strong>and</strong> publicity of tax<br />

shelters has a particularly pernicious effect on taxpayer morale.<br />

--


- 10 -<br />

..<br />

r-<br />

0<br />

N.<br />

N<br />

N<br />

m <br />

W<br />

v).<br />

7<br />

0<br />

..<br />

Ī<br />

......<br />

in<br />

-<br />

m .-. Ln In<br />

0 ..- m<br />

m. . m . m.<br />

uḷ<br />

m -r m<br />

r- 0 W<br />

N N m I<br />

I I I<br />

(I)-<br />

(I)­<br />

(I)­<br />

r-<br />

m<br />

Lc<br />

1'1<br />

m<br />

..<br />

..-<br />

(I)-<br />

.... .*I<br />

W<br />

O m <br />

LIc <br />

m<br />

o r -<br />

N ..-<br />

m m<br />

..-I m+<br />

zffi<br />

......<br />

I 1 I i i i <br />

0 0 2<br />

0 0 0 W<br />

0<br />

0.<br />

0. 0. 8 m<br />

3<br />

0 0 k<br />

0 0 0 0<br />

- R W<br />

W N<br />

(I)- (I)- (I)- 0 2<br />

0<br />

4<br />

I I<br />

0.<br />

0<br />

0 0<br />

0 0 N<br />

0 0 (I)-<br />

0. .<br />

m 0<br />

0 0<br />

W<br />

i -<br />

(I)-<br />

*<br />

(I)- c *


Needed:<br />

- 11 -<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>es That are Broad-Based, Simple, <strong>and</strong> Fair <br />

Fundamental re<strong>for</strong>m of the tax system is required to correct the<br />

problems just described. The tax system must be made simpler, more<br />

economically neutral, fairer, <strong>and</strong> more conducive to economic growth.<br />

These objectives are described more fully in the next chapter. The<br />

key to their achievement is to define real taxable income comprehensively,<br />

to exempt families with poverty-level incomes from tax, <strong>and</strong><br />

to subject taxable income to a rate structure thtit, while mildly<br />

progressive, avoids rates so high that they stifle incentives <strong>and</strong><br />

prevent economic growth. In short, the income tax should be broadbased,<br />

simple, <strong>and</strong> fair.


- 13 -<br />

Chapter 2<br />

GOALS OF FUNDAMENTAL TAX REFORM<br />

In undertaking fundamental re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>and</strong> simplification of the tax<br />

system of the United States, it is important to specify clearly <strong>and</strong><br />

explicitly the goals or criteria that should guide such an undertaking.<br />

The criteria underlying the Treasury Department's study of<br />

fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m are described here. Though some are framed in<br />

the familiar context of an income tax, in general they are equally<br />

applicable in the context of the less familiar tax on consumed income.<br />

Economic Neutrality<br />

One of the primary advantages of a free market economy is its<br />

tendency to allocate economic resources to their most productive uses.<br />

For example, market <strong>for</strong>ces lead business firms to produce what<br />

consumers want in ways that are relatively efficient <strong>and</strong> economical.<br />

Any tax inevitably discourages the type of activity that is taxed. An<br />

ideal tax system would, however, interfere with private decisions as<br />

little as possible. That is, it would not unnecessarily distort<br />

choices about how income is earned <strong>and</strong> how it is spent. It would not<br />

unduly favor leisure over work, or consumption over saving <strong>and</strong> investment.<br />

It would not needlessly cause business firms to modify their<br />

production techniques or their decisions on how to finance their<br />

activities. A neutral tax policy would not induce businesses to<br />

acquire other firms or to be acquired by them merely <strong>for</strong> tax<br />

considerations. It would not discourage risk-taking or the <strong>for</strong>mation<br />

of new businesses. It would not discourage competition by granting<br />

special preferences only to one industry or one type of financial<br />

institution. In short, an ideal tax system would be as neutral as<br />

possible toward private decisions. Any deviation from this principle<br />

represents implicit endorsement of governmental intervention in the<br />

economy -- an insidious <strong>for</strong>m of industrial policy based on the belief<br />

that those responsible <strong>for</strong> tax policy can judge better than the<br />

marketplace what consumers want, how goods <strong>and</strong> services should be<br />

produced, <strong>and</strong> how business should be organized <strong>and</strong> financed.<br />

Economic neutrality is furthered by a few simple rilles of tax<br />

design. Perhaps most importantly, income from all sources should be<br />

taxed equally; otherwise, too many resources will be devoted to<br />

activities subject to the lowest taxes. For the same reason, tax<br />

liability should not depend on how income is spent. Uni<strong>for</strong>m treatment<br />

of all sources <strong>and</strong> uses of income requires a comprehensive definition<br />

of income <strong>for</strong> tax purposes.<br />

Lower <strong>Tax</strong> Rates<br />

The higher tax rates are, the more taxes interfere with economic<br />

choices -- choices about working, about saving <strong>and</strong> investing, about<br />

production techniques <strong>and</strong> business finance, <strong>and</strong> about invention <strong>and</strong>


innovation. Moreover, any omission from the tax base is more valuable<br />

at high tax rates than at low rates. As a consequence, there is more<br />

political pressure <strong>for</strong> preferential treatment of selected activities<br />

at high rates, <strong>and</strong> tax shelters are more important at high rates.<br />

Thus an important goal of tax policy is to keep tax rates as low as<br />

possible, given other objectives. Of course, the tax rates needed to<br />

raise a given amount of revenue can be lower, the more income is<br />

subject to tax. This is a second important reason <strong>for</strong> adopting a<br />

comprehensive definition of taxable income. It is far better -- more<br />

neutral, as well as simpler <strong>and</strong> more equitable -- to levy low tax<br />

rates on all income than to impose high tax rates on only part of<br />

income.<br />

Revenue Neutrality<br />

Most Americans probably agree that those with high incomes should<br />

pay a greater percentage of their income in tax than those with intermediate<br />

levels of income. But the proper pattern of effective tax<br />

rates -- the percentage of income paid in taxes at various income<br />

levels is a matter on which opinions differ.<br />

--<br />

- 14 -<br />

The Treasury Department study of fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m has<br />

concentrated 011 questions of tax structure <strong>and</strong> has not considered any<br />

2roposals to increase the level of tax revenues that will result from<br />

current law. Thus the Treasury Department proposes tax re<strong>for</strong>ms that<br />

are revenue neutral, that is, re<strong>for</strong>ms that would leave revenues<br />

essentially unchanged from what they would be under current law.<br />

Equal Treatment of Equals<br />

A tax that places significantly different burdens on taxpayers in<br />

similar economic circumstances is not fair. For example, if two<br />

similar families have the same income, they should ordinarily pay<br />

roughly the same amount of income tax, regardless of the sources or<br />

uses of that income. A fair tax system does not allow some taxpayers<br />

to avoid taxes by legal means or to evade them by illegal means.<br />

The only way to achieve equal treatment of equals is to define the<br />

tax base comprehensively. If some items of income are omitted from<br />

the tax base, or if particular expenditures are treated preferentially,<br />

then taxpayers who are otherwise in equal positions will not<br />

be treated equally.<br />

<strong>Fairness</strong> <strong>for</strong> Families<br />

It is commonly agreed that households with incomes below the<br />

poverty level should pay little or no tax. Otherwise, they will be<br />

paying taxes with income that is needed to maintain a minimal st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

of living. In a real sense, families with poverty-level incomes do<br />

not have taxpaying ability. <strong>Tax</strong>paying capacity exists only once<br />

income exceeds the poverty level.<br />

<strong>Fairness</strong> Across Income Classes


- 15 -<br />

In its study of fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m the Treasury Department has<br />

adopted the simple working assumption that the existing distribution<br />

of tax payments across income classes should not be significantly<br />

changed b4 tax re<strong>for</strong>m. If any change in the existing distribution of<br />

tax burdens is desired, it can <strong>and</strong> should be implemented by adjusting<br />

the proposed personal exemptions <strong>and</strong> rate schedules. It should not be<br />

achieved by taxing some sources or uses of income more or less heavily<br />

than others, since that would violate both economic neutrality <strong>and</strong> the<br />

principle that those with equal incomes should pay approximately equal<br />

taxes.<br />

Defining the tax base comprehensively is necessary <strong>for</strong> the<br />

achievement of equity across income classes. Any exclusion or deduction<br />

is worth more, the higher the marginal tax bracket of the taxpayer.<br />

Moreover, wealthy taxpayers make relatively greater use of<br />

many provisions of the tax law that reduce the tax base, especially<br />

those yielding business deductions that result in the mismeasurement<br />

of economic income <strong>and</strong> produce tax shelters. As long as these tax<br />

preferences exist, the tax system will be less progressive than the<br />

rate structure suggests, <strong>and</strong> high marginal rates will be advocated as<br />

a means of achieving progressive taxation. Conversely, if income is<br />

defined comprehensively, the existing pattern of progressivity can be<br />

maintained with markedly lower marginal tax rates on upper income<br />

groups, as well as other taxpayers.<br />

<strong>Tax</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m that does not alter the distribution of tax burdens<br />

across income groups will, of course, involve redistribution of tax<br />

burdens -- winners <strong>and</strong> losers -- within income classes. This is only<br />

natural in the context of re<strong>for</strong>m that attempts to replace the<br />

inequities of the present tax system with equal treatment of<br />

households with a given income. Those who gain from any such re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

will be those who, at a given level of income, have been paying more<br />

than average amounts of tax, <strong>and</strong> those who lose will have been paying<br />

less than their fair share of taxes. But many of the losers will not<br />

lose permanently; they will simply divert funds from uneconomic<br />

investments to more productive investments <strong>and</strong> pay lower tax rates on<br />

the higher income that results.<br />

<strong>Simplicity</strong> <br />

An important goal of the Treasury Department study of fundamental<br />

tax re<strong>for</strong>m is simplification. During June of 1984, the Treasury<br />

Department held hearings on fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m in seven U.S.<br />

cities. One of the themes repeated most frequently by citizens<br />

appearing at those hearings was the need <strong>for</strong> simplification of the<br />

income tax.<br />

Though simplicity in taxation may be difficult to define, everyone<br />

knows what it is not. <strong>Simplicity</strong> is not reflected in a tax system<br />

that requires extensive recordkeeping by ordinary citizens. A simpler<br />

system would require fewer taxpayers to collect <strong>and</strong> retain receipts or<br />

cancelled checks in order to calculate <strong>and</strong> document tax deductions,


- 16 -<br />

adjustments, <strong>and</strong> credits. Simpliciky is not wondering which receipts<br />

<strong>and</strong> checks to save because the tax law is too complex <strong>and</strong> is<br />

constantly changing. <strong>Simplicity</strong> is not computing dozens of deductions<br />

<strong>and</strong> credits, <strong>and</strong> wondering all the while whether other means of saving<br />

tax might have been missed through ignorance of the laws. Nor. is<br />

simplicity being <strong>for</strong>ced to wade through long <strong>and</strong> complicated<br />

instruction booklets or resort to professional assistance, in order to<br />

meet the civic responsibility to pay taxes. A simple tax system would<br />

not require 41 percent of all taxpayers -- <strong>and</strong> about 60 percent of<br />

those who itemize deductions -- to engage professional assistance in<br />

preparing their tax returns. Under a simple system, most responsible<br />

taxpayers would be more certain of their tax liabilities.<br />

Reduced costs <strong>and</strong> greater ease of administration <strong>for</strong> the<br />

government are the mirror image of simplicity or the taxpayer. Many<br />

provisions of the tax code could be administered effectively only by<br />

devoting exorbitant resources to their en<strong>for</strong>cement. About 90 percent<br />

of taxpayers who itemize deductions make at least one error in<br />

claiming their deductions, but the Internal Revenue Service simply<br />

does not have the capacity to audit all returns <strong>and</strong> either collect the<br />

tax due or make refunds to these taxpayers. The current tax structure<br />

creates a dilemma <strong>for</strong> tax administrators. Effective en<strong>for</strong>cement of<br />

complicated laws generally creates complexity <strong>for</strong> the taxpayer <strong>and</strong><br />

fosters apprehension <strong>and</strong> resentment against the fiscal authorities.<br />

On the other h<strong>and</strong>, ineffective en<strong>for</strong>cement loses revenue, it creates<br />

uncertainty <strong>for</strong> taxpayers, it converts the tax system into an unfair<br />

tax on honesty, <strong>and</strong> it may also generate hostility toward the tax<br />

system. A primary focus of the tax re<strong>for</strong>m study has been to eliminate<br />

<strong>and</strong> avoid provisions that would unduly complicate tax administration<br />

<strong>and</strong> compliance <strong>for</strong> most taxpayers.<br />

Perceived Fafmess<br />

The perception of fairness may be as important as fairness itself<br />

as a goal of tax policy. The United States was once justly proud of<br />

the taxpayer morale of its citizens. With media coverage of tax<br />

shelters now commonplace <strong>and</strong> talk of "beating the system" prevalent in<br />

conversation, taxpayers increasingly view the tax system as unfair <strong>and</strong><br />

wonder why they should pay taxes. One of the primary goals of the<br />

Treasury Department study of fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m is the reversal of<br />

this threatening trend.<br />

The growing use of the income tax to subsidize various <strong>for</strong>ms of<br />

economic activity is a major source of the increase in the perceived<br />

lack of fairness of the tax system. The U.S. Government has long<br />

spent public funds in ways that many taxpayers question. While this<br />

may cause many to believe that their tax dollars are being wasted, it<br />

does not raise doubts about the equity of the tax system itself. The<br />

situation is very different when the tax system, rather than direct<br />

spending, is used to provide subsidies. Similarly situated taxpayers<br />

can pay considerably different amounts of tax, depending on how they<br />

earn <strong>and</strong> spend their income, <strong>and</strong> high-income families may pay tax on a<br />

smaller portion of their income than do poorer families. The result


- 17 -<br />

is a perception that the income tax itself is unfair, both with n <strong>and</strong><br />

across income classes.<br />

<strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong>s of many types are needed to improve the image of the U.S.<br />

income tax. Families below the poverty line should pay little or no<br />

tax. Income tax compliance should be easier <strong>and</strong> less expensive. Most<br />

<strong>for</strong>ms of economic income should be subject to tax, but fictitious<br />

income representing nothing but inflation should not be taxed. The<br />

tax system generally should not be used to implement subsidy programs.<br />

Opportunities <strong>for</strong> tax shelters should be sharply curtailed, if not<br />

eliminated. <strong>Tax</strong> evasion should be made more difficult. Adoption of<br />

fairer tax rules would h aw a multiplier effect, as increased fairness<br />

would lead to an improved perception of fairness <strong>and</strong>, in turn, to<br />

better compliance.<br />

An Inflation-proof <strong>Tax</strong> Law<br />

Starting in 1985 personal exemptions, the zero bracket amount, <strong>and</strong><br />

the tax brackets in the individual income tax will be adjusted <strong>for</strong><br />

inflation. This important innovation, commonly called indexing, will<br />

prevent taxpayers with a given real income from being <strong>for</strong>ced by<br />

inflation to pay higher taxes. It should remain an inviolate part of<br />

the tax system. Indexing of this kind, important as it is, meets only<br />

part of the need to protect taxpayers from inflation. Inflation<br />

adjustment in the calculation of taxable income is perhaps more<br />

important, because it cannot be achieved by periodic adjustments of<br />

personal exemptions <strong>and</strong> the rate structure. Without it inflation<br />

causes mismeasurement of business <strong>and</strong> capital income.<br />

Inflation currently causes income to be overstated in at least<br />

four ways. First, depreciation allowances based on historical costs<br />

are generally not adequate to allow tax-free recovery of investment in<br />

a time of inflation. Second, deductions <strong>for</strong> the cost of goods sold<br />

from inventories are inadequate if based on historical costs. Third,<br />

capital gains include nominal appreciation that merely reflects the<br />

general rise in prices, rather than an increase in the real value of<br />

assets. Fourth, nominal interest receipts include an inflation<br />

premium that should not be taxed. By the same token, full deduction<br />

<strong>for</strong> nominal interest expenses during inflationary times results in the<br />

understatement of real economic income.<br />

Congress has made some ad hoc adjustments in depreciation<br />

allowances <strong>and</strong> the taxation of capital gains in response to inflation.<br />

‘In most cases these measures do not accurately adjust <strong>for</strong> inflation,<br />

<strong>and</strong> they are too inflexible to deal adequately with changes in the<br />

rate of inflation.<br />

An ideal income tax system would provide inflation adjustments in<br />

the ceasurement of taxable income in order to prevent the taxation of<br />

fictitious income <strong>and</strong> the deduction of fictitious interest expenses.<br />

Such adjustments would prevent the effective tax rates imposed on<br />

business <strong>and</strong> capital income from varying dramatically <strong>and</strong> arbitrarily<br />

every time the inflation rate changes.


Neutrality Toward Business Form<br />

- 10 -<br />

Corporate income that is distributed as dividends is subject to<br />

tax twice, first at the corporate level <strong>and</strong> again when received by<br />

individuals. Many observers -- among them economists <strong>and</strong> lawyers,<br />

businessmen, <strong>and</strong> public officials -- have argued that a separate<br />

unintegrated tax on corporate profits has adverse economic effects <strong>and</strong><br />

makes no sense. Yet the corporate <strong>and</strong> individual income taxes cannot<br />

be fully integrated, <strong>for</strong> technical reasons, <strong>and</strong> the corporate tax<br />

cannot simply be eliminated without creating a large loophole. It is,<br />

however, possible to relieve double taxation of dividends, keeping<br />

full taxation at the corporate level only <strong>for</strong> income that is retained.<br />

The Treasury Department study of tax simplification <strong>and</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m has<br />

been guided by the need <strong>for</strong> balance in the treatment of corporations<br />

<strong>and</strong> individual taxpayers. The corporate tax rate shoulg be no higher<br />

than -- <strong>and</strong>, as has been the case historically, perhaps somewhat below<br />

-- the top rate applied to income of individuals. If the corporate<br />

rate <strong>and</strong> the top individual rate differ significantly, there would be<br />

an artificial inducement either <strong>for</strong> or against use of the corporate<br />

<strong>for</strong>m.<br />

Economic <strong>Growth</strong><br />

The U.S. economy has long been hampered by a combination of<br />

defects in its tax system. High marginal tax rates discourage work,<br />

saving <strong>and</strong> investment, <strong>and</strong> invention <strong>and</strong> innovation. Heavy reliance<br />

on income taxation, rather than taxes on consumption, has produced a<br />

further disincentive <strong>for</strong> saving. Preferential tax treatment of<br />

particular industries -- industrial policy implemented through tax<br />

policy -- causes too much labor <strong>and</strong> capital to flow into the favored<br />

industries, <strong>and</strong> too little into other sectors. In many instances, it<br />

is difficult to establish new businesses simply because the tax system<br />

places them at a severe competitive disadvantage. In extreme cases<br />

tax-preferred investments that lose money on a be<strong>for</strong>e-tax basis are<br />

profitable once tax savings are considered. The result of all this<br />

tax-induced interference with market <strong>for</strong>ces is lost opportunities <strong>for</strong><br />

productive investment <strong>and</strong> needless sacrifice of national output. Economic<br />

growth, a primary goal of the study of fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m,<br />

depends on a neutral tax system -- one that would not hinder the<br />

potential <strong>for</strong> growth inherent in a free market economy.<br />

Trade-offs<br />

In many cases the objectives of tax policy discussed above are<br />

quite consistent. Elimination of deductions not required <strong>for</strong> the<br />

accurate measurement of income would generally simplify the tax<br />

system, promote horizontal equity, allow lower tax rates, <strong>and</strong> reduce<br />

existing distortions of economic decisions. Sometimes, however, it is<br />

necessary to strike a balance among competing objectives of sound tax<br />

policy. In some cases -- extraordinary medical expenses or the<br />

presence of dependents, <strong>for</strong> example -- deductions are justified<br />

because they affect ability to pay even if they do not affect income.


- 19 -<br />

#any of the deductions <strong>and</strong> credits that complicate the tax system<br />

were enacted -- <strong>and</strong> are defended -- as necessary to avoid inequities.<br />

For example, almost everyone agrees that taxpayers should be allowed<br />

to claim-exemptions <strong>for</strong> dependents, but implementing the dependency<br />

test can be complicated in certain cases. Deductions <strong>for</strong> extraordinary<br />

medical expenses are necessary <strong>for</strong> the measurement of the<br />

ability to pay taxes; but documenting them can be very time-consuming.<br />

Low-income individuals may not realize that they are eligible <strong>for</strong> the<br />

earned income tax credit; they are also least able to deal with the<br />

complexity it entails <strong>and</strong> may not realize that the IRS will compute<br />

the credit if a return is filed. The two-earner deduction involves<br />

complicated conflicts between equal treatment of equals, incentive<br />

effects, fairness to families, <strong>and</strong> fairness across income classes, as<br />

well a: trade-offs between these effects <strong>and</strong> simplicity.<br />

Measuring income accurately or implementing a tax on consumed<br />

income, either of which would be desirable on grounds of fairness <strong>and</strong><br />

neutrality, may involve difficult problems of compliance <strong>and</strong> administration,<br />

<strong>for</strong> example, in the valuation of certain fringe benefits.<br />

Measurement of income as it accrues on infrequently traded or unique<br />

assets would present insurmountablv administrative problems. On the<br />

other h<strong>and</strong>, taxing capital gains on realizations allows tax to be<br />

postponed indefinitely. Calculation of business income is complicated,<br />

but legitimate business expenses, including estimated<br />

depreciation allowances, must be allowed on both equity <strong>and</strong> neutrality<br />

grounds. Implementing an inflation-proof income tax is complicated,<br />

but the alternative is to allow inflation to play havoc with effective<br />

tax rates, creating distortions <strong>and</strong> inequities. And any tax on<br />

consumption, whether a sales tax or a progressive personal tax on<br />

consumed income, raises troublesome issues of distributional equity.<br />

The Treasury Department has carefully weighed these competing<br />

objectives in appraising the strengths <strong>and</strong> weaknesses of the four<br />

options it considered in its study of fundamental tax simplification<br />

<strong>and</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m. Nost individuals will face a dramatically simpl.er tax<br />

system under the Treasury Department proposals. But in some cases<br />

praposed re<strong>for</strong>ms that are necessary to improve the equity <strong>and</strong><br />

neutrality of the tax law do conflict with the important goal of<br />

simplification.<br />

Fair <strong>and</strong> Ordorlj! Transition i_<br />

The present income tax is complex, it is inequitable, it causes<br />

economic distortions, <strong>and</strong> it impedes economic growth. But movement to<br />

a comprehensive tax on all income or consumption, while desirable in<br />

the long run, would involve substantial short-run shifts in resource<br />

allocation <strong>and</strong> tax burdens. Even here there are conflicts <strong>and</strong> tradeoffs<br />

-- between the advantages of rationalizing tax policy <strong>and</strong> the<br />

disruptions caused by doing so too suddenly or too rapidly.<br />

-- --<br />

<strong>Tax</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m has often <strong>and</strong> long been held hostage by failure<br />

to deal with transition issues; those who would be hurt by tax re<strong>for</strong>m


- 20 -<br />

have successfully resisted change. An important objective of the<br />

Treasury Department's study of fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m is the<br />

specification of transition rules that will allow tax re<strong>for</strong>m to become<br />

a reality. Transition steps are necessary both to ease the impact of<br />

tax changes <strong>and</strong> to make tax re<strong>for</strong>m a political reality. Without them,<br />

re<strong>for</strong>m will not occur, <strong>and</strong> this generation will leave to the next a<br />

tax system that remains deeply flawed.<br />

Rather than being introduced suddenly, with little or no time <strong>for</strong><br />

adjustment, some components of fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m should be<br />

introduced gradually, in order to avoid windfall gains <strong>and</strong> losses <strong>and</strong><br />

economic dislocations. Gradual introduction of fiscal measures can<br />

take a number of <strong>for</strong>ms, depending on circumstances. Effective dates<br />

can be postponed <strong>and</strong> implementation can be phased in, starting either<br />

at once or at a subsequent effective date. Gr<strong>and</strong>fathering of income<br />

from certain assets or of groups benefitting from certain provisions<br />

(<strong>for</strong> example, applying new provisions only to new purchasers of<br />

assets, <strong>and</strong> not to income from old assets) is appropriate in some<br />

cases. These mechanisms are among those proposed to meet the final<br />

criterion of a fair <strong>and</strong> orderly transition t o a simpler, fairer, <strong>and</strong><br />

more neutral tax system.<br />

__ Addendum:<br />

Implications <strong>for</strong> Spending<br />

Most of the exclusions, adjustments, itemized deductions, <strong>and</strong><br />

credits currently found in the income tau are not required <strong>for</strong> the<br />

accurate measurement of income or ability to pay taxes. Rather, they<br />

are simply subsidies <strong>for</strong> private activities that are administered<br />

through the tax system.<br />

Administering subsidies through the tax system creates complexity<br />

<strong>for</strong> taxpayers. By allowing taxpayers in similar circumstances to pay<br />

greatly different amounts of tax, it undermines taxpayer morale in a<br />

way that direct spending does not. The Treasury Department thus<br />

recommends that most of the exclusions, adjustments, deductions, tax<br />

deferral provisions, <strong>and</strong> credits that are inconsistent with a<br />

comprehensive definition of income <strong>for</strong> tax purposes be repealed or<br />

sharply curtailed.<br />

This recommendation should not be construed to imply that none of<br />

the currently tax-preferred activities is worthy of direct public<br />

support. Such a judgment would go beyond the m<strong>and</strong>ate from the<br />

President to propose re<strong>for</strong>ms that will make the tax system broadbased,<br />

simple, <strong>and</strong> fair. Except in a few cases this study makes no<br />

recommendations about the need to enact spending proposals to replace<br />

subsidies currently administered through the tax system. Of course,<br />

to the extent that direct spending replaces tax subsidies, tax rates<br />

could not be reduced as much as proposed.


- 21 -<br />

Chapter 3 <br />

THE FOUR OPTIONS <br />

In its study of fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m, the Treasury Department<br />

focused on four basic options: a pure flat tax; a "modified" flat<br />

tax; a consumed income tax; <strong>and</strong> a general sales tax, such as a valueadded<br />

tax or a Federal retail sales tax. These four options are<br />

described <strong>and</strong> analyzed briefly in this chapter. Chapters 4 to 8<br />

describe the Treasury Department proposal <strong>for</strong> a modified flat tax in<br />

greater detail <strong>and</strong> compare it with similar proposals that have been<br />

advanced recently by several members of Congress. Chapters 9 <strong>and</strong> 10<br />

provide further analysis of the consumed income tax <strong>and</strong> value-added<br />

tax, two options which are not being proposed. (Volume I1 contains<br />

details of the Treasury Department proposal <strong>for</strong> a modified flat tax<br />

<strong>and</strong> Volume 111 analyzes a value-added tax in greater detail.)<br />

I. The Pure Flat <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

Most pure "flat tax" proposals share two characteristics: a much<br />

more comprehensive tax base than under current law <strong>and</strong> a single low<br />

tax rate. In some flat tax proposals the tax base is consumption,<br />

rather than income. In the most extreme proposals there are virtually<br />

no deviations from a comprehensive definition of income or<br />

consumption, except <strong>for</strong> personal exemptions.<br />

A. Advantages of the Flat <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

A pure flat tax would have major advantages over current law,<br />

because of the breadth of the tax base <strong>and</strong> the low tax rate made<br />

possible by the comprehensive base. Such a tax would reduce the<br />

inequality of tax treatment of families with equal incomes, the<br />

distortions of economic decisions, the disincentives to growth, <strong>and</strong><br />

some of the complexities that plague the current tax system. Because<br />

the present system contains many exclusions, exemptions, deductions,<br />

<strong>and</strong> credits not required <strong>for</strong> the accurate measurement of income, it<br />

requires higher tax rates than would be necessary under a pure flat<br />

tax. In addition, a uni<strong>for</strong>m tax rate lessens problems inherent in<br />

steeply graduated rates, such as the bunching of income,<br />

discrimination between single persons <strong>and</strong> married couples, <strong>and</strong><br />

incentives to shift income artificially to family members subject to<br />

lower tax rates.<br />

B. Distributional Inequity of the Pure Flat <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

These important advantages must be compared to the troublesome<br />

distributional implications of a pure flat rate tax. A single,<br />

totally flat rate, whether imposed on income or on consumption, would<br />

involve a substantial shift of tax burden from those in the highest<br />

income brackets to low- or middle-income taxpayers. Under current law<br />

families with less than $20,000 of income pay 5.5 percent of the


_I<br />

~<br />

- 22 -<br />

Table 3-1<br />

Percentage Distributions of Individual Income <strong>Tax</strong> Liability<br />

Under Current Law, a Pure Flat <strong>Tax</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

the Treasury Department Proposal,<br />

by Economic Income Class of Families<br />

(1983 Levels of Income)<br />

Share of <strong>Tax</strong> 1/<br />

: Share of : Current : Pure : Treasury<br />

Family Economic Income Class: income : law flat : Department<br />

: tax l-/ : tax &/ : proposal A/<br />

(. ................... percent .................... )<br />

Less than $20,000 ......... 13.7 5.5 9.5 5.1<br />

$20,000 to $50,000 ........ 41.6 34.6 41.6 34.3<br />

$50,000 to $100,000 ....... 30.4 32.7 32.6 33.1<br />

$100,000 or more .......... 14.3 27.2 16.3 27.5<br />

- - -<br />

Total ............. 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0<br />

Office of the Secretary OE the Treasury<br />

Office of <strong>Tax</strong> Policy<br />

-1/ Current law applicable in 1986.<br />

-2/ A single rate of 16.8 percent applied t o taxable income under the Treasury<br />

Department proposal, which essentially exempts from tax those in poverty.<br />

-3/ A three-rate graduated structure applied to taxable income under the<br />

Treasury Department proposal, which essentially exempts from tax those in<br />

poverty .


individual income tax, although they receive 13.7 percent of the<br />

income. (See Table 3-1.) A pure flat tax even one with<br />

liberalized personal exemptions <strong>and</strong> zero-bracket amounts designed to<br />

eliminate tax <strong>for</strong> families at or below the poverty level -- would<br />

raise the share of taxes paid by families with less than $20,000 of<br />

income to 9.5 percent of the total. This pure flat tax would sharply<br />

reduce the share of individual taxes paid by those with incomes over<br />

$50,000, from 59.9 percent under current law to 48.9 percent. Stated<br />

differently, taxpayers with incomes above $50,000 would pay about 18<br />

percent less under a revenue-neutral flat-rate tax than under current<br />

law. (See Table 3-2.) Conversely, those with incomes between $20,000<br />

<strong>and</strong> $50,000 would pay one-fifth more tax than under current law.<br />

Because of the massive redistribution of tax burdens a pure flat tax<br />

would produce, the Treasury Department recommends against its<br />

enactment.<br />

11. Reconciliation: The Modified Flat <strong>Tax</strong><br />

In order to simplify <strong>and</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m the existing income tax, but avoid<br />

the massive redistribution of tax liabilities of a pure flat tax, the<br />

Treasury Department proposes that a modified flat tax on income be<br />

enacted. The proposal is broadly consistent with several modified<br />

flat tax proposals advanced by members of Congress, but it goes beyond<br />

them in the scope of its recommendations <strong>for</strong> simplification <strong>and</strong><br />

re<strong>for</strong>m.<br />

Many believe that conflict between the goal of distributional<br />

equity, on the one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> the goals of simplicity, economic<br />

neutrality, encouragement of growth, <strong>and</strong> equal tax treatment of equals<br />

(horizontal equity), on the other, is inherent in any flat tax<br />

proposal, whether pure or modified. In fact, this conflict is more<br />

apparent than real. Most of the advantages commonly attributed to<br />

pure flat tax proposals result primarily from the inclusion of all<br />

income (or consumption) in the tax base <strong>and</strong> have relatively little to<br />

do with whether tax rates are flat or graduated. Conversely, the<br />

redistribution of the tax burden from high- to middle-income taxpayers<br />

that would result from application of a flat rate cannot be traced to<br />

implementation of a comprehensive definition of the tax base. It<br />

results entirely from the substitution of a flat rate <strong>for</strong> graduated<br />

rates.<br />

Because the effects produced by a totally flat rate are quite<br />

distinct from those resulting from base-broadening, it is possible to<br />

achieve most of the base-broadening advantages of a pure flat tax<br />

without the shift in tax burdens among income classes a pure flat rate<br />

would entail. This is, in effect, the approach taken in proposals <strong>for</strong><br />

a modified flat tax. By combining a more comprehensive definition of<br />

income than under current law with modestly graduated low rates,<br />

modified flat tax proposals are able to achieve gains in simplicity,<br />

economic neutrality, equal tax treatment of families with equal<br />

incomes, <strong>and</strong> economic growth, without sacrificing distributional<br />

equity.


- 24 -<br />

Table 3-2<br />

Changes in <strong>Tax</strong> Resulting from a Pure Flat <strong>Tax</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> the Treasury Department Proposal<br />

Distributed by Family Economic Income Class<br />

Family Economic<br />

Income Class<br />

(1983 Levels of Income)<br />

- -<br />

: Pure Flat <strong>Tax</strong> 2/ : Treasury Proposal 3/<br />

:Current: : Chanae from : : Chanse trom<br />

: law :Amount: current law :Amount: current law<br />

: tax L/:<br />

:Amount:Percent: :?mount:Percent<br />

(.... $ billions .....) (. 8 .)( $ billions )( . % .)<br />

Less than $20,000 ..... 14.6 25.0 10.5 72.1 12.3 -2.3 -15.7<br />

$20,000 - $50,000 ..... 91.2 109.6 18.4 20.2 82.8 -8.4 -9.2<br />

$50,000 - $100,000 .... 86.4 86.1 -0.3 -0.4 80.0 -6.4 -7.4<br />

$100,000 or more ...... 71.6 43.1 -28.6 -39.9 66.4 -5.2 -7.2<br />

- -<br />

~-I_______<br />

Total ................. 263.8 263.8 0 0 241.5 -22.3 -8.5<br />

Office of the Secretary of the Treasury<br />

Office of <strong>Tax</strong> Policy<br />

I 1/ Current<br />

law applicable in 1986.<br />

-2/ A single rate of 16.8 percent applied to taxable income under the Treasury<br />

Department proposal, which essentially exempts from tax those i n poverty.<br />

-3/ A three-rate graduated structure applied to taxable income under the<br />

Treasury Department proposal, which essentially exempts from tax those in<br />

poverty.


- 25 -<br />

A modified flat tax that imcludes only two or three tax rates<br />

covering a wide range of low to middle income would be indistinguishable<br />

from a pure flat tax <strong>for</strong> most taxpayers. (Of course, low-income<br />

taxpayers would pay lower rates under a modified flat tax than under a<br />

pure flat tax.) The use of flat rates over wide ranges of incomes<br />

minimizes marriage penalties <strong>and</strong> bonuses, as well as problems caused<br />

by bunching of income in one year.<br />

A. Questions Common to income <strong>and</strong> Consumed incorne <strong>Tax</strong>es<br />

The term "modified flat tax" could be applied to an exp<strong>and</strong>ed<br />

income tax base or to a consumption tax base. The only inherent<br />

difference between these two tax bases involves the treatment of<br />

saving. Under a tax on consumed income, a deduction is allowed <strong>for</strong><br />

net saving, whereas under an ordinary income tax it is not. This<br />

distinction is explained briefly in part B of this section <strong>and</strong> at<br />

greater length in chapter 9. Under either approach many of the issues<br />

that must be answered in defining the tax base are the same. Should<br />

fringe benefits provided by employers be taxed, or should they be<br />

exempt? HOW are business assets to be distinguished from private<br />

assets? Should housing receive preferential treatment? Should<br />

charitable contributions be favored? Should activities of state <strong>and</strong><br />

local governments be subsidized through the tax system? Should a tax<br />

continue to be Levied on corporations? The remainder of this section<br />

focuses on questions such as these, on suggested modifications of the<br />

present taxation of capital <strong>and</strong> business income, <strong>and</strong> on proposed<br />

deviations from the pure income tax model.<br />

B. Advantages of a Comprehensive Measure of income<br />

A comprehensive definition of taxable income or consumption is<br />

generally conducive to simplicity <strong>and</strong> to equal treatment of equally<br />

situated taxpayers, while retreat from a comprehensive base generally<br />

involves complexity <strong>and</strong> horizontal inequity. A comprehensive tax base<br />

is also necessary <strong>for</strong> economic neutrality, since high tax rates <strong>and</strong><br />

discrimination between various ways of earning <strong>and</strong> spending income<br />

distort economic decisions.<br />

Omissions from the tax base generally also result in a<br />

distribution of tax liability between families with different income<br />

levels that is at least somewhat different -- <strong>and</strong> frequently markedly<br />

different -- from what the schedule of marginal tax rates suggests.<br />

Finally, any deviations from a comprehensive definition of income,<br />

unless based on widely-held views of tax equity <strong>and</strong> other generally<br />

accepted economic objectives, are likely to reduce the perceived<br />

fairness of the tax system <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e undermine taxpayer morale.<br />

Erosion of the tax base also has a heavy political cost. If one<br />

special interest group is allowed a deduction or credit not required<br />

<strong>for</strong> the accurate measurement of income, it becomes more difficult to<br />

resist others. Ultimately, the only way to maintain a fair tax base<br />

-- one without the many loopholes in the present tax code --<br />

is to


- 26 -<br />

resist requests <strong>for</strong> special treatment. For all those reasons, the tax<br />

base should be defined as broadly as possible.<br />

C. Distributional Neutrality<br />

Modification of the uni<strong>for</strong>m rate contained in flat-tax proposals<br />

also involves difficult trade-offs. <strong>Fairness</strong> suggests that a single<br />

flat tax rate should not be levied at all income levels. And yet tax<br />

equity <strong>and</strong> due regard <strong>for</strong> the disincentive effects of high marginal<br />

tax rates dictate that the top marginal tax rates should not be<br />

excessive. By-<strong>and</strong>-large, the rate structure proposed by the Treasury<br />

Department, when applied to an exp<strong>and</strong>ed definition of taxable income,<br />

is designed to approximate the distribution of tax liabilities that<br />

prevails under current law. The primary exception is at the bottom of<br />

the income scale. Increased personal exemptions <strong>and</strong> zero-bracket<br />

amounts will ensure that most taxpayers with incomes below the poverty<br />

line will be exempt from income tax altogether.<br />

An important feature of modified flat tax proposals is a reduction<br />

in the number of tax rates. Because rates would be constant over much<br />

wider ranges of incomes than under current law, a modified flat tax<br />

system would resemble a flat-rate system <strong>for</strong> most taxpayers. Of<br />

course, <strong>for</strong> marginal tax rates to be reduced significantly, without<br />

sacrificing revenue, it would be necessary to define the tax base much<br />

more comprehensively than under current law.<br />

D. Issues in Income Measurement<br />

At a conceptual level, the proper tax treatment of many currently<br />

untaxed sources <strong>and</strong> uses of income is clear. Fringe benefits provided<br />

by employers <strong>and</strong> payments that represent wage replacement should be<br />

included in income subject to tax. Only in a few cases do problems of<br />

valuation make this ideal unattainable, as in the case of small<br />

hard-to-value fringe benefits recently determined to be tax-exempt in<br />

the 1984 Deficit Reduction Act. <strong>Tax</strong>payers should not be allowed<br />

business deductions <strong>for</strong> what are really personal expenses, <strong>and</strong> they<br />

should not be allowed artificially to shift income between family<br />

members to reduce taxes. Preferential treatment of above-average<br />

amounts of charitable contributions is desirable, in order to maintain<br />

incentives <strong>for</strong> contributions; moreover, taxpayers making extraordinary<br />

contributions may be considered to have less taxpaying ability than<br />

others with similar incomes. The deduction of state <strong>and</strong> local taxes<br />

should be phased out, both because it is unnecessary <strong>for</strong> the<br />

measurement of income <strong>and</strong> because there is no compelling reason <strong>for</strong><br />

the deduction. The Federal Government, through the tax system, in<br />

effect pays part of the cost of expenditures by state <strong>and</strong> local<br />

governments. Only real income should be taxed; capital gains <strong>and</strong><br />

nominal profits that only represent inflation should not be taxed.<br />

Special credits <strong>and</strong> deductions that are not required to measure<br />

income accurately should be repealed. These include depreciation<br />

allowances that are greater than real economic depreciation,<br />

percentage depletion allowances in excess of cost depletion,


- 27 -<br />

intangible drilling expenses, <strong>and</strong> various <strong>for</strong>ms of preferential<br />

treatment currently accorded certain financial institutions.<br />

particularly important is the need to deal with inconsistencies in the<br />

tax law that give rise to tax shelters. <strong>Tax</strong> shelters <strong>and</strong> the<br />

complexities, inequities, <strong>and</strong> distortions they create can be<br />

eliminated only by repealing the tax preferences that make them<br />

possible. The disparate tax treatment of corporations <strong>and</strong><br />

partnerships should be rationalized by reducing the double taxation of<br />

dividends <strong>and</strong> by treating large limited partnerships like corporations<br />

<strong>for</strong> tax purposes.<br />

E. Disparities in Effective <strong>Tax</strong> Rates<br />

A simple example illustrates the lack of fairness <strong>and</strong> neutrality<br />

of the present income tax. The first column of Table 3-3 shows how<br />

the current tax system treats two different types of labor income,<br />

wages <strong>and</strong> salaries <strong>and</strong> fringe benefits, <strong>and</strong> two <strong>for</strong>ms of capital<br />

income, interest <strong>and</strong> capital gains. Under present law, a taxpayer<br />

subject to the top statutory rate of 50 percent would actually pay<br />

effective tax rates on various <strong>for</strong>ms of real income ranging from zero<br />

to 125 percent. The disparities in effective rates are less dramatic<br />

<strong>for</strong> taxpayers with lower incomes, but they are qualitatively the same.<br />

Whereas wages <strong>and</strong> salaries are taxed at an effective rate equal to<br />

the statutory rate, certain fringe benefits are not taxed under<br />

current law. The inequity <strong>and</strong> non-neutrality of this tax treatment<br />

are obvious. Recipients of fringe benefits are treated more favorably<br />

than those who receive labor income as wages <strong>and</strong> salaries. Besides<br />

being unfair, this provides an artificial incentive <strong>for</strong> greater<br />

consumption of goods <strong>and</strong> services that can be provided as tax-free<br />

fringe benefits. Under a comprehensive definition of income, wages<br />

<strong>and</strong> fringe benefits would be taxed identically, that is, at the same<br />

effective rates.<br />

The story is somewhat more complicated <strong>for</strong> capital income, since<br />

the effective tax rate depends crucially on the rate of inflation.<br />

The example in Table 3-3 assumes that the interest rate is 4 percent<br />

if there is no inflation, but 10 percent if the inflation rate is 6<br />

percent. It also assumes that capital assets that have no current<br />

yield are appreciating at the rate of interest, either 4 percent or 10<br />

percent. In the absence of inflation, interest <strong>and</strong> long-term capital<br />

gains are taxed at rates of 50 percent <strong>and</strong> 20 percent, respectively.<br />

But if the inflation rate is 10 percent, tax on nominal interest<br />

income is 125 percent of real interest income, <strong>and</strong> real long-term<br />

capital gains are taxed at an effective rate of 50 percent, despite<br />

the apparent top rate on long-term capital gains of 20 percent. At<br />

higher rates of inflation, effective tax rates on real interest income<br />

<strong>and</strong> real capital gains are even higher.<br />

The statutory tax rate collected on interest income equals the<br />

effective rate only if there is no inflation. At inflation rates<br />

within recent experience, the effective tax rates on real interest<br />

income are much higher than the statutory rates suggest. Besides


eing unfair, this penalizes saving <strong>and</strong> encourages borrowing, with<br />

adverse effects on capital <strong>for</strong>mation <strong>and</strong> growth. This problem can be<br />

overcome in the context of an income tax only by providing an<br />

inflation adjustment <strong>for</strong> debt.<br />

Long-term capital gains nominally benefit from preferential tax<br />

treatment. Thus in the absence of inflation, they are taxed less<br />

heavily than wages <strong>and</strong> salaries <strong>and</strong> interest income, as shown in Tabie<br />

3-3, creating both inequities <strong>and</strong> misallocations of capital. A<br />

comprehensive definition of income would not apply different tax rates<br />

to capital gains <strong>and</strong> other income. But if inflation is high <strong>and</strong><br />

illusory capital gains are taxed, as under the current system, effective<br />

tax rates on real gains are high; inequities <strong>and</strong> distortions are<br />

magnified <strong>and</strong> invention <strong>and</strong> innovation suffer. A comprehensive<br />

definition of income that included indexing (inflation adjustment) of<br />

the basis (cost) of assets used in calculating capital gains <strong>and</strong><br />

losses would ensure that fictitious gains are not taxed.<br />

The second column of Table 3-3 illustrates the advantage of a<br />

comprehensive definition of taxable income. The current top statutory<br />

rate of 50 percent is used <strong>for</strong> illustrative purposes; of course, with<br />

a more comprehensive definition of income, a lower rate would be<br />

possible. For taxpayers subject to the highest marginal tax rate<br />

under current law, income from all sources would be taxed at a rate of<br />

50 percent, regardless of the rate of inflation. Subjecting all real<br />

income to tax treats equally situated families equally <strong>and</strong> reduces<br />

tax-induced distortions of economic decisions.<br />

F. Simplification <br />

Simplifying the income tax <strong>for</strong> most individual taxpayers has been<br />

an important objective of the Treasury Department study. Simplification<br />

would result from several general approaches. First, increasing<br />

the personal exemptions <strong>and</strong> zero-bracket amounts will eliminate many<br />

poor Americans from the income tax rolls. Second, several itemized<br />

deductions will be eliminated or subjected to floors. Like the floor<br />

under the current deduction <strong>for</strong> medical expenses, these floors will<br />

reduce the need <strong>for</strong> so many to keep records of deductible expenditures<br />

<strong>for</strong> extended periods of time. With the exp<strong>and</strong>ed zero-bracket amount<br />

<strong>and</strong> fewer deductions, about one-third fewer taxpayers will find it<br />

advantageous to itemize deductions. Third, most tax credits would<br />

simply be eliminated. The Treasury Department believes that most<br />

Americans would rather pay low taxes on all of their income than pay<br />

high taxes on part of it; doing so is simpler, as well as fairer <strong>and</strong><br />

more neutral toward economic behavior.


- 29 -<br />

Table 3-3 <br />

Illustration of Disparities in Effective <strong>Tax</strong> Rates <br />

Effective <strong>Tax</strong> Rate on <br />

<strong>Tax</strong>payer in 50% Bracket <br />

Type of Income Current Comprehensive<br />

Law<br />

Definition of<br />

Real Income<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>able wages <strong>and</strong> salaries<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>-free fringe benefits <br />

Interest: <br />

No inflation <br />

6 percent inflation <br />

Long-term capital gains: <br />

NO inflation <br />

6 percent inflation <br />

50 50 <br />

0 50 <br />

50 50<br />

125 50<br />

20 50<br />

50 50<br />

Office of the Secretary of Treasury November 25, 1984<br />

Office of <strong>Tax</strong> Analysis


111. consumed Income <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

Consumption provides an alternative to income as the basis <strong>for</strong><br />

personal taxation. A personal tax on consumption, or consumed income,<br />

would be levied by exempting all saving from tax, allowing a deduction<br />

<strong>for</strong> repayment of debt, taxing all borrowing <strong>and</strong> withdrawals from<br />

savings. Consumed income would be reported on a <strong>for</strong>m much like the<br />

present <strong>for</strong>m 1040. Deductions would be allowed <strong>for</strong> deposits in<br />

"qualified accounts" similar to existing individual retirement<br />

accounts (IRAs); withdrawals from such accounts would be subject to<br />

tax. (Further details of such a tax are described in Chapter 9.)<br />

Though a flat rate could be applied to the consumption base<br />

calculated in this way, most proposals <strong>for</strong> a consumed income tax<br />

postulate personal exemptions <strong>and</strong> graduated rate schedules. Thus, a<br />

consumed income tax could be progressive, if that were desired.<br />

Itemized deductions could also be allowed, as under the existing<br />

income tax.<br />

A. Administrative AavantaE<br />

The current income tax is based on the principle that income<br />

should be taxed annually as it is realized. It represents a practical<br />

compromise between administrative feasibility <strong>and</strong> the objective of<br />

taxing income as it accrues. Conceptually, accrued income can be<br />

defined as the amount a taxpayer could consume without reducing his OK<br />

her net wealth, that is, as the total of what the taxpayer actually<br />

consumes plus the change in his or her net wealth. Many practical<br />

difficulties plague application of this conceptual ideal as the basis<br />

of an income tax. Compromise between achieving the ideal, on the one<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> avoiding complexity, on the other, produces a system that<br />

departs significantly from the conceptual ideal. Examples of compromise<br />

include taxation of capital gaitis only when they are realized,<br />

commonly by sale of an asset, rather than as they accrue. Compromises<br />

such as this can allow tax on large amounts of income to be postponed<br />

indefinitely, or even avoided altogether, as when appreciated property<br />

is transferred at death. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, ef<strong>for</strong>ts to administer the<br />

tax on an accrual basis, by levying tax be<strong>for</strong>e realization occurs, can<br />

introduce significant complexity an6 hardship. For example, if tax<br />

were levied on unrealized gains on closeiy-held business, valuation<br />

would be difficult; payment of tax, moreover, could frequently be<br />

required even though there is no cash flow with which to pay the tax.<br />

Because it avoids the problems inherent in accrual taxation, a tax<br />

on personal consumption is simpler i n many respects than an income<br />

tax. The consumed income tax is simpler because all costs of investment<br />

are deducted immediately ("expensed"), rather than<br />

depreciated over the life of assets; because all costs of creating<br />

inventories are expensed, rather than being recognized only as goods<br />

are sold; <strong>and</strong> because capital gains are not taxed, as such. A corporate<br />

income tax is not an essential part of an ideal tax system based<br />

on consumption; if retained, it woulc? serve only as a withholding<br />

device.


- 31 -<br />

The consumed income tax has another major administrat ve advantage<br />

over the income tax. Under the present income tax, the m asurement of<br />

income is commonly distorted by inflation. Because consumption<br />

inherently occurs in dollars of the current year, the measurement of<br />

the base of the consumed income tax cannot be distorted by inflation.<br />

Since depreciable assets <strong>and</strong> inventory investments are expensed,<br />

inflation cannot erode the value of future deductions because there<br />

are none. Interest is not taxed, unless spent on consumption, <strong>and</strong><br />

thus the inflation premium is not taxed. Purely inflationary capital<br />

gains are not taxed, because there is no tax on capital gains, per se<br />

5. Economic Advantages <br />

Advocates of a consumed income tax argue that it is preferable to<br />

the ordinary income tax on conceptual <strong>and</strong> economic grounds, as well as<br />

on administrative grounds. First, an income tax penalizes saving by<br />

inducing taxpayers to consume rather than save <strong>for</strong> future consumption.<br />

By comparison, under certain circumstances, a tax on consumption does<br />

not distort the choice between consuming now <strong>and</strong> saving <strong>for</strong> future<br />

consumption. This is a major attraction of any tax on consumption.<br />

Second, seen from a lifetime perspective, a tax on consumed income<br />

is said to be more equitable than an income tax. A taxpayer's total<br />

tax burden under a tax on consumed income does not depend on when<br />

income is earned or spent, at least under fairly restrictive<br />

simplifying assumptions. By comparison, an income tax imposes a<br />

heavier burden on those who earn income relatively early in life or<br />

spend it relatively late.<br />

Despite the manifest attractions of the tax on consumed income,<br />

the Treasury Department does not propose it as either a replacement<br />

<strong>for</strong>, or a supplement to, the income tax. Several defects <strong>and</strong><br />

difficulties of a consumed income tax lead to this conclusion.<br />

C. Transition Problems <br />

First, the current existence of substantial wealth, much of which<br />

has been accumulated from after-tax income, poses difficult transition<br />

problems. <strong>Tax</strong>ing all consumption financed from such wealth would<br />

constitute a cruel trick on those who did not expect it -- especially<br />

those who have saved after-tax dollars <strong>for</strong> retirement. Nor would<br />

complete exemption of consumption financed from existing wealth be<br />

satisfactory. Such an exemption would either be enormously expensive<br />

in terms of lost revsnue or entail extremely high tax rates during the<br />

transition period. Worse, it would allow wealthy taxpayers to escape<br />

taxation <strong>for</strong> many generations if they consumed only old wealth <strong>and</strong><br />

saved all current income.<br />

On equity grounds, a compromise between complete exemption <strong>and</strong><br />

full taxation of consumption from existing wealth would be necessary.<br />

Such a compromise might allow each taxpayer above a given aye to enjoy<br />

a given amount of tax-free consumption during his or her lifetime.


- 32 -<br />

But phasing in a consumed income tax in this way would involve<br />

transition rules that could complicate the tax system <strong>for</strong> ordinary<br />

taxpayers <strong>for</strong> a generation.<br />

A different type of transition problem would result from the<br />

possibility of avoiding taxes by hoarding money be<strong>for</strong>e the effective<br />

date of the new tax. Arter the effective date the taxpayer could<br />

either deposit the hoarded funds in a qualified account in order to<br />

get a tax deduction <strong>for</strong> saving or use them to meet living expenses<br />

without paying tax. Alternatively, pre-effective date investments in<br />

<strong>for</strong>eign banks could be liquidated after the effective date <strong>and</strong><br />

reinvested as tax-deductible saving. Even though this would be a<br />

temporary problem of transition, it would undermine both the revenue<br />

yield <strong>and</strong> fairness of the tax during that period.<br />

D. Perception Problems <br />

Even though a taxpayer’s st<strong>and</strong>ard of living, as reflected by his<br />

level of consumption, may be considered by many to be an appropriate<br />

base <strong>for</strong> taxation, the consumed income tax suffers from an important<br />

perception problem. <strong>Tax</strong>payers presumably would welcome the<br />

opportunity to postpone taxes on amounts saved, paying tax only when<br />

dissaving <strong>and</strong> consumption occurs; such is the tax treatment currently<br />

accorded saving in qualified pension accounts. But to be consistent,<br />

it would also be necessary to tax amounts borrowed <strong>and</strong> allow a<br />

deduction <strong>for</strong> repayment of loans. This treatment of saving <strong>and</strong><br />

dissaving would create a pattern of tax liabilities over the lifetime<br />

of the taxpayer that might be perceived to be unfair. Relative to<br />

experience under current law, tax liability would be greater during<br />

early adulthood <strong>and</strong> during retirement -- periods when financial<br />

resources are commonly strained. <strong>Tax</strong> would be relatively lower during<br />

middle age, the tine when many taxpayers receive most of their income.<br />

The fairness of including amounts borrowed in taxable consumption<br />

might be questioned, <strong>and</strong> this tax treatment might even require a<br />

constitutional arnendment.<br />

E. Complexity <strong>for</strong> Individuals <br />

A consumed income tax would be more complicated than the existing<br />

income tax <strong>for</strong> many individual taxpayers. Under the present income<br />

tax, amounts withheld on wages <strong>and</strong> salaries roughly offset tax<br />

liabilities <strong>for</strong> many taxpayers who have only modest amounts of income<br />

from capital. Relatively few taxpayers must worry about estimating<br />

liabilities <strong>and</strong> paying significant amounts of tax in addition to<br />

amounts withheld. Under the consumed income tax the situation could<br />

be quite different. Withholding might be required on borrowing <strong>and</strong><br />

withdrawals from savings; if so, “reverse withholding” would be<br />

appropriate when a loan is paid off. Even then, far more taxpayers<br />

might need to file estimated returns than now, because it would be<br />

difficult to adjust withholding rates on financial transactions to the<br />

personal circumstances of taxpayers. Moreover, many young adults <strong>and</strong>


- 33 -<br />

retired individuals are not required to file or pay -tax under an<br />

income tax, but would be required to file <strong>and</strong> pay tax under a consumed<br />

income tax.<br />

Owner-occupied housing would not be treated as an item of<br />

consumption, to be taxed in full in the year of purchase. Rather,<br />

inclusion of the purchase price in taxable consumption would be spread<br />

over the lifetime of the home, in effect, by requiring taxpayers to<br />

pay tax as their mortgages were paid off. This could be accomplished<br />

through special treatment of mortgages outside of qualified accounts.<br />

But purchases of homes from amounts saved in qualified accounts could<br />

require special averaging features that would complicate compliance<br />

<strong>for</strong> taxpayers. Ironically, individual taxpayers would, in a sense, be<br />

aslted to keep accounts resembling depreciation accounts at the same<br />

time that such accounts were eliminated <strong>for</strong> businesses.<br />

F. The Dilemma of G ifts <strong>and</strong> Bequests<br />

The proper treatment of gifts <strong>and</strong> bequests under a tax on consumed<br />

income is a fundamental issue. Under one view such transfers would<br />

not be taxed to the person making the gift or bequest; they would only<br />

be taxed when consumed by the recipient. Under a very different view,<br />

transfers would be taxed to the donor, as well as when consumed by the<br />

recipient. Advocates of this second approach argue that taxing gifts<br />

<strong>and</strong> bequests is necessary in order to realize fully the beneficial<br />

equity <strong>and</strong> efficiency effects of a consumption-based tax. They refer<br />

to this type of tax 7s a tax on lifetime income, to distinguish it<br />

from the conventiondl tax on annual income. The distributional<br />

differences in the two ways of treating gifts <strong>and</strong> bequests are, of<br />

course, substantial. The first approach would allow great <strong>for</strong>tunes to<br />

be passed from generation to generation without tax, whereas the<br />

second would subject transfers to tax.<br />

G. International Aspects<br />

No country has a tax on consumed income, although Sweden <strong>and</strong> the<br />

United Kingdom have considered it, <strong>and</strong> India <strong>and</strong> Sri Lanlta (then<br />

Ceylon) attempted to impose the tax <strong>for</strong> a brief period following World<br />

War 11. Any country imposing a consumed income tax would be very much<br />

out of step with its trading partners, all of which employ income<br />

taxes, <strong>and</strong> would face the task of renegotiating its <strong>for</strong>eign tax<br />

treaties.<br />

IV.<br />

Sales <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

The fourth option considered by the Treasury Department in its<br />

study of fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m was a general sales tax, such as a<br />

value-added tax or retail sales tax. Chapter 10 of this volume<br />

examines sales taxes in greater detail, <strong>and</strong> Volume 111 contains an<br />

even more detailed analysis, especially of the value-added tax.<br />

Serious consideration was given to only two <strong>for</strong>ms of sales tax: a<br />

single-stage retail sales tax <strong>and</strong> a value-added tax extending through


- 34 -<br />

the retail level. Alternatives such as a gross receipts or turnover<br />

tax, a general manufacturer's tax, <strong>and</strong> a value-added tax that excludes<br />

the retail level contain fundamental defects that render them<br />

inappropriate <strong>for</strong> use by a developed country such as the United<br />

States. These defects are described in greater detail in Chapter 10.<br />

Though the value-added tax (VAT) is now familiar throughout Europe<br />

<strong>and</strong> much of the rest of the world, it is new <strong>and</strong> unfamiliar in the<br />

United States. Americans there<strong>for</strong>e are likely to have difficulty<br />

appraising its economic effects. The kind of VAT most likely to be<br />

considered seriously in the United States is best seen as a particular<br />

way to administer a sales tax with economic effects very similar to<br />

those of a retail sales tax. Thus, in what follows, the discussion of<br />

the effects of a "sales tax" applies to both a VAT <strong>and</strong> a retail sales<br />

tax.<br />

General sales taxes have the advantages of not penalizing saving<br />

<strong>and</strong> investment, as income taxes do, <strong>and</strong> of being fairly neutral<br />

between ways of earning <strong>and</strong> spending money. Because their base is<br />

very large <strong>and</strong> they are collected in small increments on billions of<br />

transactions, they can efficiently <strong>and</strong> relatively painlessly raise<br />

large amounts of revenue to finance federal spending or to take<br />

pressure off the income tax. Some advocates of a national sales tax<br />

believe this to be a disadvantage <strong>and</strong> propose that any tax of this<br />

kind should be accompanied by constitutional limits on the tax rate or<br />

on Federal spending, as a percent of GNP.<br />

The following points also argue against use of a sales tax: it<br />

would involve some shift of tax liability to low-income groups; it<br />

would probably cause a one-time increase in prices; its implementation<br />

would require substantial administrative resources; <strong>and</strong> it would<br />

involve Federal intrusion on a revenue base long thought to be the<br />

fiscal preserve of state <strong>and</strong> local governments. Of these, the<br />

regressivity problem is probably the greatest.<br />

Regressivity could be eliminated, or at least reduced, by<br />

exempting from tax sales of certain goods such as food, housing, <strong>and</strong><br />

medical care, or by taxing them at reduced rates. However, exemptions<br />

<strong>and</strong> differential rates increase complexity <strong>and</strong> require higher general<br />

rates of tax. Alternatively, regressivity could be redressed by<br />

establishing a comprehensive system of refundable credits under the<br />

income tax, or by adjusting transfer payments <strong>and</strong> providing nonrefundable<br />

credits. The slight tendency toward regressivity higher up<br />

the income scale should not be addressed by application of<br />

differential rates to "luxury" consumption. European experience<br />

indicates clearly that administrative costs far outweigh any benefits<br />

of such an approach.<br />

A value-added tax would be preferable to a retail sales tax,<br />

despite the greater familiarity of the latter. A Federal retail sales<br />

tax, when combined with the retail sales taxes levied by most states,<br />

would provide irresistable inducement to tax evasion at the retail<br />

level. By comparison, the VAT would involve collection of about


- 35 -<br />

two-thirds of revenue be<strong>for</strong>e the retail stage. Moreover, a VAT would<br />

contain self-en<strong>for</strong>cement features that, while easily overstated, are<br />

quite important.<br />

An additional reason <strong>for</strong> preferring the VAT over a retail sales<br />

tax is its treatment of capital goods <strong>and</strong> intermediate products <strong>and</strong> of<br />

goods in international trade. Under a VAT, exports, capital goods,<br />

<strong>and</strong> other intermediate inputs are automatically freed of tax. By<br />

comparison, under a retail sales tax this desired result is only<br />

approximately achieved; under many state sales taxes it is not even<br />

sought.<br />

Total substitution of a sales tax <strong>for</strong> the ciirrent income tax was<br />

rejected because of the distributional inequity of such a policy. In<br />

a revenue-neutral re<strong>for</strong>m package, revenues from a sales tax could be<br />

used to reduce the income tax. This would have the advantage of<br />

shifting some of the burden of taxation from income to consumption <strong>and</strong><br />

of allowing lower income tax rates, taking pressure off the definition<br />

<strong>and</strong> measurement of taxable income. It would have the disadvantage of<br />

reducing the progressivity of the tax system. Given the considerable<br />

administrative costs implementing a sales tax would entail, however,<br />

it probably should not be imposed merely as a replacement <strong>for</strong> part of<br />

the income tax.


- 37 -<br />

Chapter 4<br />

SUMMARY OF TREASURY DEPARTMENT PROPOSALS AND THEIR EFFECTS <br />

I. The Proposals in Brief <br />

This chapter summarizes the Treasury DepaKi"nt proposals <strong>for</strong><br />

re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>and</strong> simplification of the income tax <strong>and</strong> their effects on<br />

revenues <strong>and</strong> the distribution of tax burdens. Chapter 5 provides a<br />

detailed discussion of proposals that would affect most individual<br />

taxpayers. For the most part, it deals with taxation of income from<br />

labor <strong>and</strong> self-employment. Details of proposals <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m of the<br />

taxation of corporations <strong>and</strong> of income from business <strong>and</strong> capital are<br />

presented <strong>and</strong> discussed in chapters 6 <strong>and</strong> 7. The Treasury Department<br />

proposals that affect these features of the tax law are of little<br />

direct significance <strong>for</strong> most individual taxpayers. However, the most<br />

important re<strong>for</strong>ms affecting retirement saving, the tax treatment of<br />

interest income <strong>and</strong> expense, <strong>and</strong> the taxation of capital gains are<br />

summarized briefly in chapter 5.<br />

It is worth repeating here the watchwords (described further in <br />

chapter 2) that guided development of these re<strong>for</strong>ms: simplicity;<br />

fairness; lower rates; economic neutrality; economic growth; <strong>and</strong> fair <br />

<strong>and</strong> orderly transition. <br />

A. Individuals<br />

The financial affairs of most American taxpayers are not very<br />

complicated -- certainly, they are not as complicated as the income<br />

tax law makes them appear. Exclusions, adjustments, itemized<br />

deductions, <strong>and</strong> tax credits create much of the complexity in the<br />

individual income tax. If not required <strong>for</strong> the fair <strong>and</strong> accurate<br />

measurement of income or taxpaying ability, these provisions violate<br />

basic notions of fairness <strong>and</strong> distort economic choices. By reducing<br />

the tax base, they make necessary the high tax rates that stifle<br />

incentives <strong>and</strong> retard economic growth.<br />

1. <strong>Fairness</strong> <strong>for</strong> families. The personal exemptions will be <br />

increased to $2,000, <strong>and</strong> the zero-bracket amounts will be raised to <br />

$3,800 <strong>for</strong> a coup1e.filing a joint return, to $3,500 <strong>for</strong> a head of <br />

household, <strong>and</strong> to $2,800 <strong>for</strong> a single person. This will eliminate <br />

income tax <strong>for</strong> virtually all families with incomes below the poverty<br />

level. The dollar limits on the earned income tax credit will be <br />

indexed <strong>for</strong> inflation. The tax-exempt level <strong>for</strong> the elderly will be <br />

increased slightly, even though the extra exemption <strong>for</strong> the aged will <br />

be eliminated. The special exemption <strong>for</strong> the blind will be folded <br />

into an exp<strong>and</strong>ed credit <strong>for</strong> the elderly, blind, <strong>and</strong> disabled. <br />

2. Lower tax rates. The present 14 tax rates (15 <strong>for</strong> single<br />

returns) will be collapsed into 3 rates, 15, 25, <strong>and</strong> 35 percent. (See<br />

Table 4-1.) The first of these will apply only to income above the<br />

459-370 0 - 84 - 3


- 38 -<br />

"<br />

0<br />

w<br />

A<br />

w<br />

al<br />

U<br />

al 91<br />

a<br />

Y<br />

2 4 a<br />

4<br />

... .<br />

I m " .."<br />

....I<br />

0<br />

0 0<br />

o o y g<br />

o m <br />

m . A ><br />

r m n o<br />

A d *<br />

( b e W<br />

o c<br />

c z u 9 1<br />

; o o 0 o 0<br />

o m, m<br />

m <br />

m : u 1 2<br />

; g ( b ( b<br />

.... ..."I<br />

. . " . "<br />

0<br />

0 0<br />

0 0 0 Y<br />

0 0 r a l<br />

y1<br />

A<br />

" ( b<br />

-.I<br />

* . W %<br />

. ; z g A<br />

O<br />

c o u o<br />

9 1 J J<br />

C<br />

9 0 0 0<br />

0 9 9<br />

a l n N V<br />

A * * *<br />

*" . ......".. ...... .<br />

0<br />

0 0<br />

o o m "<br />

o m .<br />

m- 2 ; s a<br />

n<br />

m<br />

* * W<br />

o c<br />

c o u a<br />

9 1 . u<br />

0 0<br />

9 0 0 0<br />

0 "<br />

a m . .<br />

m<br />

r r ( n<br />

a l n m w<br />

A " ' "<br />

....".......... ...... ..<br />

0 <br />

0 0 <br />

0 0 A­<br />

!i<br />

O m ? m ><br />

- - n o<br />

N A ( b<br />

o<br />

c<br />

c o u m<br />

( b ( b W<br />

U<br />

$ 0 0 0<br />

.... .<br />

O ? ?<br />

'm % m m<br />

UNA^<br />

A * * *<br />

......... .. ......... .


- 39 -<br />

tax threshold, which will be $11,800 <strong>for</strong> a family of four. The <br />

personal exemption, zero bracket amount, <strong>and</strong> other bracket limits will <br />

be indexed, as under current law. <br />

A couple filing a joint return will not reach the 25 <strong>and</strong> 35<br />

percent rates until taxable income exceeds $31,800 <strong>and</strong> $63,800,<br />

respectively. By comparison, in 1986 under current law <strong>and</strong> expected<br />

1985 inflation, the 25 percent rate will apply to income in excess of<br />

$26,850, <strong>and</strong> rates of 38 to 50 percent will be levied on incomes in<br />

excess of $49,980.<br />

On average, the marginal. tax rates that will be paid on economic<br />

income under the Treasury Department proposals are 20 percent lower<br />

than under current law. Individual tax liabilities will be reduced an<br />

average of 8.5 percent. Of course, the percentage reduccion in taxes<br />

is greater at the bottom of the income scale, due to the increase in<br />

the tax threshold. <strong>Tax</strong> liabilities of families with incomes below<br />

$10,000 will fall by an average of 32.5 percent <strong>and</strong> the reduction in<br />

taxes <strong>for</strong> families with income of $10,000 to $15,000 will be 16.6<br />

percent. These changes are discussed further in section 111.<br />

3. Fair <strong>and</strong> Neutral <strong>Tax</strong>ation. In order to achieve fair <strong>and</strong><br />

neutral taxation <strong>and</strong> to allow rates to be reduced, it is necessary to<br />

define the tax base more accurately <strong>and</strong> more comprehensively thanunder<br />

current law. Certain fringe benefits -- most notably the cost<br />

of medical insurance in excess of $175 per month <strong>for</strong> a family <strong>and</strong> $70<br />

per month <strong>for</strong> a single person <strong>and</strong> group term life insurance -- will be<br />

subject to tax. Payments that replace lost wages will also be taxed.<br />

Since several <strong>for</strong>ms of wage replacement will be eligible <strong>for</strong> the<br />

exp<strong>and</strong>ed credit <strong>for</strong> elderly, blind, <strong>and</strong> disabled, subjecting these<br />

<strong>for</strong>ms of income to tax generally will not affect families with incomes<br />

below the poverty line. Real capital gains will be taxed as ordinary<br />

income, but interest income <strong>and</strong> capital gains that only reflect<br />

inflation will not be taxeC at all.<br />

Deductions <strong>for</strong> expenditures that are presently tax-preferred will<br />

be eliminated or curtailed. The deduction <strong>for</strong> State <strong>and</strong> local taxes<br />

will be phased out, <strong>and</strong> itemized deductions will be allowed <strong>for</strong> charitable<br />

contributions only to the extent that they exceed 2 percent of<br />

adjusted gross income. The deduction <strong>for</strong> charitable contributions by<br />

nonitemizers will be repealed. Deductions will be al.lowed <strong>for</strong><br />

interest expense in excess of investment income only up to the amount<br />

of mortgage interest on the principal residence of the taxpayer, plus<br />

$5,000. The existing deductions <strong>for</strong> medical expenses <strong>and</strong> casualty <strong>and</strong><br />

theft losses will be retained unchanged. The complicated credit <strong>for</strong><br />

child <strong>and</strong> dependent care will be converted to a simpler deduction,<br />

available to nonitemizers as well as itemizers, in recognition that<br />

child <strong>and</strong> dependent care is an expense of earning income. Other<br />

expenses of earning income will be combined into one adjustment, or<br />

above-the-line deduction, subject to a minimis floor of one percent<br />

of adjusted gross income. The two-earner deduction will be repealed.


- 40 -<br />

Under the Treasury Department proposals it will not be possible to use <br />

gifts to children or trusts to circumvent the graduated rate <br />

structure. <br />

4. Retirement Savinq Incentives. Present law refrains from fully<br />

taxing economic income by providing tax-preferred treatment of saving<br />

<strong>for</strong> retirement. The Treasury Department-proposals will retain this<br />

treatment <strong>and</strong>, indeed, will liberalize the present tax treatment of<br />

Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs). Spouses who work in the home<br />

will be eligible to make tax-deferred contributions to an IRA on equal<br />

terms with those who are employed in the marketplace. The Treasury<br />

Department proposes that the limits on tax-deferred contributions to<br />

IRAs be raised to $2,500 ($5,000 <strong>for</strong> a husb<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> wife). This<br />

proposal will, in effect, allow the vast majority of taxpayers to<br />

defer tax on most of their financial saving.<br />

5. Simplification. The increased personal exemptions <strong>and</strong> zerobracket<br />

amounts <strong>and</strong> the curtailment of itemized deductions <strong>and</strong> credits<br />

will bring considerable simplification. Of the 97 million tax returns<br />

filed currently, 16 percent involve no tax liability. This figure<br />

will rise to 22 percent. Roughly 35 percent of all returns now report<br />

itemized deductions. This figure will drop by about a third under the<br />

Treasury Department proposals, relieving an additional 10 to 11<br />

percent of all taxpayers of the need to record expenses <strong>and</strong> itemize<br />

deductions.<br />

In order to simplify tax compliance further, the Internal Revenue <br />

Service (IRS) will examine the possibility of implementing a system<br />

under which many taxpayers would no longer be required to prepare <strong>and</strong> <br />

file tax returns. Under such a "return-free" system, the IRS would, <br />

at the election of each eligible taxpayer, compute their tax <br />

liability, based on withholding <strong>and</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mation reports provided to <br />

the IRS currently <strong>and</strong> send the taxpayer a report on the calculation of <br />

tax liability. The taxpayer would, of course, be allowed to question<br />

the IRS calculation of tax. Institution of the "return-free" system,<br />

together with the increases in zero-bracket amount <strong>and</strong> the personal<br />

exemptions, would substantially reduce the number of returns that <br />

taxpayers need to file with the IRS each year. This, in turn, would <br />

eliminate burdensome recordkeeping <strong>and</strong> cost requirements incurred by <br />

taxpayers in preparing returns. <br />

B. <strong>Tax</strong>ation of Capital <strong>and</strong> Business Income <br />

The taxation of capital <strong>and</strong> business income in the United States<br />

is deeply flawed. It is best characterized as irrational <strong>and</strong><br />

internally inconsistent. Effective tax rates on investment income are<br />

unpredictable, as they vary tremendously with inflation. The tax law<br />

provides subsidies to particular <strong>for</strong>ms of investment that are unfair<br />

<strong>and</strong> that seriously distort choices in the use of the Nation's scarce<br />

capital. The interaction of various provisions results in opportunities<br />

<strong>for</strong> tax shelters that allow wealthy individuals to pay little<br />

tax, create the perception of a fundamentally unfair tax system, <strong>and</strong><br />

further distort economic choices. The double taxation of dividends


discourages equity investment in the corporate sector, <strong>and</strong> needlessly<br />

high marginal tax rates create disincentives <strong>for</strong> saving, investment,<br />

invention, <strong>and</strong> innovation. Moreover, high marginal rates encourage<br />

ef<strong>for</strong>ts to obtain additional special tax benefits which, if <br />

successful, further erode the tax base <strong>and</strong> necessitate even higher <br />

rates in a vicious cycle. The international allocation of IJ.S. <br />

capital is also distorted. <br />

The tax re<strong>for</strong>ms proposed by the Treasury Department will<br />

rationalize the taxation of income from business <strong>and</strong> capital. The<br />

primary objective of re<strong>for</strong>m is to subject real economic income from<br />

all sources to consistent tax treatment. IJni<strong>for</strong>m taxation of all<br />

income is necessary in order to minimize interference of the tax<br />

system with the market-determined allocation of economic resources<br />

among competing uses. A comprehensive <strong>and</strong> consistent definition of<br />

the tax base is also needed to restore both the fairness of the tax<br />

system <strong>and</strong> the public perception of fairness. Finally, the tax base<br />

must be broadened in order to allow the reduction of both individual<br />

<strong>and</strong> corporate income tax rates.<br />

1. <strong>Tax</strong>ing Real Economic Income. Real economic income should be<br />

measured accurately during periods of inflation. The Treasury<br />

Department proposes that inflation adjustments be made in the<br />

calculation of depreciation allowances, capital gains, the cost of<br />

goods sold from inventories, certain charitable contributions, <strong>and</strong><br />

interest income <strong>and</strong> expense. This re<strong>for</strong>m will eliminate the need <strong>for</strong><br />

the arbitrary ad hoc adjustments <strong>for</strong> inflation currently incorporated<br />

in the investment tax credit, the accelerated write-off of depreciable<br />

property, <strong>and</strong> the partial exclusion of long-term capital gains.<br />

Replacing the investment tax credit (ITC) <strong>and</strong> the Accelerated Cost<br />

Recovery System (ACRS) with real economic depreciation <strong>and</strong> taxing real<br />

capital gains as ordinary income will eliminate the great disparities<br />

in the taxation of various industries under current law. Inflation<br />

adjustment will prevent effective tax rates on investment income from<br />

depending on the rate of inflation in ways that vary across asset<br />

types <strong>and</strong> industries. The taxation of real economic income at lower<br />

rates, coupled with several additional re<strong>for</strong>ms, will reduce the<br />

opportunities <strong>and</strong> incentives <strong>for</strong> tax shelter activities <strong>and</strong>, thus,<br />

allow investment decisions to be motivated by economic realities<br />

rather than by tax considerations.<br />

2. Retirement Savings Incentives. The tax treatment of retirement<br />

savings, a major source of funds <strong>for</strong> capital <strong>for</strong>mation in the IJnited<br />

States, should be exp<strong>and</strong>ed <strong>and</strong> rationalized. The Treasury Department<br />

believes that the basic elements of the current tax structure which<br />

favor retirement savings should be retained <strong>and</strong> that the tax<br />

incentives encouraging such saving should be exp<strong>and</strong>ed. Accordingly,<br />

the Treasury Department proposes that the limits on contributions to<br />

individual retirement accounts (IRAs) be increased <strong>and</strong> that<br />

availability of IRAs be extended on an equal basis to spouses not<br />

employed in the marketplace. Under the Treasury Department proposals<br />

much of the financial saving of families will be accorded favorable<br />

tax treatment. According to one survey, only 39 percent of all


- 42 -<br />

American families have accumulated total financial assets of more than<br />

$5000. An even smaller percentage would save as much as $5000 in any<br />

one year As a result, individuals will experience much of the tax<br />

preference <strong>for</strong> saving associated with a consumed income tax, but the<br />

many problems involved in implementing such a personal tax on<br />

consumption (discussed in chapter 9) will be avoided. The Treasury<br />

Department also proposes that the tax treatment of retirement savings<br />

be rationalized by subjecting all pre-retirement distributions to<br />

uni<strong>for</strong>m rules, <strong>and</strong> by simplifying the contribution limits applied to<br />

various tax-preferred plans.<br />

3. Neutrality Toward Business Form. Corporations <strong>and</strong> partnerships<br />

should be taxed in more nearly the same way. The Treasury Department<br />

proposes that corporations be-given a partial deduction <strong>for</strong> dividends<br />

paid in order to reduce the double taxation of dividends, <strong>and</strong> that<br />

certain large partnerships be taxed as corporations.<br />

4. Industry-Specific Subsidies arid <strong>Tax</strong> Shelters. Highly<br />

preferential tax treatment that benefits only a few selected<br />

industries should be eliminated. This special treatment is<br />

undesirable both because it is inequitable <strong>and</strong> because it violates the<br />

principle of economic neutrality. A consistent definition of taxable<br />

income would allow market <strong>for</strong>ces, rather than the tax system, to<br />

determine the allocation of the Nation's scarce economic resources.<br />

c. Economic Effects<br />

Implementation of the tax re<strong>for</strong>ms proposed by the Treasury<br />

Department will cause a substantial reallocation of economic <br />

resources. The lower tax rates made possible by base-broadening <strong>and</strong> <br />

the more accurate rules <strong>for</strong> the measurement of income <strong>and</strong> calculation <br />

of tax liabilities will stimulate investment in industries that are <br />

burdened by the current unfair <strong>and</strong> distortionary tax regime. The <br />

proposed re<strong>for</strong>ms will thus benefit both some established industries as <br />

well as new "high-tech" industries. <br />

However, the primary beneficiaries of the Treasury Department's<br />

proposals will be the American public. No longer will the allocation<br />

of the Nation's scarce economic resources -- its labor, its capital,<br />

its l<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> its inventive genius -- be distorted by the biases of<br />

the current tax system. Instead, under the economically neutral tax<br />

system proposed by the Treasury Department, market <strong>for</strong>ces will direct<br />

resources to those activities where returns are greatest. The result<br />

will be more productive investment <strong>and</strong> thus greater output. A more<br />

effectively utilized capital stock will result in a more productive,<br />

<strong>and</strong> thus more highly paid, labor <strong>for</strong>ce. Output prices in currently<br />

tax-favored industries will increase, while output prices in currently<br />

tax-disadvantaged industries will fall. As a result, a more useful<br />

mix of goods will be produced, since consumer prices will adjust to<br />

reflect these changes in costs, <strong>and</strong> consumer dem<strong>and</strong> will no longer be<br />

artificially distorted.


- 43 -<br />

In addition, the biases under current law against emerging firms,<br />

especially those with relatively low dem<strong>and</strong>s <strong>for</strong> physical capital,<br />

will be eliminated. The current bias toward firms with relatively<br />

la?ge investments in depreciable assets, especially short-lived <br />

equipment, will be eliminated under a capital recovery system that <br />

approximates economic depreciation. Economic depreciation will reduce <br />

the current bias toward established firms that can fully utilize <br />

special deductions <strong>and</strong> credits by replacing the present "front-loaded" <br />

capital recovery system of ACRS <strong>and</strong> the ITC. MOKeOVeK, the current <br />

bias toward established firms with retained earnings will be reduced <br />

by decreasing the marginal tax rate on corporate income paid out as <br />

dividends. Since retained earnings would not have as large a tax <br />

advantage over new equity, firms in need of new equity financing will <br />

find it more readily available. Since many firms in the "high<br />

technology" industries are emerging <strong>and</strong> relatively low capital<br />

intensity, the proposed re<strong>for</strong>ms will foster invention <strong>and</strong> innovation <br />

by benefitting such firms. The re<strong>for</strong>m proposal thus would promote<br />

faster economic growth, in addition to improving the allocation of the <br />

Nation's resources at any single point in time. <br />

The Treasury Department prOpOSalS will affect different industries<br />

in different ways; in particular, not all industries would benefit<br />

from tax re<strong>for</strong>m. That is the nature of the tax re<strong>for</strong>m problem. The<br />

only way to reduce the burden of taxes on industries that pay aboveaverage<br />

taxes under current law is to shift part of that burden to<br />

industries where taxes are now artificially reduced by special provisions.<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>payers that would lose special tax preferences under the<br />

proposed re<strong>for</strong>ms include the oil <strong>and</strong> gas industry; banks, life<br />

insurance companies, <strong>and</strong> other financial institutions; <strong>and</strong> industries<br />

in which production extends over several years.<br />

Although it is possible to identify the industries that would lose<br />

special tax preferences, it is impossible to predict the precise<br />

economic effects of the entire package of Treasury Department<br />

proposals on all industries <strong>and</strong> individuals in the economy. Although<br />

many mathematical models of the economy exist, economic science simply<br />

is not sufficiently precise to allow accurate prediction of the<br />

effects of re<strong>for</strong>ms as fundamental <strong>and</strong> pervasive as those proposed by<br />

the Treasury Department; accordingly, this Report contains no such<br />

attempt at precise quantification of economic effects. <br />

D. Transition <br />

Enactment of the Treasury Department proposals would undoubtedly<br />

result in a sizable reallocation of resources. Costly dislocations<br />

<strong>and</strong> unanticipated losses caused by tax re<strong>for</strong>m can -- <strong>and</strong> should -- be<br />

mitigated through provisions <strong>for</strong> fair <strong>and</strong> orderly transition. This<br />

Report contains many recommendations (see Volume 2) <strong>for</strong> delayed or<br />

phased-in enactment dates. MOKeOVeK, "gr<strong>and</strong>fathering" provisions<br />

designed to maintain current tax treatment <strong>for</strong> commitments made under<br />

present law would mitigate the dislocations <strong>and</strong> windfall losses<br />

associated with implementing re<strong>for</strong>m. Nevertheless, transition to a<br />

more equitable <strong>and</strong> more neutral system must OCCUK. To resist


- 44 -<br />

permanently the need to tax all real economic income consistently <strong>and</strong> <br />

uni<strong>for</strong>mly would be to perpetuate the high tax rates, inequities, <strong>and</strong> <br />

tax-induced distortions of resource allocation that currently plaque<br />

the economy. It would also threaten the viability of our voluntary<br />

income tax system by allowing these defects to continue to undermine <br />

taxpayer morale. <br />

11. Effects on Revenues<br />

The Treasury Department proposals are designed to be revenue <br />

neutral. That is, they raise roughly the same amount of revenue as <br />

current law, when fully phased in, <strong>and</strong> during each of the transition <br />

years, FY 1986-90. Table 4-2 shows projected tax receipts under both <br />

current law <strong>and</strong> the Treasury Department proposals, plus receipts under <br />

the proposals as a percent of current law receipts, <strong>for</strong> fiscal years<br />

1986-90. <br />

During FY 1986, receipts under the proposals exceed those under <br />

current law by $0.5 billion. In FY 1987, they fall short of current <br />

receipts by $5.8 billion. During the FY 1988-90 period, receipts<br />

under the proposal exceed those under current law by an average of <br />

$6.0 billion, or 0.9 percent of current law receipts. These <br />

deviations from receipts under current law are small enough, compared<br />

to potential errors in estimates, that the proposals should be <br />

characterized as revenue neutral. <br />

It would not be helpful to show actual dollar receipts beyond the<br />

transition period, given the vagaries of <strong>for</strong>ecasting so far into the<br />

future. But, when fully phased in, the proposal raises about 1 to 3<br />

percent less revenue than current law. In other words, if receipts<br />

under current law would have otherwise been $1 trillion, they will be<br />

$10 to $30 billion less under the Treasury Department proposal when<br />

fully phased in. Thus, even when fully phased in, the proposals are<br />

revenue neutral.<br />

The estimates of receipts <strong>for</strong> 1986-90 are based on the economic<br />

<strong>for</strong>ecast in the 1984 Mid-session Review. The estimates reflect the<br />

assumption that the level of economic output is not affected by the<br />

tax re<strong>for</strong>ms being proposed. In fact, the dramatic reductions in<br />

marginal tax rates that are being proposed can be expected to generate<br />

additional work ef<strong>for</strong>t, saving, investment <strong>and</strong> innovation. As a<br />

result, economic output -- <strong>and</strong> with it tax receipts -- will probably<br />

be higher than projected. Predicting how much higher is, however,<br />

inevitably a difficult task. Any estimates of the effects of<br />

increased incentives would be far outside the range of recent<br />

experience.<br />

Table 4-2 also shows the breakdown of annual receipts between<br />

individual <strong>and</strong> corporate taxpayers. Over the period FY 1986-1990,<br />

individual receipts will be reduced by some 6 to 9 percent per year<br />

relative to current law, while corporate receipts will be 25 to 37<br />

percent higher. Fully phased in individual receipts will be 8.5<br />

percent lower; corporate receipts will be about 24 percent higher.


~ ~ ~ ~ ~<br />

Lo<br />

U<br />

a<br />

"rl ....<br />

....<br />

N<br />

91WrlD<br />

45 -<br />

.... 91<br />

~-.rom 0 m W<br />

P N V I P m mpmo<br />

c<br />

m m 0<br />

mN m<br />

m<br />

0) mw m 0 0 0)<br />

a VId W 91.4 I. rl rl<br />

a<br />

r <br />

....<br />

W NdPO m m W<br />

m r-VI91m ai<br />

0<br />

0 rl<br />

91 WVI m VI<br />

a<br />

4 0<br />

W 914 W rl<br />

0<br />

c<br />

,-<br />

W<br />

c<br />

0<br />

"rl ....<br />

".. N 4 0) W<br />

U<br />

rl Nrl91VI 91 m m c 0<br />

rl VIrl m 0 0<br />

a .rl al 0<br />

91rl W<br />

0<br />

W U<br />

m rl<br />

U<br />

7<br />

YI<br />

al<br />

- . PI<br />

....<br />

rwom N VI m 0<br />

t-NVIW N W VI<br />

r &<br />

00 m VI 91 I 0)<br />

a<br />

0 <br />

91.4 VI VI<br />

r<br />

VI E?<br />

0 VI<br />

TI<br />

al mt-mw N 00<br />

U m<br />

(L: 0<br />

~m m 0 VIrl 0<br />

E m<br />

0<br />

VI m.4 VI<br />

N 2<br />

cn<br />

rl<br />

I<br />

r<br />

91u<br />

al<br />

a l m 4 5 ,a a m m H 5 al al .d 5 W "4 W D c ... 0<br />

0 . .<br />

3 al * .<br />

"d W 2 > U a .rl<br />

... al u al m<br />

U C<br />

.rl<br />

3 5<br />

m c<br />

rl 2<br />

0<br />

U u<br />

c 10 al 0<br />

I<br />

U U U<br />

a U I ..+ 1 al m 3<br />

U<br />

U<br />

al<br />

rl W U 0 U rl<br />

c<br />

U a,<br />

m c U al U 0 U U U 7 U I ii rl m $ 0 2 a 0 W<br />

.... U ....<br />

II<br />

I1 .u. z a .U . W .<br />

II "rl . w ..d<br />

II al ..d<br />

. .<br />

. m.<br />

U<br />

$ . . <br />

I1 <br />

. m.<br />

I1<br />

... <br />

I1<br />

8 rl .5 . <br />

male. <br />

I1<br />

W<br />

0<br />

I1 aum.<br />

rl<br />

I1 <br />

rl<br />

m .4<br />

I1<br />

m U rl 'rlUalal m <br />

U<br />

I1<br />

U U 3 ou W U <br />

0<br />

/I<br />

al 5 .d a m ..+ 0<br />

H<br />

I1<br />

8 W al 5 u u u 4 U <br />

I1 W 10 C O W X al .d <br />

I1<br />

al<br />

I1 84<br />

rlw al<br />

II<br />

U no u<br />

I1<br />

al 0<br />

HVWW uw .. <br />

z P, 3 a


- 46 -<br />

111. Effects on Income Distribution <strong>and</strong> Incentives<br />

The Treasury Department has designed its proposals to be basically<br />

neutral from a distributional point of view, as well as revenue <br />

neutral, once fully phased in. That is, the distribution of <br />

individual income tax burdens across income classes does not differ <br />

significantly from that under current law, except in one important <br />

respect. An explicit goal of the study is the elimination of income <br />

tax liability from families with incomes below the poverty level. To <br />

achieve the increase in the tax threshold required to meet this <br />

objective, the personal exemptions <strong>and</strong> zero-bracket amounts will be <br />

increased, thus increasing slightly the relative burdens of all <br />

taxpayers above the new tax-exempt levels of income. <br />

One way to see the distributional neutrality of the proposed<br />

package of tax re<strong>for</strong>ms <strong>and</strong> simplification is to examine the percentage<br />

distribution of tax liabilities under present law <strong>and</strong> proposed law. A<br />

comparison of lines 5 <strong>and</strong> 6 of Table 4-3 reveals that the percentage<br />

distribution of tax liabilities would not be changed significantly,<br />

except at the bottom of the income scale, where burdens would clearly<br />

be reduced.<br />

Although the proposed tax re<strong>for</strong>ms reduce total revenues from the<br />

individual income tax by 8.5 percent, the increase in the tax<br />

threshold is reflected in substantially greater reductions in taxes<br />

paid in the bottom two income classes. Liabilities of families with<br />

incomes below $10,000 fall by 32.5 percent <strong>and</strong> those of families with<br />

incomes between $10,000 <strong>and</strong> $15,000 fall by 16.6 percent. Above<br />

average, but smaller reductions are also experienced in the next three<br />

income classes. In the three income classes above $50,000 the<br />

reduction in taxes is slightly less than average, at 6.4 to 8.0<br />

percent. (See line 9 of Table 4-3 <strong>and</strong> Figure 4-2.)<br />

The distributional neutrality of the proposed re<strong>for</strong>ms is also<br />

shown by the pattern of average tax rates paid at each income level,<br />

under present law <strong>and</strong> the proposed law. (See lines 10 <strong>and</strong> 11 of Table<br />

4-3 <strong>and</strong> Figure 4-1.) Under current law, the average rates increase<br />

steadily from about 1-1/2 percent <strong>for</strong> those with incomes below $10,000<br />

to roughly 21 percent <strong>for</strong> taxpayers with income in excess of $200,000.<br />

Under proposed law the range of average rates is from about 1 percent<br />

to just above 19 percent.<br />

The pattern of average tax rates, that is, the percentage of total<br />

income taken by taxes at various income levels, is relevant <strong>for</strong><br />

judging the distributional fairness of the tax system. The figures<br />

just presented show that the re<strong>for</strong>ms proposed do not significantly<br />

redistribute tax burdens across income classes except insofar as tax<br />

burdens at the very bottom of the income scale are reduced<br />

dramatically; that is, the proposals are basically distributionally<br />

neutral.<br />

Average tax rates do not indicate the extent to which taxation<br />

creates disincentives <strong>for</strong> productive economic activities. To appraise


~<br />

- 47 -<br />

.. .. .. ... ?9<br />

W<br />

00 00 00<br />

E<br />

mom<br />

011 00 00 00<br />

oa wrlm "<br />

00 00 00<br />

c u I<br />

rlrl rlrl rlrl<br />

H U<br />

c<br />

r2lL OLO OLD<br />

a .. ..<br />

m o<br />

..<br />

rlmo<br />

...<br />

rlNO<br />

Y91 ...<br />

0 s W(0 w r wm O-rW<br />

o c o m wmm<br />

rlrl<br />

N<br />

rlN I Nrl W*N<br />

I<br />

.. .. ..<br />

Nm<br />

..<br />

I<br />

0<br />

Nrl rlm mW<br />

00 mm a m NN "<br />

ON<br />

rl<br />

rlrl 44<br />

0 r-r W(0<br />

.. ..<br />

mrl 0:-<br />

.. . .<br />

1<br />

0<br />

04 rlrl rlN<br />

m Nm NVr<br />

mm mm mm I<br />

IO w N -4<br />

..<br />

mo<br />

mm m a<br />

NrlN<br />

W<br />

0 m .. Y?<br />

mrl<br />

.. Y?y?<br />

W U<br />

m NN NN " V-r rr o w 4 5::<br />

I c a<br />

-.I<br />

a 0 U<br />

o w<br />

1 0 nm .. .. m Wm mN<br />

...<br />

0 . 91:7<br />

0<br />

??<br />

oom<br />

-3- -rm 00<br />

N<br />

mwm WLO<br />

rlrl rlrl<br />

W V N<br />

rlrl I 1 rlrlrl h<br />

N ??<br />

w o<br />

.. ..<br />

w o<br />

1 0 mrl<br />

1 .<br />

m mm !nm "91<br />

rl<br />

o m w-r Nrlrl<br />

drlrl<br />

I<br />

.. ..<br />

NP<br />

I V<br />

C<br />

V<br />

.rl<br />

3<br />

IO mm O rl<br />

mw<br />

.. "'9<br />

U W<br />

0<br />

mm rlrl<br />

rl<br />

mmw mN mmm a m<br />

rlrl<br />

I<br />

1 1<br />

0<br />

?m<br />

LON mm<br />

.. .. ???<br />

m<br />

1<br />

rl<br />

0 rlrl rlrl<br />

v)<br />

V W N<br />

ri m<br />

1 1<br />

.. ...<br />

.. U w W .. ... ...<br />

I .<br />

0 a .. 0.. * W . I .<br />

C<br />

C 3 E . .<br />

.rl ._I<br />

0..<br />

0 .m v . . U<br />

.-I W m e.. QJ<br />

U U C .I . . a<br />

a E W u .rl C<br />

9 V a W 3<br />

.rl C C a W<br />

u H P C m<br />

U<br />

QJ<br />

3<br />

m C U<br />

W<br />

m<br />

.rl m m<br />

E 2r c a<br />

n 0 0 U V<br />

U V ..I X<br />

W W C rl W<br />

0. H .I m i?<br />

m a W 9 m<br />

U W QJ mx m U W<br />

C U mm .?I e m<br />

W 0 2 rlh 4 W m<br />

V a m V<br />

U X x U<br />

W F .. m 0 .<br />

m .. W ... 2 <br />

et < rlN h mw h LOW et Pmm &<br />

u . .<br />

x<br />

H<br />

H H H<br />

H<br />

H<br />

\\<br />

rlN


0 <br />

- 48 -<br />

1 <br />

F<br />

4<br />

E!<br />

3<br />

.- m<br />

U<br />

t- 0.....<br />

.....<br />

,....<br />

,....<br />

4<br />

.....<br />

,.... .:.<br />

rx<br />

w<br />

ca


- 49 ­<br />

::m$:m:wA<br />

.: . ..<br />

:":%:%:<br />

............................... .. .if....<br />

w <br />

I­<br />

I-<br />

C


- 50 -<br />

incentive effects it is necessary to know marqinal tax rates, that is,<br />

the percentage of an additional dollar of income that will be taken by <br />

taxes. <br />

Lines 12 to 14 of Table 4-3 <strong>and</strong> Figure 4-3 present data on<br />

marginal tax rates paid, on the average, at various income levels. In<br />

the aggregate the proposed re<strong>for</strong>ms reduce marginal tax rates by 19.9<br />

percent, from 23.6 percent to 18.9 percent. The fact that marginal<br />

tax rates can be cut this much while average tax rates fall by only<br />

8.5 percent shows clearly the advantage of defining taxable income<br />

comprehensively. By levying lower marginal tax rates on a broader tax<br />

base, it is possible to avoid the disincentive effects of higher<br />

rates.<br />

Marginal tax rates paid by families in the three income classes<br />

between $30,000 <strong>and</strong> $200,000 fall, on average, by about 20 percent.<br />

The marginal tax rates paid, on the average, by families with income<br />

below $30,000 fall by 10 to 13 percent. Even though marginal income<br />

tax rates do not fall as much at this income level as at others, they<br />

are low, on average, ranging from only 4 to 14 percent under the<br />

proposed law.<br />

In the very highest income bracket, that above $200,000, the<br />

marginal tax rate falls by 23 percent, from 46 percent to 33 percent.<br />

It bears repeating that this relatively greater cut in marqinal rates<br />

in the top income classes does not imply that high-income taxpayers<br />

will experience a relatively greater tax cut than taxpayers with lower<br />

incomes. As line 9 of Table 4-3 indicates, all income groups above<br />

the $50,000 income level experience smaller than average tax<br />

reductions. Rather, marginal rates fall furthest at the top of the<br />

income distribution because that is where the tax base is increased by<br />

the largest fraction. The proposed tax re<strong>for</strong>ms increase adjusted<br />

gross income (AGT) <strong>for</strong> all families by only 2.8 percent. (See line 7<br />

of Table 4-3.) But <strong>for</strong> families with income in excess of $200,000,<br />

AGI increases by 10.1 percent, as a result of eliminating many<br />

provisions that allow income to be sheltered from tax.<br />

The total of taxable income <strong>for</strong> all families is virtually<br />

unchanged under the Treasury Department proposals. (See line 8 of<br />

Table 4-3.) But <strong>for</strong> those with incomes below $15,000, taxable income<br />

falls dramatically -- by 14 to 16 percent, due primarily to the<br />

increase in the personal exemptions. Smaller reductions in taxable<br />

income extend through the $30,000 to $50,000 income class. Above that<br />

point, taxable income increases, with taxable income of those with<br />

incomes of more than $200,000 rising by 24.9 percent. (See Figure<br />

4-4 1 )<br />

The dramatic reduction in marginal tax rates that base-broadening<br />

makes possible at the top of the income scale emphasizes the <br />

importance of taxing all income in a consistent manner. Simply by<br />

defining the tax base comprehensively, it is possible to achieve a <br />

percentage reduction of marginal tax rates paid by high-income<br />

individuals that is larger than that provided in the Economic Recovery


- 5:1 -<br />

I <br />

...).(<br />

n.....<br />

.....<br />

....,<br />

x<br />

m <br />

I-


- 52 -<br />

a 0 0 0 0 0<br />

3 N r 7 N <br />

I<br />

I


- 53 -<br />

<strong>Tax</strong> Act of 1981, <strong>and</strong> to do so while cutting taxes <strong>for</strong> them by less<br />

than they are cut <strong>for</strong> lower income classes. A reduction of marginal<br />

tax rates of this magnitude will open wide the doors of opportunity to<br />

those who are willing to work, to save <strong>and</strong> invest, <strong>and</strong> to innovate.<br />

The advantage of base-broadening can also be seen from Table 4-4<br />

<strong>and</strong> from Figure 4-5. Of the 91.4 million families in the country,<br />

fewer than 20 million, or about 22 percent, will experience any tax<br />

increase as a result of the Treasury Department proposals. By<br />

comparison, 56 percent will have their taxes reduced. At the lower<br />

income levels the fraction of families with tax increases is even<br />

smaller, ranging from less than 5 percent in the zero to $10,000<br />

income class to about 20 percent in the $15-20,000 income class.<br />

In every income class far more families will benefit from the<br />

Treasury Department's proposals than will lose. Moreover, there are<br />

far more families whose average tax rate will fall by a given.amount<br />

(<strong>for</strong> example, less than one percentage point or more than two<br />

percentage points) than there are families whose average rates will<br />

rise by that amount. (See Table 4-4.)


- 54 -<br />

a,<br />

5 <br />

u e m <br />

urn<br />

m<br />

33<br />

3u <br />

rc<br />

UIU omw ~ m - m 3 0 3 ~m o<br />

Q W N N or*" **om<br />

3 .... .... P; 9<br />

a, 0 0 mwmo mmmp 3 o<br />

E N n m * w 0<br />

0 3<br />

U,<br />

C 3<br />

H I wmm u> 3 0 m*Y) nmmm m o<br />

wm 00 N-N ......<br />

0.3 ON<br />

3<br />

X F<br />

m u m<br />

Et I3<br />

IO<br />

0 <br />

03 <br />

m<br />

IO In<br />

O<br />

C<br />

'33<br />

e m 1 0<br />

I om m<br />

r* mo 0<br />

ca N<br />

m mo<br />

3<br />

n F u<br />

U<br />

m<br />

4 hE IO<br />

n u<br />

0 * N<br />

UlW 3<br />

aa,<br />

IY)<br />

3<br />

0 <br />

3<br />

I O<br />

3<br />

0 <br />

y1<br />

PLnm3 N 0<br />

N 3 3 W 0<br />

3<br />

.... ...... <br />

0 ~ m 3m *3*n mmmm m o<br />

W W P O mmwm * o<br />

3 m 3 3 N W 0<br />

3<br />

.... ..... <br />

wmm- W N P 0 0<br />

PNNN ~ m m oc o<br />

*wr.m Goma P 0<br />

AN 3 N N W 0<br />

n<br />

....<br />

mCWm<br />

q ~ n m<br />

wwmm<br />

3<br />

......<br />

*rl-m N wwmo m o<br />

In,.?*** n 0<br />

3 N N W 3 0<br />

3<br />

.... ...... <br />

wwmrl WNNO m o<br />

m3ow wmmu) m o<br />

"W*<br />

3<br />

mNWm 3 0<br />

33" m 0<br />

rl<br />

......<br />

~ o m mN mwmm m o<br />

mwoCm 3 o<br />

N P O<br />

3<br />

.... 3 ........<br />

n a, a, a, a, E E E 0 0 0 5 :::: : :<br />

U U u C 2 ... C .... c ......<br />

3 "3 "3 ,.?I . ...a, "I W W W VI 0 ... 0 0 o ...m . .<br />

m F . .'\<br />

a, m<br />

u u a, 4.l u u ..mu . Q<br />

E E * .3 C c .. u , . A<br />

a, a, 3 3 a, m u.uaJ . 3<br />

0 U V C .cTJ 1 -3<br />

U Lo u m .Q<br />

.; a, a, u.ux<br />

i+L i : 3<br />

w ..* i a u.um . w<br />

x 3 muou x<br />

m 3 a ~ am 3<br />

m '; m m u 3 m m a,surl<br />

N U3U m<br />

C n. u ,.3 E<br />

,.-I C Q C 3 , ' d<br />

i w!i 3 UI iw<br />

3<br />

a,<br />

-<br />

m 0<br />

2 0 u ffi<br />

u 8 C 0 u U u c o<br />

w oom m 4 C w womo m 4<br />

E a uum<br />

a,<br />

0 + E n uumo~1<br />

0 0 o m +<br />

x x z3.3 U x x 23.3<br />

m m 0 a, m m 0<br />

4<br />

4 z PI 4 E.@ z<br />

'7


- 55 -<br />

E <br />

a,<br />

fn<br />

m <br />

e<br />

0<br />

.- E<br />

X<br />

m<br />

c <br />

fn<br />

a,<br />

- .-<br />

E<br />

2 <br />

I I I I<br />

s 0 0 0 0 0<br />

0 a3 (0 d N<br />

0<br />

T-


- 57 -<br />

Appendix 4-A<br />

Explanation of Concept of Economic Income Used<br />

in Distributional Tables<br />

The tables in this Report showing the distribution of current <strong>and</strong><br />

proposed tax liabilities by family income class represent an important<br />

improvement over the kinds of comparisons the Treasury Department has<br />

been able to display in the past. They differ from the usual tables<br />

in two ways: (1) taxes <strong>and</strong> the effects of changes in tax policy are<br />

distributed over all families in the population, rather than over taxfiling<br />

units; <strong>and</strong> (2) the definition of income is a broad measure of<br />

economic income, rather than adjusted gross income.<br />

Families<br />

For many people, the tax unit <strong>and</strong> the family are the same. A<br />

family can, however, consist of several tax filing units if dependents<br />

have incomes of their own. For instance, if the children in a family<br />

have jobs or have investment funds in their names, they may have to<br />

file returns to pay taxes OK to receive a refund of taxes that were<br />

withheld. For judging the fairness of the distributional burden of<br />

the tax system, the incomes <strong>and</strong> the taxes of those dependents should<br />

be included with the incomes <strong>and</strong> taxes of the taxpayers (usually<br />

parents) who support them.<br />

Another difference between the tax return unit <strong>and</strong> the family is<br />

that many families <strong>and</strong> individuals have too little income <strong>for</strong> them to<br />

be required to file a tax return under current law. These "nonfilers"<br />

should be recognized in surveying the tax system's impact on people at<br />

different income levels. Tables based on tax returns cannot show how<br />

many people at a given income class are not even in the tax system,<br />

whereas the tables in this Report do reflect the families <strong>and</strong><br />

indivfduals who do not file tax returns.<br />

Income Definition<br />

The definition of income used in this Report <strong>for</strong> classifying<br />

families <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> comparing tax burdens differs from adjusted gross<br />

income <strong>and</strong> other tax system concepts of income in a number of ways.<br />

(The income classifier does not serve as the basis <strong>for</strong> actual<br />

taxation.) Economic income is a comprehensive measure of income that<br />

is intended to approximate as closely as possible the st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

definition of income, consumption plus change in net worth. It<br />

includes <strong>for</strong>ms of income that are not subject to tax, such as interest<br />

from tax-exempt state <strong>and</strong> local bonds <strong>and</strong> government transfer<br />

payments. It also measures more accurately certain other <strong>for</strong>ms of<br />

income that are subject to tax, such as real interest income. This<br />

broader measure of income, there<strong>for</strong>e, provides a better yardstick <strong>for</strong><br />

comparing families -- that is, <strong>for</strong> determining their abilities to pay<br />

taxes <strong>and</strong> comparing tax burdens by income class.


- 58 -<br />

"Economic income" starts from adjusted gross income as reported on<br />

tax returns <strong>and</strong> adds in unreported or underreported income. It adds<br />

back certain "adjustments to income," principally IRA <strong>and</strong> Keogh<br />

contributions <strong>and</strong> the second earner deduction. Since economic income<br />

aims to measure income in the current year, it adds back net operating<br />

losses carried over from previous years. It includes cash <strong>and</strong> nearcash<br />

transfers that are not subject to tax, principally social<br />

security benefits, welfare payments, unemployment <strong>and</strong> workers'<br />

compensation, veterans' compensation, <strong>and</strong> food stamps. It adds in the<br />

untaxed portion of compensation such as employer contributions <strong>for</strong><br />

pensions <strong>and</strong> health <strong>and</strong> life insurance <strong>and</strong> other fringe benefits. So<br />

that pension income not be double counted, it excludes pension income<br />

as received but includes the accrual of earnings on pension <strong>and</strong> life<br />

insurance plans, <strong>and</strong> on IRA <strong>and</strong> Keogh accounts. It includes taxexempt<br />

interest. Since home owners receive implicit income from their<br />

houses, economic income includes an estimate of the real imputed net<br />

rent on owner-occupied housing.<br />

"Economic income" reflects the view that corporations are not<br />

separate from their stockholders, but that: the income of corporations<br />

is income of its stockholders; there<strong>for</strong>e, economic income allocates<br />

pre-tax corporate profits both to individuals who own stock directly<br />

<strong>and</strong> to those who own stock indirectly, <strong>for</strong> example, through shares of<br />

pension or Life insurance funds. Economic income attempts to measure<br />

capital income correctly: by indexing interest receipts <strong>and</strong> expenses,<br />

by indexing capital gains <strong>and</strong> losses, by replacing tax depreciation<br />

with real economic depreciation, <strong>and</strong> by including the tax-preference<br />

component of intangible drilling costs <strong>and</strong> percentage depletion<br />

allowances.<br />

The derivation of economic income from adjusted gross income is<br />

described in greater detail in Table 4A-1. Figure 4A-1 compares the<br />

distribution of tax returns classified by AGI with the distribution of<br />

families classified by economic income. The most striking difference<br />

is that twice as large a percentage of tax returns fall in the<br />

smallest class -- below $lG,OOO -- than do families. Conversely, a<br />

much higher percentage of the families appear in the higher income<br />

classes of economic income. The chart shows clearly how poorly the<br />

distribution of tax returns by AGI approximates the distribution of<br />

families by economic income, which is a more appropriate way of<br />

viewing the population <strong>for</strong> most analytical purposes.


-' 59 -<br />

Table 4A-1<br />

Economic Income Equals<br />

Adjusted gross income:<br />

reported on tax returns<br />

unreported or underreported<br />

plus net operating losses carried over from previous years<br />

plus adjustments to income:<br />

IRA <strong>and</strong> Keogh contributions<br />

two-earner deduction<br />

other adjustments<br />

plus untaxed employer contributions <strong>for</strong>:<br />

pensions<br />

health <strong>and</strong> life insurance<br />

profit sharing<br />

other benefits<br />

plus certain fringe benefits<br />

plus certain military benefits<br />

plus untaxed cash benefits <strong>for</strong>:<br />

unemployment compensation<br />

workers' compensation<br />

AFDC <br />

SSI <br />

veterans' compensation<br />

social security<br />

railroad retirement <br />

plus food stamps benefits <br />

plus non-corporate earnings on pension <strong>and</strong> 1 fe insurance pl ns<br />

less taxable pension income <br />

plus earnings on IRA <strong>and</strong> Keogh plans<br />

plus tax-exempt interest <br />

plus real net imputed rent on owner-occupied homes <br />

less realized conorate income <br />

plus accrued pre-tax real corporate income <br />

plus adjustment <strong>for</strong> indexing of non-corporate capital gains <strong>and</strong> losses <br />

plus adjustment <strong>for</strong> indexing of interest income <strong>and</strong> expense<br />

plus replacement of tax depreciation with economic depreciation<br />

plus tax preference <strong>for</strong> intangible drilling costs, <strong>and</strong> percentage<br />

depletion


- 60 -<br />

.- 0<br />

- E<br />

u o <br />

0<br />

s w<br />

-2. ....


- 61 -<br />

a<br />

C<br />

m u) ffl<br />

C a,<br />

m m a<br />

I fflrl ffl<br />

9<br />

n a<br />

m<br />

w<br />

2<br />

m<br />

h <br />

.II<br />

rl<br />

m<br />

s<br />

.rl<br />

3<br />

..i<br />

a<br />

C<br />

m m H<br />

i C<br />

9 0 U<br />

..i 0<br />

X U W<br />

..i a<br />

a n C<br />

C .rl 0<br />

w U ..i<br />

a U U<br />

m m<br />

2 .rl V<br />

LII .-I<br />

a, 5 ..<br />

rl<br />

5: a E<br />

C .rl<br />

.rl In<br />

a 5<br />

w<br />

2s<br />

a 0<br />

4 E .rl<br />

V UU<br />

C 00<br />

H<br />

w a ..<br />

d U<br />

a: m u <br />

X<br />

Uffl<br />

ma, u a<br />

RU<br />

m<br />

a a<br />

w c<br />

w a Z H<br />

E<br />

0<br />

V <br />

C<br />

H


- 63 -<br />

Chapter 5 <br />

INCOME TAX REFORM AND SIMPLIFICATION FOR INDIVIDUALS & FAMILIES<br />

I. Summary <br />

The Treasury Department proposals will lower tax rates <strong>and</strong> reduce<br />

the current number of rate brackets from 15 to three: 15, 25, <strong>and</strong> 35<br />

percent. The amount of income that can be earned tax-free will also<br />

be increased by raising to $2,000 the personal exemptions <strong>for</strong> the<br />

taxpayer, spouse, <strong>and</strong> dependents <strong>and</strong> by increasing the zero bracket<br />

amounts. Very few families below the poverty level will be subject to<br />

income tax.<br />

The tax base will be broadened to make this rate reduction<br />

possible, simplify the system, <strong>and</strong> make it fairer by eliminating<br />

special preferences <strong>and</strong> abuses. The definition of individual taxable<br />

income will be exp<strong>and</strong>ed to include certain fringe benefits <strong>and</strong> other<br />

items. Deductions <strong>for</strong> tax shelter investments <strong>and</strong> business expenses<br />

that involve personal consumption will be curtailed. The itemized<br />

deduction <strong>for</strong> State <strong>and</strong> local taxes will be phased out, <strong>and</strong> charitable<br />

contributions will be deductible only to the extent that they exceed 2<br />

percent of adjusted gross income. Left intact will be the current<br />

itemized deductions <strong>for</strong> interest on the principal residence of the<br />

taxpayer, medical expenses, <strong>and</strong> casualty losses.<br />

Elimination of several tax credits <strong>and</strong> other items will <br />

substantially simplify the tax <strong>for</strong>ms. The Internal Revenue Service <br />

will consider the possibility of initiating a new system under which <br />

it calculates tax liability <strong>for</strong> many taxpayers. <br />

The deductions <strong>for</strong> contributions to Individual Retirement Accounts<br />

will be increased to $2,500 per employee <strong>and</strong> from $250 to $2,500 <strong>for</strong><br />

spouses working in the home. Other proposed changes that involve the<br />

taxation of business <strong>and</strong> capital income, including the corporation<br />

income tax, are of less concern to most individuals <strong>and</strong> are discussed<br />

in chapters 6 <strong>and</strong> 7. (The appendix to the present chapter contains a<br />

detailed listing of all proposals primarily affecting individuals <strong>and</strong><br />

families.)<br />

11. Rate Reduction <br />

The re<strong>for</strong>ms proposed by the Treasury Department will exp<strong>and</strong> the<br />

income tax base enough to allow substantial rate reductions <strong>for</strong><br />

individuals. On incomes above the tax threshold ($11,800 <strong>for</strong> a family<br />

of four) three rates -- 15, 25, <strong>and</strong> 35 percent -- will apply. Under<br />

current law, marginal rates range from I1 percent to 50 percent. Thus<br />

the top marginal rate will be cut by 30 percent under the Treasury<br />

Department proposals. The proposed rate schedules <strong>for</strong> single returns,<br />

head of household returns, <strong>and</strong> joint returns are compared with those


- 64 -<br />

under current law in Table 5-1. On average, marginal tax rates will <br />

be 20 percent lower under these proposals than under current law. The <br />

effects on marginal rates paid at various points in the income <br />

distribution were discussed further in Chapter 4. <br />

Individual income taxes in 34 States rely on the Federal income<br />

tax base. <strong>Tax</strong>payers will experience further rate reductions if States<br />

cut rates to hold their revenues constant in the face of an increased<br />

tax base.<br />

As noted in previous chapters, rate reduction will encourage<br />

saving, investment, work ef<strong>for</strong>t, innovation, <strong>and</strong> other productive<br />

behavior. It will reduce the attraction of both tax avoidance through<br />

legitimate tax shelters <strong>and</strong> illegal underreporting of income. Even <br />

without elimination of tax preferences, credits, <strong>and</strong> deductions, rate <br />

reduction will lessen the disparities in the tax treatment of various <br />

sources <strong>and</strong> uses of income. When combined with some of the other <br />

proposals described below, rate reduction should also help to reduce <br />

interest rates <strong>and</strong> lead to a more robust <strong>and</strong> efficient economy. <br />

While lower marginal rates tend to increase work incentives <strong>for</strong> <br />

everyone, beneficial incentive effects will be especially pronounced<br />

<strong>for</strong> secondary workers, persons who often have considerable discretion <br />

over their labor market activity. Lower marginal rates will also <br />

reduce the extent to which the tax system influences choices of <br />

occupation <strong>and</strong> the amount of personal investment in education. <br />

Rate reduction will provide significant benefits to those who <br />

receive little or no income in preferred <strong>for</strong>ms. Thus, rate reduction <br />

will be particularly helpful to persons who now receive the bulk of <br />

their labor income in the <strong>for</strong>m of cash wages. This group includes <br />

secondary workers, workers in retail <strong>and</strong> certain service industries,<br />

<strong>and</strong> other workers who generally do not benefit from large fringe<br />

benefit packages. By the same token, those employers who now pay<br />

their employees in cash, rather than fringe benefits, will find that <br />

the after-tax wages of their employees will rise slightly relative to <br />

those of other employers, without any added cost to the employer.<br />

These employers will find that any competitive disadvantage they<br />

experience in attracting workers because of the current tax Law will <br />

be diminished. <br />

On the other h<strong>and</strong>, rate reduction will have a less favorable <br />

impact on the sectors of the economy that benefit most from preferen­<br />

tial treatment under current law. Rate reduction will reduce the <br />

attraction of tax-exempt bonds relative to taxable investments. <br />

Since charitable contributions are encouraged by high marginal tax <br />

rates that reduce the after-tax cost of giving, reducing marginal <br />

rates may reduce contributions. Deductions or exclusions <strong>for</strong> the cost <br />

of health insurance (whether provided by employers or by individuals)<br />

will becomes less valuable, thus leading to a reduction in the dem<strong>and</strong> <br />

<strong>for</strong> such insurance <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> health services.


- 65 -<br />

Table 5-1 <br />

Proposed <strong>Tax</strong> Rate Schedule<br />

Single Returns<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>able : Marqinal .<br />

income : tax rate<br />

( percent )<br />

Less than $2,800 0 <br />

$2,800 to 19,300 15 <br />

$19,300 to 38,100 25 <br />

$38,100 or more 35 <br />

:Head of Household Returns:<br />

Joint Returns<br />

- -<br />

: <strong>Tax</strong>able : Marqinal : <strong>Tax</strong>able : Marqinal<br />

: income : tax rate income : tax rate<br />

( percent ) ( percent )<br />

Less than $3,500 0 Less than $3,800 0<br />

$3,500 to 25,000 15 $3,800 to 31,800 15<br />

$25,000 to 48,000 25 $31,800 to 63,800 25<br />

$48,000 or more 35 $63,800 or more 35<br />

1986 Current Law <strong>Tax</strong> Rate Schedules<br />

Single Returns :Head of Household Returns: Joint Returns<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>able : Marginal : <strong>Tax</strong>able : Marginal : <strong>Tax</strong>able : Marginal<br />

income 1/: tax rate : income 1/: tax rate : income 1/: tax rate<br />

( percent ) ( percent ) ( percent )-<br />

Less than $2,5 10 0 <br />

2,510- 3,710 11 <br />

3,710- 4,800 12 <br />

4,800- 7,090 14 <br />

7,090- 9,280 15 <br />

9,280-1 1,790 16 <br />

11,790-14,080 18 <br />

14,080-1 6,370 20 <br />

16,370-1 9,860 23 <br />

19,860-25,650 26 <br />

25,650-31,430 30 <br />

31,430-37,210 34 <br />

37,210-45,290 38 <br />

45,290-60,350 42 <br />

60,350-89,270 48 <br />

89,270 or more 50 <br />

Less than $2,510 0 Less than $3,710 0<br />

2,510- 4,800 11 3,710- 6,000 11 <br />

4,800- 7,090 12 6,000- 8,290 12<br />

7,090- 9,490 14 8,290- 12,990 14<br />

9,490- 12,880 17 12,990- 17,460 16<br />

12,880- 16,370 18 17,460- 22,040 18<br />

16,370- 19,860 20 22,040- 26,850 22<br />

19,860- 25,650 24 26,850- 32,630 25<br />

25,650- 31,430 28 32,630- 38,410 28<br />

31,430- 37,210 32 38,410- 49,980 33<br />

37,210- 48,780 35 49,980- 65,480 38<br />

48,780- 66,130 42 65,480- 93,420 42<br />

66,130- 89,270 45 93,420-119,390 45<br />

89,270-118,190<br />

48 119,390-117,230 49<br />

118,190 or more 50 177,230 or more 50<br />

Office of the Secretary<br />

Office of <strong>Tax</strong> Policy<br />

of the Treasury<br />

-1/ Estimated.


- 66 -<br />

The impact on currently favored sectors can, of course, easily be<br />

exaggerated. All tax rate reductions can be opposed on the grounds<br />

that high tax rates increase the value of exemptions <strong>and</strong> deductions<br />

<strong>for</strong> favored activities. But imposing high tax rates on most income,<br />

in order to accord favorable treatment to some sources <strong>and</strong> uses of<br />

income, is hardly an efficient way to provide subsidies, even if that<br />

is desired. A more efficient <strong>and</strong> productive economy in the end helps<br />

participants in all sectors. For example, though rate reductions<br />

would initially raise the after-tax cost of health insurance, the<br />

overall cost of health care should eventually be less than in the<br />

absence of tax re<strong>for</strong>m. Costs will respond to the reduced dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

such care <strong>and</strong> to the greater attention that would be focused on the<br />

cost of both health care <strong>and</strong> insurance.<br />

111. <strong>Fairness</strong> <strong>for</strong> Families <br />

Families with incomes at or below the poverty level should not be<br />

subject to income tax. Thus, the tax threshold -- the level of income<br />

at which tax is first paid -- will be raised so that <strong>for</strong> most<br />

taxpayers it approximates the poverty level, as determined by the<br />

Bureau of the Census. The proposed tax threshold will be increased<br />

relatively more <strong>for</strong> returns filed by heads of household (those single<br />

persons who maintain households <strong>for</strong> dependents), in recognition of the<br />

particular economic difficulties of such households.<br />

After considering various means of setting the tax threshold, the <br />

Treasury Department proposes to retain the basic structural features <br />

of the present income tax: the personal exemption <strong>and</strong> the zero-<br />

bracket amount. The personal exemption <strong>for</strong> taxpayers, spouses, <strong>and</strong> <br />

dependents <strong>for</strong> 1986 will be increased to $2,000, compared with a <br />

projected $1,090 under current law (after indexing <strong>for</strong> inflation <br />

expected to occur during 1985). The zero-bracket amounts <strong>for</strong> single <br />

persons, heads of household, <strong>and</strong> married couples filing jointly will <br />

be increased, as shown in Table 5-2. The personal exemptions, zero-<br />

bracket amounts, <strong>and</strong> tax brackets will continue to be indexed to <br />

prevent their value from being eroded by inflation. These proposed<br />

changes are designed to reflect differences in ability to pay taxes <br />

that result from differences in family size <strong>and</strong> composition. The <br />

increase in the personal exemption recognizes the greater financial <br />

responsibilities <strong>and</strong> lesser ability to pay of those taking care of <br />

dependents. <br />

The proposed changes in the personal exemptions <strong>and</strong> zero-bracket<br />

amount would raise the 1986 tax threshold <strong>for</strong> a married couple filing<br />

jointly with no dependents from $5,890 to $7,800. A couple with two<br />

children would pay no income tax unless its income exceeded $11,800.<br />

Under current law, the same family will pay tax on income above<br />

$9,613, assuming full use of the earned income credit. (See Table 5-2<br />

<strong>and</strong> Figure 5-1.)


- 67 -<br />

Table 5-2 <br />

Comparison of Personal Exemptions, <strong>and</strong> ZBA <br />

Under Current Law <strong>and</strong> Treasury Department Proposals <br />

1986 Levels<br />

: Current Law -1/: Treasury<br />

: Proposal<br />

Personal Exemption $1,090 $2,000 <br />

Zero-Bracket Amount <br />

Single persons 2,510 2,800<br />

Heads of househ o1ds 2,510 3,500<br />

Married couples 3,710 3,800<br />

-1/ Includes indexation <strong>for</strong> expected inflation in 1985.


- 68 -<br />

<br />

3<br />

=?.<br />

3<br />

N <br />

Y3<br />

3 <br />

3<br />

?<br />

n <br />

5<br />

3 <br />

3<br />

3<br />

r <br />

53<br />

3<br />

3 <br />

3"<br />

u3<br />

b3<br />

80<br />

0<br />

D<br />

b3


- 69 -<br />

This increase in the tax threshold will exempt all families in<br />

poverty from Federal income tax. Table 5-3 shows the relationship<br />

between the poverty level of income <strong>and</strong> the tax threshold <strong>for</strong><br />

households of different sizes <strong>and</strong> compositions under both current law<br />

<strong>and</strong> the Treasury Department proposals. For single persons without<br />

dependents, where the tax threshold will still be $1,000 less than the<br />

poverty level. If the tax-free income level <strong>for</strong> single taxpayers were<br />

raised further, in order to benefit those single persons whose tax<br />

threshold is below the poverty level, it would be too high relative to<br />

the levels <strong>for</strong> heads of household <strong>and</strong> married couples. An increase in<br />

tax -- or marriage penalty -- would be imposed on single persons who<br />

decide to marry.<br />

For single taxpayers without dependents who live with relatives or<br />

unrelated persons, the comparison of the tax-free income level with<br />

the poverty income level may be misleading. When the tax-free income<br />

level <strong>for</strong> these individuals is combined with the tax-free income<br />

levels <strong>for</strong> other members of the household, the total generally exceeds<br />

a poverty income level. For example, the tax-free income levels <strong>for</strong><br />

taxpayers who are under age 21, who account <strong>for</strong> over one-quarter of<br />

all single persons with income subject to tax, often should be<br />

combined with the tax-free income levels of parents <strong>and</strong> other<br />

household members. Similarly, the combined poverty level <strong>for</strong> two<br />

single persons who share living quarters might, if appropriately<br />

measured, be close to that of a married couple. Their combined taxexempt<br />

income level might exceed that poverty level.<br />

The existing tax treatment of the blind, disabled, <strong>and</strong> elderly has<br />

evolved with little rationale. The Treasury Department proposes that<br />

all special treatment provided these groups under current law,<br />

including the additional personal exemptions, be replaced with a<br />

single tax credit <strong>for</strong> the elderly, blind, <strong>and</strong> disabled. Under the<br />

proposal, persons receiving workers' compensation, black lung<br />

payments, <strong>and</strong> certain veterans' disability pay would be treated<br />

similarly to persons who are permanently <strong>and</strong> totally disabled <strong>and</strong><br />

receive disability pay from employers. Once the tax benefits of this<br />

exp<strong>and</strong>ed credit are taken into account, the tax-exempt level of income<br />

<strong>for</strong> a single person who is disabled <strong>for</strong> an entire year, <strong>and</strong> whose<br />

income is composed mainly of such disability payments, would be<br />

$9,700. For a family of four, the level would be $17,200. These taxexempt<br />

levels substantially exceed of those applying to other<br />

taxpayers ($4,800 <strong>for</strong> single persons; $11,800 <strong>for</strong> families of four).<br />

In about 80 percent of States, a family of four solely dependent upon<br />

workers' compensation would pay no Federal income tax even if it<br />

received the maximum payment under that State's program.<br />

llnder the Treasury Department proposal, as under current law, tax-<br />

exempt levels <strong>for</strong> the elderly will be substantially higher than those <br />

<strong>for</strong> the non-elderly. When both the increased personal exemption <strong>and</strong> <br />

459-370 0 - 84 - 4


- 70 -<br />

Table 5-3 <br />

Comparison of the Poverty Threshold <strong>and</strong> the <strong>Tax</strong>-Free Income <br />

Level Under Current Law <strong>and</strong> the Treasury Proposal<br />

I./<br />

(1986 Levels) <br />

:<strong>Tax</strong>-free Income Levels<br />

: Poverty : Current : Treasury<br />

Status : Threshold : Law 2/: Proposal 2/<br />

single persons without dependents $5,800 $3,600 $4,800<br />

Heads of households with<br />

one dependent 7,900 7,979 9,303<br />

Married couples 3/ 7,400 5,890 7,800<br />

Married couples with<br />

two dependents 3/ 11,600 9,613 11,800<br />

-1/ Includes expected indexation <strong>for</strong> inflation in 1985.<br />

-2/ Assumes full use of the earned income tax credit where applicable.<br />

3/ Assumes one earner.<br />

-


- 71 -<br />

the new exp<strong>and</strong>ed credit <strong>for</strong> the elderly, blind <strong>and</strong> disabled are taken<br />

into account, the tax-exempt level <strong>for</strong> elderly couples receiving no<br />

social security income, at $14,533, will be essentially unchanged from<br />

current law. It will be $16,800 <strong>for</strong> a couple receiving the average<br />

amount of social security income, virtually the same as under current<br />

law. BY comparison, a non-elderly couple will have a tax-exempt<br />

amount of only $7,800. (See also Figure 5-2.)<br />

The benefits of the existing two-earner deduction are not <br />

well-focused <strong>for</strong> families where marriage increases tax burdens. While <br />

marriage penalties are reduced in some cases, marriage bonuses are <br />

created in others. With the proposed increase in personal exemptions<br />

<strong>and</strong> flatter rate structure, the two-earner deduction will be <br />

unnecessary. For most taxpayers the work incentive of second earners <br />

will be greater under the proposed lower <strong>and</strong> flatter rate structure <br />

than under existing law, with its two-earner deduction. The Treasury<br />

Department there<strong>for</strong>e proposes that the two-earner deduction be <br />

eliminated in favor of tax rate reduction. <br />

The earned income tax credit (EITC) adds considerable complexity <br />

to the system, especially <strong>for</strong> those least able to underst<strong>and</strong> it. If <br />

simplicity were the primary goal of tax re<strong>for</strong>m, the EITC would be <br />

eliminated, <strong>and</strong> with it a large number of tax returns filed only to <br />

claim the refundable credit. Given the equity objectives of re<strong>for</strong>m,<br />

however, the EITC is retained, <strong>and</strong> it is indexed to prevent its <br />

erosion by inflation. <br />

The complicated child <strong>and</strong> dependent care credit should be replaced<br />

by a simpler deduction. A deduction is more appropriate than a <br />

credit, because child <strong>and</strong> dependent care is an expense related to <br />

earning income. Accordingly, the true net income of those who incur <br />

child care expenses in order to be employed will be better measured if <br />

they are allowed to deduct such costs, up to a limit. Failure to <br />

allow a deduction, besides being unfair, would adversely affect work <br />

incentives. Of course, a deduction is relatively less favorable to <br />

low-income taxpayers than is a credit. The choice of a deduction in <br />

this case reflects the view that progressivity should be provided<br />

directly, through changes in the rate structure, rather than through<br />

individual provisions that lack logic <strong>and</strong> add to complexity. <br />

Recognition of the cost of raising dependents, the cost of main­<br />

taining a household, <strong>and</strong> the cost of child care will be especially<br />

beneficial to low-income single heads of household, a group that has <br />

grown from 2.6 percent of total income tax returns in 1963 to 8.9 per-<br />

cent in 1982. In combination the Treasury Department proposals should <br />

have an especially positive effect on the amount of labor supplied by<br />

members of this group.


- 72 -<br />

3<br />

3-<br />

3<br />

U <br />

?9<br />

3<br />

3”<br />

n <br />

F<br />

?3<br />

3<br />

=??<br />

3<br />

F <br />

b9<br />

0<br />

0<br />

9 In<br />

69 <br />

0<br />

69 <br />

I­<br />

-a<br />

P)<br />

C<br />

z


IV.<br />

Fair <strong>and</strong> Neutral <strong>Tax</strong>ation <br />

- 73 -<br />

Equity <strong>and</strong> neutrality require that all income be subject to tax <br />

regardless of its source or use. Otherwise, families in similar <br />

circumstances will pay different amounts of tax, depending on how they <br />

earn or spend their income. <br />

A. Excluded Sources of Income<br />

1. Fringe benefits. Many fringe benefits are not subject to tax <br />

under current law; among the most important fringe benefits presently<br />

excluded from tax are contributions to qualified retirement plans, <strong>and</strong> <br />

accident, health, <strong>and</strong> group term life insurance provided by employers.<br />

It is unfair that one taxpayer is excused from paying income tax on <br />

the value of a fringe benefit, while another who wants to enjoy the <br />

same good or service, but does not receive it as a fringe benefit, <br />

must purchase it with after-tax dollars. Nor is the solution to <br />

extend the exemption of fringe benefits even further, as some have <br />

suggested. Health care is made much more expensive <strong>for</strong> all because it <br />

is effectively subsidized through the tax system <strong>for</strong> some. The tax <br />

advantage now accorded some fringe benefits causes more of them to be <br />

consumed than if, like most goods <strong>and</strong> services, they could only be <br />

bought with after-tax income. This distortion of consumer choices <br />

would only be accentuated by widening the exemption of fringe<br />

benefits. Moreover, extending the scope of the exclusion of fringe<br />

benefits would exacerbate inequities in the treatment of employees<br />

receiving fringe benefits <strong>and</strong> those who receive income in other <strong>for</strong>ms. <br />

Finally, the growing tendency to pay compensation in tax-exempt <strong>for</strong>ms <br />

reduces the base <strong>for</strong> the social security taxes <strong>and</strong> thus weakens the <br />

social security system, These inequities <strong>and</strong> distortions can be <br />

reduced only if statutory fringe benefits are taxed more nearly like <br />

other income. <br />

The Treasury Department supports the proposal contained in the<br />

Administration's Budget <strong>for</strong> fiscal year 1985 to place a limit on the<br />

amount of health <strong>and</strong> accident insurance provided by an employer that<br />

can be obtained tax-free by an employee. The Treasury Department<br />

proposes to repeal the exclusion of such premiums, to the extent that<br />

they exceed $70 per month <strong>for</strong> a single person <strong>and</strong> $175 per month <strong>for</strong> a<br />

family. The proposed limits would have no effect on approximately 70<br />

percent of all employees, because the limits exceed their employers'<br />

contributions. For example, <strong>for</strong> 1985 the maximum monthly contribution<br />

by the Federal Government to plans <strong>for</strong> its non-postal employees will<br />

be $52 <strong>for</strong> a single person <strong>and</strong> $116 <strong>for</strong> a family. The Treasury<br />

Department also proposes to repeal the current exclusions <strong>for</strong><br />

employer-provided group life insurance, death benefits, dependent-care<br />

services, housing <strong>and</strong> housing allowances <strong>for</strong> ministers, <strong>and</strong> certain<br />

military cash compensation <strong>and</strong> proposes to permit provisions dealing<br />

with educational assistance plans <strong>and</strong> group legal services to expire.<br />

The value of taxable fringe benefits will be reported by the employer,<br />

<strong>and</strong> tax will be withheld on it. No revenue gain is projected from


- 74 -<br />

repealing the exclusion of military compensation, because it is <br />

expected that compensation will be increased to offset the loss of <br />

this tax benefit. <br />

Presently the exclusion of fringe benefits from taxable income has<br />

gone so far that it has become necessary to offset the distorting<br />

effects of some tax provisions by allowing employers to offer a choice<br />

of tax-free benefits. On the one h<strong>and</strong>, current law encourages the use<br />

of tax-free <strong>for</strong>ms of compensation, but on the other it attempts to<br />

counteract these incentives by allowing employers to offer employees<br />

the choice that is normally associated with payment of wages in cash.<br />

Under the Treasury Department proposals, it will not be necessary to<br />

restrict so-called cafeteria plans, plans that allow employees to<br />

choose among tax-exempt fringe benefits. Since premiums <strong>for</strong> medical<br />

insurance below the proposed cap will be the only major statutory<br />

fringe benefit that will remain exempt, the provisions authorizing<br />

tax-free cafeteria plans will be largely redundant <strong>and</strong> should be<br />

repealed. Of course, employers -- <strong>and</strong> their employees -- may find<br />

nontax reasons, such as lower insurance rates <strong>for</strong> groups <strong>and</strong> the<br />

accommodation of different preferences, <strong>for</strong> allowing employees to<br />

select from a menu of taxable fringe benefits. Cafeteria plans might<br />

continue <strong>for</strong> this purpose.<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>ing most statutory fringe benefits will greatly simplify the <br />

administration of the tax laws by relieving the pressure to pay<br />

compensation in non-taxable <strong>for</strong>ms. Employers can continue, in effect, <br />

to offer certain goods <strong>and</strong> services <strong>for</strong> sale through salary deduc­<br />

tions, but in the absence of tax inducements <strong>for</strong> paying wages as <br />

fringe benefits, most compensation will be in cash. <br />

Employees will compare the full market prices of <strong>for</strong>merly<br />

subsidized consumption with other uses of their after-tax dollars. As <br />

a result, it is expected that employers will provide less life <br />

insurance <strong>and</strong> legal insurance, <strong>and</strong> that employees will purchase more <br />

directly. Purchases of insurance <strong>for</strong> marginal amounts of health <br />

coverage will also decline. These purchases are often quite<br />

inefficient because administrative costs, while small relative to <br />

large health bills, can be quite large relative to the cost of <br />

moderate or small amounts of health care. The rapidly rising cost of <br />

health care in the United States can be attributed in part to the <br />

large subsidy inherent in the current tax laws. The proposal to cap<br />

these health insurance benefits will help contain future increases in <br />

costs of health care. <br />

Repeal of the current exemption of fringe benefits will require<br />

both employees <strong>and</strong> employers to reconsider the mix of fringe benefits <br />

offered <strong>and</strong> accepted. To allow time <strong>for</strong> adjustment, taxation of <br />

fringe benefits will be phased in gradually, as existing employment <br />

contracts expire. <br />

2. Retirement savinqs. Current law allows saving <strong>for</strong> retirement<br />

to be sheltered from tax until retirement. <strong>Tax</strong>-preferred vehicles <strong>for</strong><br />

retirement saving include qualified retirement plans established by<br />

corporate employers, individual retirement accounts (IRAs), <strong>and</strong> H.R.


- 75 -<br />

10 plans <strong>for</strong> the self-employed (Keogh plans). The Treasury Department<br />

proposes that eligibility <strong>for</strong> IRAs be extended on equal terms to those<br />

who work in the home without pay <strong>and</strong> to those who work in the labor<br />

market. Moreover, the limit on tax-deferred contributions to an IRA<br />

will be raised to $2,500 ($5,000 <strong>for</strong> a husb<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> wife). This<br />

proposal will allow most American families to pay no tax on the income<br />

they save, as under a tax on consumed income, <strong>and</strong> will stimulate<br />

saving.<br />

3. Wage replacements. Under the Treasury Department proposals,<br />

unemployment compensation will be made fully subject to taxation.<br />

There is no reason to tax moderate-income workers more heavily than<br />

unemployed persons with the same incomes. Employees in many seasonal<br />

industries are employed, then laid off, <strong>and</strong> then rehired on a<br />

predictable annual cycie. For them, unemployment compensation is more<br />

accurately seen as a part of annual earnings than as insurance against<br />

lost wages. Beyond that, many recipients of unemployment compensation<br />

have income from other sources or are married to working spouses. <strong>Tax</strong><br />

equity is not served by exempting from tax the unemployment<br />

compensation they receive, while fully taxing other families with the<br />

same amount of income received from other sources.<br />

The failure to tax wage replacement programs under current law is<br />

quite unfair. If a program is designed to replace 70 percent of<br />

be<strong>for</strong>e-tax wages <strong>for</strong> all employees, tax exemption results in a 70<br />

percent wage replacement <strong>for</strong> low-income employees who have no other<br />

source of income. By comparison, it produces total wage replacement<br />

<strong>for</strong> a taxpayer in the 30 percent tax bracket, <strong>and</strong> lost wages are more<br />

than fully replaced <strong>for</strong> taxpayers in higher tax brackets.<br />

The current tax law provides quite inconsistent treatment of <br />

persons who are elderly, blind, <strong>and</strong> disabled. The proposed new credit <br />

<strong>for</strong> these groups will ensure greater equality of treatment of various <br />

sources of income that they receive. <strong>Tax</strong>-exempt levels of income will <br />

continue to exceed substantially the levels applying to other <br />

taxpayers. Families with large amounts of income from other sources,<br />

however, will no longer be allowed a complete exclusion <strong>for</strong> workers' <br />

compensation or <strong>for</strong> black lung or certain veterans' disability <br />

payments. Instead, such income will be taxable, but made eligible <strong>for</strong> <br />

the credit. The proposed taxation of wage replacement programs will <br />

apply only to amounts received as a result of future settlements. <br />

The taxation of wage replacements will have little effect on<br />

families with low or moderate incomes; these families generally will<br />

not be taxable because of the increase in exemptions <strong>and</strong> zero-bracket<br />

amounts proposed in this package. Many moderate income disabled<br />

workers will also receive additional benefit from the credit <strong>for</strong> the<br />

elderly <strong>and</strong> the disabled. For example, a family of four that receives<br />

$9,000 or more of workers' compensation will not owe tax until its<br />

income exceeds $17,200. Further, workers in 80 percent of States who<br />

are totally disabled <strong>for</strong> the entire year will be exempt from tax if<br />

they had no other income. For persons with high incomes -- including<br />

both those with generous rates of wage replacement <strong>and</strong> those with


- 16 -<br />

substantial income from other sources -- taxation of wage replacement<br />

payments will have a positive work incentive effect. Under current<br />

law, some individuals receive nontaxable wage replacement in excess of<br />

the after-tax wages they would receive if they continued work. Under<br />

the proposal, these individuals will again be given a positive<br />

incentive to work.<br />

4. Scholarships <strong>and</strong> fellowships. Scholarships <strong>and</strong> fellowships<br />

should be taxable, to the extent that they exceed tuition, because the <br />

stipends are used largely <strong>for</strong> consumption; such as food <strong>and</strong> lodging.<br />

For most students, the higher tax threshold provided by the personal<br />

exemptions <strong>and</strong> zero-bracket amount will prevent the taxation of these <br />

benefits. Students with substantial other sources of income, however,<br />

will be treated like other individuals with the same income. <br />

5. Capital qains. Only 40 percent of long-term capital gains --<br />

appreciation on assets held <strong>for</strong> more than 6 months -- are currently<br />

subject to tax. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, capital gains <strong>and</strong> losses are<br />

measured without regard to inflation during the time the taxpayer<br />

holds an asset. In other words, tax is applied to fictitious gains<br />

that only reflect inflation, as well as to real increases in the value<br />

of capital assets. Thus real (inflation-adjusted) gains are taxed at<br />

effective rates that can far exceed the nominal tax rate, <strong>and</strong> in some<br />

cases tax is collected even when assets decline in real value.<br />

The Treasury Department proposes to eliminate the taxation of <br />

fictitious gains by allowing taxpayers to index (adjust <strong>for</strong> inflation)<br />

the basis (usually the cost) of assets in computing capital gains.<br />

Moreover, real capital gains should be fully taxed as ordinary income. <br />

By equalizing the tax treatment of real capital gains <strong>and</strong> other <br />

sources of income, these re<strong>for</strong>ms will improve the equity <strong>and</strong> <br />

neutrality of the tax system. <br />

Given recent rates of inflation, taxing real capital gains as <br />

ordinary income would be no less generous, on average, than current <br />

law. Thus, the Treasury Department proposals should have no negative<br />

effect on capital <strong>for</strong>mation <strong>and</strong> the supply of venture capital. This <br />

is discussed further in chapter 6. <br />

Elimination of the distinction between capital gains <strong>and</strong> ordinary<br />

income will allow substantial simplification of the tax law <strong>and</strong> <br />

facilitate taxpayer compliance <strong>and</strong> tax administration. Each year the <br />

courts hear literally hundreds of tax cases involving capital gain <br />

versus ordinary income issues. Moreover, some of the most technical <br />

<strong>and</strong> complicated provisions of the Internal Revenue Code are necessary <br />

to deal with ramifications of the distinction between ordinary income <br />

<strong>and</strong> capital gains. These include the provisions dealing with <br />

depreciation recapture, collapsible partnerships <strong>and</strong> corporations,<br />

dealer versus investor determinations, <strong>and</strong> so-called section 1244 <br />

(small business corporation) stock. Finally, taxpayers <strong>and</strong> their <br />

advisors spend enormous resources or tax planning designed to achieve <br />

capital gain characterization.


6. Interest indexing. During an inflationary period, interest <br />

payments include an element that is neither income to the lender, nor <br />

an expense <strong>for</strong> the borrower, but merely compensates the lender <strong>for</strong> the <br />

reduction in the purchasing power of principal that results from <br />

inflation. Under current law this so-called "inflation premium" is <br />

subject to tax as interest income to the lender <strong>and</strong> is allowed as an <br />

interest expense to the borrower. <br />

At even moderate rates of inflation, tax liability can exceed the<br />

amount of interest earned, once adjustment is made <strong>for</strong> inflation.<br />

Suppose, <strong>for</strong> example, that the interest rate is 12 percent at a time<br />

when the inflation rate is 8 percent; the real (inflation-adjusted)<br />

interest rate is thus 4 percent. A taxpayer in the 20 percent tax<br />

bracket who holds a $1,000 bond that pays interest of $120 per year<br />

pays $24 in tax. Since the real component of interest, after<br />

adjustment <strong>for</strong> inflation, is only $40, the taxpayer pays an effective<br />

tax rate of 60 percent, not the statutory rate of 20 percent. For a<br />

taxpayer in the 40 percent bracket the situation is even worse; tax<br />

liability is $48, or 120 percent of real interest income.<br />

The Treasury Department proposes that a portion of interest<br />

receipts be excluded from tax in order to avoid this taxation of the<br />

inflation premium. An equal reduction is proposed <strong>for</strong> the deduction<br />

of non-mortgage interest expense in excess of $5,000 per year. The<br />

proposal <strong>for</strong> interest indexing is discussed briefly below <strong>and</strong> in<br />

greater detail in chapter 6.<br />

7. Dividends-received exclusion. Current law provides an<br />

exclusion from gross income <strong>for</strong> the first $100 ($200 <strong>for</strong> married<br />

taxpayers filing a joint return) of dividend income received from a<br />

domestic corporation. Because the exclusion provides little, if any,<br />

investment incentive <strong>and</strong> contributes to complexity in the tax system,<br />

it should be repealed. The proposed partial deduction <strong>for</strong> dividends<br />

paid (described in Chapter 6) can be expected to have far more<br />

favorable benefits to the owners of corporate stock.<br />

8. Preferred Uses of Income<br />

Deductions <strong>for</strong> certain personal expenditures should be curtailed,<br />

in order to broaden the tax base, simplify compliance <strong>and</strong> administra­<br />

tion, reduce government interference with private decision-making, <strong>and</strong> <br />

allow rates to be reduced <strong>for</strong> all. Two of the most important itemized <br />

deductions represent substantial Federal subsidies to State <strong>and</strong> local <br />

governments <strong>and</strong> to charities. <br />

The deduction <strong>for</strong> State <strong>and</strong> local taxes, other than the deductions <br />

<strong>for</strong> State <strong>and</strong> local taxes constituting expenses of earning income,<br />

will be phased out. There<strong>for</strong>e, no itemized deductions <strong>for</strong> State <strong>and</strong> <br />

local taxes will be allowed. The above-the-line deduction of <br />

charitable contributions by nonitemizers will be repealed a year<br />

be<strong>for</strong>e its current expiration date, <strong>and</strong> the itemized deduction <strong>for</strong> <br />

contributions will be limited to the excess over 2 percent of adjusted <br />

gross income. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the existing deductions <strong>for</strong> medical


expenses <strong>and</strong> casualty losses, which are allowed only to the extent<br />

that expenses <strong>and</strong> losses exceed 5 percent <strong>and</strong> 10 percent, respectively,<br />

of adjusted gross income, will be retained. Table 5-4<br />

indicates floors applied to various itemized deductions under both<br />

current law <strong>and</strong> the Treasury Department proposal.<br />

Itemized deductions <strong>for</strong> State <strong>and</strong> local taxes <strong>and</strong> charitable<br />

contributions together totalled some $122 billion in 1982, <strong>and</strong> they<br />

reduced individual income tax collections by roughly $30 billion. Had<br />

the policies proposed by the Treasury been in effect in that year,<br />

individual income tax rates could have been cut by about 10 percent,<br />

on average, without sacrificing revenue. Federal support of this<br />

magnitude can be defended only if there is reason to believe that the<br />

subsidized activities would otherwise be carried on at too low a level<br />

<strong>and</strong> if the present tax deduction is an efficient <strong>for</strong>m of subsidy.<br />

1. State <strong>and</strong> local taxes. Itemized deduction <strong>for</strong> State <strong>and</strong> local<br />

taxes are not required <strong>for</strong> the accurate measurement of income. Many<br />

years ago, with top rates in the neighborhood of 90 percent, the<br />

deduction was perceived to be necessary to prevent the sum of the<br />

marginal tax rates <strong>for</strong> Federal <strong>and</strong> State income taxes from exceeding<br />

100 percent. Given the present levels of tax rates, such an argument<br />

is no longer relevant. The deduction is sometimes defended as a<br />

subsidy that is required to reduce the taxpayer's net cost of paying<br />

State <strong>and</strong> local taxes. Some would argue that the deduction has the<br />

advantage of encouraging greater expenditures by State <strong>and</strong> local<br />

governments.<br />

Expenditures by State <strong>and</strong> local governments provide benefits<br />

primarily <strong>for</strong> residents of the taxing jurisdiction. To the extent<br />

that State <strong>and</strong> local taxes merely reflect the benefits of services<br />

provided to taxpayers, there is no more reason <strong>for</strong> a Federal subsidy<br />

<strong>for</strong> spending by State <strong>and</strong> local governments than <strong>for</strong> private spending.<br />

Both equity <strong>and</strong> neutrality dictate that State <strong>and</strong> local services<br />

should be financed by taxes levied on residents or on businesses<br />

operating in the jurisdiction, in the absence of evidence that<br />

substantial benefits of such expenditures spill over into other<br />

jurisdictions.<br />

There is no reason to believe that most expenditures<br />

of State <strong>and</strong> local governments have such strong spillover effects that<br />

they would be greatly under-provided in the absence of the deduction<br />

<strong>for</strong> State <strong>and</strong> local taxes. There is no reason to have high Federal<br />

tax rates <strong>and</strong> provide implicit Federal subsidies to spending of State<br />

<strong>and</strong> local governments by allowing deduction <strong>for</strong> their taxes. It would<br />

be better -- fairer, simpler, <strong>and</strong> more neutral -- to have lower<br />

Federal tax rates <strong>and</strong> have State <strong>and</strong> local government services -- like<br />

private purchases -- funded from after-tax dollars.<br />

Moreover, the deduction <strong>for</strong> State <strong>and</strong> local taxes is not an<br />

efficient subsidy. Because itemized deductions are claimed by<br />

approximately one-third of all families (or 35.1 percent of total<br />

returns in 1982), it is doubtful that they increase significantly the


- I9 -<br />

Table 5-4<br />

Floors <strong>for</strong> Deductions on Individual Income <strong>Tax</strong> Returns*<br />

Item <br />

Medical expenses <br />

Casualty expenses <br />

Charitable contributions <br />

Itemized deductions <strong>for</strong> <br />

miscellaneous expenses <br />

Employee business <br />

expenses <br />

Floor<br />

: Current Law :Proposal<br />

5% Of AGI <br />

10% of AGI <br />

No floor <br />

AIO floor<br />

( Available only<br />

t:o itemizers)<br />

No floor<br />

(Available to all<br />

taxpayers )<br />

5% Of AGI <br />

10% of AGI<br />

2% Of AGI<br />

1% Of AGI<br />

(Combined<br />

<strong>and</strong> made<br />

available<br />

to all<br />

taxpayers )<br />

*Deductions generally would be allowed only to extent they exceed the <br />

floor.


- 80 -<br />

level of State <strong>and</strong> local government services. The benefits of the <br />

subsidy thus accrue primarily to high-income individuals <strong>and</strong> high-<br />

income communities. To the extent that such subsidies are warranted,<br />

they could be provided in a much more efficient <strong>and</strong> cost-effective way<br />

through direct Federal outlays. <br />

The three most important sources of State <strong>and</strong> local tax revenue in<br />

the United States are the general sales tax, the personal income tax,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the property tax. There may be a tendency to believe that<br />

itemized deductions should be eliminated <strong>for</strong> some of these taxes, but<br />

retained <strong>for</strong> others. The Treasury Department rejects this view,<br />

because the degree of reliance on these three tax bases varies widely<br />

from state to state. Five States have no general sales tax, <strong>and</strong> six<br />

have no personal income tax. Moreover, local governments in various<br />

States make widely different use of the property tax; in 1982 the tax<br />

represented from below 40 percent to almost 100 percent of total local<br />

tax collections in various states. To allow itemized deductions <strong>for</strong><br />

some of these revenue sources, but not others, would unfairly benefit<br />

residents of the States levying the deductible taxes, relative to<br />

those who live elsewhere. Moreover, it would distort tax policy at<br />

the State <strong>and</strong> local level away from the non-deductible cevenue source.<br />

Current law does this by allowing deductions <strong>for</strong> certain taxes but not<br />

<strong>for</strong> many fees <strong>and</strong> other taxes.<br />

Moreover, because the deduction <strong>for</strong> State <strong>and</strong> local taxes leads to <br />

higher Federal tax rates <strong>for</strong> all, there is a net benefit only <strong>for</strong> <br />

States (<strong>and</strong> localities) that levy above-average taxes. Residents of <br />

states (<strong>and</strong> localities) with below-average taxes are worse off than if <br />

there were no deduction. <br />

Finally, because income levels vary across the country, taxpayers<br />

in various States make differing use of itemized deductions <strong>and</strong> pay<br />

different marginal tax rates, on average. That is, residents of highincome<br />

States make more use of itemized deductions arid pay higher<br />

marginal tax rates, on average, than do residents of low-income<br />

States. Under current law, the Federal Government pays part of State<br />

<strong>and</strong> local taxes only <strong>for</strong> those who itemize, <strong>and</strong> it pays a higher<br />

percentage of State <strong>and</strong> local taxes the higher the average income of<br />

those who do itemize deductions. Thus, under present law, the Federal<br />

Government underwrites a greater share of State <strong>and</strong> local expenditures<br />

in high-income States than in low-income States. In order to be evenh<strong>and</strong>ed<br />

<strong>and</strong> avoid this distributionally perverse pattern of subsidies,<br />

no itemized deductions should be allowed <strong>for</strong> taxes <strong>and</strong> fees paid to<br />

State <strong>and</strong> local governments. In order to minimize dislocations <strong>and</strong><br />

inequities, the Treasury Department proposes that these deductions be<br />

phased out over a two-year period.<br />

Elimination of this itemized deduction will probably have little<br />

direct effect on the revenues of State <strong>and</strong> Local jurisdictions, unlike<br />

direct reductions in revenue sharing or similar cutbacks in Federal<br />

grants. It may make citizens more conscious of the actual social cost<br />

of services provided by State <strong>and</strong> local governments. Governments will


- 81 -<br />

have incentives to rely more heavily on user charges when appropriate.<br />

Under current law, the use of such charges is discouraged, since they<br />

are not deductible. Finally, these proposed changes will reduce the<br />

extent to which low-tax <strong>and</strong> low-income jurisdictions indirectly<br />

subsidize high-tax <strong>and</strong> high-income jurisdictions.<br />

In considering the effect of the Treasury Department proposals on<br />

State <strong>and</strong> local governments, it should be noted that 34 State income<br />

tax systems piggyback on the Federal individual income tax base, <strong>and</strong><br />

many of the 46 States with corporate income taxes rely on income<br />

measurement rules of the Federal corporate tax. The base broadening<br />

contained in the Treasury Department proposals will produce large<br />

increases in individual <strong>and</strong> corporate tax revenue <strong>for</strong> these States,<br />

with little or no ef<strong>for</strong>t on their part. There<strong>for</strong>e, if State revenues<br />

are not to increase, rate reduction will also be necessary at the<br />

State level.<br />

2. Charitable contributions. Many organizations that benefit from<br />

the deduction <strong>for</strong> charitable contributions provide services that have<br />

important social benefits. Services of this kind may not be provided<br />

at optimal levels if left to the marketplace. In the absence of<br />

charitable organizations, these services might have to be provided or<br />

funded directly by government. Instead, in our pluralistic society<br />

they have been subsidized through the tax system by the allowanc'e<br />

itemized deductions <strong>for</strong> charitable contributions. Some would argue<br />

that a deduction is especially appropriate when charitable<br />

contributions of a high percentage of current income substantially<br />

reduce the taxpayer's true ability to pay, as measured by income<br />

available <strong>for</strong> private use. The important question is whether it is<br />

necessary or efficient to allow a deduction <strong>for</strong> all contributions --<br />

<strong>and</strong> thereby <strong>for</strong>ce tax rates to be higher -- in order to achieve the<br />

desired stimulus to charitable giving. To the extent that<br />

contributions would have been made in the absence of the tax benefit,<br />

the deduction only reduces revenues <strong>and</strong> causes all tax rates to be<br />

higher, without stimulating giving. For example, little incentive is<br />

provided by a deduction <strong>for</strong> the first dollars of contributions --<br />

those that are most likely to be made in any case.<br />

The Treasury Department proposes to allow a tax deduction <strong>for</strong><br />

charitable contributions only to the extent that they exceed 2. percent<br />

of adjusted gross income. For example, a taxpayer with $25,000 of<br />

income <strong>and</strong> $1,200 of contributions, would be allowed to deduct only<br />

$700; the first $500 would be nondeductible.<br />

Under present law, charitable donations of appreciated property<br />

can result i n substantial tax saving. The full value of certain<br />

donated property can be deducted against ordinary income, without any<br />

requirement that gain on the property be recognized <strong>for</strong> tax purposes.<br />

Such treatment conflicts with basic principles governing the<br />

measurement of income, produces an artificial incentive to donate<br />

appreciated property rather than cash, <strong>and</strong> also leads to abuse <strong>and</strong><br />

administrative problems <strong>for</strong> the Internal Revenue Service when<br />

taxpayers overvalue donated property. The Treasury Department<br />

of


- 82 -<br />

proposes that the deduction <strong>for</strong> a charitable contribution of<br />

appreciated property be limited to the smaller of the indexed basis of<br />

the asset or its fair market value. This re<strong>for</strong>m would increase tax<br />

equity <strong>and</strong> eliminate the attraction of fraudulent schemes based on<br />

donation of property with overstated values. It is consistent with<br />

tax law in circumstances where appreciated property is used to pay a<br />

deductible expense, or where such property is the subject of a<br />

deductible loss; a taxpayer generally is not allowed a tax deduction<br />

in respect of untaxed appreciation in property.<br />

Under current law, the deduction <strong>for</strong> charitable contributions is<br />

generally limited to 50 percent of adjusted gross income. Thus, those<br />

who contribute more than 50 percent of their income to charity are<br />

taxed on the amount contributed in excess of 50 percent of income.<br />

Individuals who contribute all of their income to charity, such as<br />

those who have taken a vow of poverty, must there<strong>for</strong>e pay tax on<br />

one-half of their contribution. By repealing the limits on the<br />

deductible charitable contributions, the Treasury propo;jal will<br />

benefit those who contribute all or most of their income to charity.<br />

Be<strong>for</strong>e 1982, only itemizers were allowed a deduction <strong>for</strong> charitable<br />

contributions. Extension of this deduction to nonitemizers<br />

taxpayers who on average have only small amounts of deductions --<br />

creates unnecessary complexity, while probably stimulating little<br />

additional giving <strong>and</strong> presenting the IRS with a difficult en<strong>for</strong>cement<br />

problem. In 1983, 33 percent of those who did not itemize claimed the<br />

"above-the-line" deduction <strong>for</strong> charitable contributions. Of these, 70<br />

percent claimed $25, the maximum amount allowed. In appraising this<br />

deduction, it would be useful to know whether taxpayers actually made<br />

these contributions or only claimed them. If the donations were made,<br />

one must ask whether they would have been made in the absence of the<br />

deduction. If they would have been made, the deduction provides no<br />

incentive <strong>for</strong> increased giving <strong>and</strong> is equivalent to an increase in the<br />

zero-bracket amount. The above-the-line deduction is scheduled to be<br />

increased in 1986, then eliminated thereafter. Since there is some<br />

lag in taxpayers' response to incentives, eliminating the incentive in<br />

1986 is unlikely to have a significant effect on the level of<br />

charitable contributions.<br />

In recent years, a little more than half of all tax returns with<br />

itemized deductions reported contributions of less than 2 percent of<br />

adjusted gross income (AGI). Even so, these proposed changes in the<br />

tax treatment of charitable contributions will have only a modest<br />

effect on the amount of charitable giving. It is doubtful that the<br />

first dollars of giving, or the giving of those who give only modest<br />

amounts, are affected much by tax considerations. Rather they<br />

probably depend more on factors such as financial ability to give,<br />

membership in charitable or philanthropic organizations, arid a general<br />

donative desire. As potential giving becomes large relative to<br />

income, however, taxes are more likely to affect the actual level of<br />

donations. Under the Treasury Department proposal, incentives are<br />

maintained <strong>for</strong> the most sensitive group, taxpayers who give aboveaverage<br />

amounts.


- 83 -<br />

By removing tax deductions <strong>for</strong> small charitable gifts, the<br />

Treasury Department proposal simplifies recordkeeping requirements <strong>for</strong><br />

taxpayers <strong>and</strong> eliminates the need <strong>for</strong> IRS to spend resources auditing<br />

these small transactions.<br />

3. Interest expense. Under current law all interest expense is<br />

deductible, either as a business or investment expense or as an<br />

itemized deduction. As a result, taxpayers are allowed deductions <strong>for</strong><br />

interest expense that does not produce currently taxable income. Home<br />

mortgages, automobile loans, <strong>and</strong> other consumer credit are examples of<br />

debt incurred to finance personal consumption, rather than business<br />

investments. Debt may also be used to finance investments that yield<br />

income that is tax-preferred, either because it is taxed at preferential<br />

rates or because tax liability is postponed to a later year.<br />

Under a comprehensive definition of income, full interest deductions<br />

would not be allowed <strong>for</strong> debt of either type.<br />

The Treasury Department proposes that the deductions individuals <br />

can claim <strong>for</strong> interest expense be limited to the sum of mortgage<br />

interest on the principal residence of the taxpayer, passive<br />

investment income (including interest income), <strong>and</strong> $5,000 per return. <br />

This limitation would permit a taxpayer to deduct mortgage interest on <br />

his or her home, interest <strong>for</strong> the purchase of a car, <strong>and</strong> interest on a <br />

considerable amount of consumption <strong>and</strong> investment-related debt. It <br />

would, however, curtail the subsidy implicit in the current law <br />

deduction <strong>for</strong> interest on debt to finance large amounts of passive,<br />

tax-preferred, investment assets (such as corporate stock) or <br />

extraordinary consumption expenditures (such as second homes). <br />

Interest expense, like interest income, is overstated during a<br />

period of inflation. Thus, the Treasury Department proposes that<br />

deductions <strong>for</strong> interest expense also be adjusted <strong>for</strong> inflation. The<br />

adjustment would apply only to the extent that interest deductions<br />

exceeded the interest on the taxpayer's principal mortgage, plus<br />

$5,000 per return ($2,500 per return <strong>for</strong> a married couple filing<br />

separately). Again, inflation adjustment of interest expense would<br />

not affect the current ability to deduct both mortgage interest on the<br />

taxpayer's home <strong>and</strong> on a considerable amount of consumer debt.<br />

Neither the indexing of net interest expense nor the limit on interest<br />

deduction would affect the vast majority of taxpayers. In 1981, only<br />

3.3 percent of individual tax returns claimed itemized deductions <strong>for</strong><br />

non-mortgage interest in excess of $5,000.<br />

4. Simplification benefits. Eliminating the deduction <strong>for</strong> State<br />

<strong>and</strong> local taxes <strong>and</strong> limitinq those <strong>for</strong> charitable contributions will<br />

simplify compliance <strong>and</strong> administration. It will no longer be<br />

necessary <strong>for</strong> taxpayers to wonder which taxes are deductible <strong>and</strong> which<br />

are not. The table used to calculate deductions <strong>for</strong> sales tax, a<br />

major nuisance <strong>and</strong> the source of numerous errors <strong>and</strong> much inaccuracy,<br />

can be eliminated. So also can the significant recordkeeping requirements<br />

<strong>for</strong> taxpayers who choose to claim sales tax deductions based on<br />

actual receipts rather than the table.


- 84 -<br />

Those who can confidently predict that their charitable contributions<br />

will not exceed 2 percent of AGI will not nee6 to worry about<br />

either writing checks or obtaining <strong>and</strong> keeping receipts <strong>for</strong> contributions.<br />

Moreover, disputes over valuation of donated property will be<br />

reduced, since deductions will be limited to indexed basis, <strong>and</strong><br />

disputes over basis can occur only if contributions exceed the two<br />

percent threshold.<br />

With itemized deductions limited in this way <strong>and</strong> the zero-bracket<br />

amount increased, the number of returns with itemized deductions will<br />

fall by about one-third. Virtually the only taxpayers who would<br />

choose to itemize would be those who could claim a deduction <strong>for</strong><br />

mortgage or other allowable interest, those with large charitable<br />

gifts, <strong>and</strong> those with large medical expenses or casualty losses.<br />

As in the case of taxation of fringe benefits, wage replacements,<br />

<strong>and</strong> other sources of presently excluded income, the increase in the <br />

personal exemption <strong>and</strong> zero-bracket amounts will prevent the few low-<br />

income households who itemize from being adversely affected by the <br />

proposed reductions in itemized deductions. <br />

C. Abuses<br />

1. Mixed personal <strong>and</strong> business expenses. Some expenditures<br />

combine business expenses with personal consumption. Amonq obvious<br />

examples are expense-account meals <strong>and</strong> entertainment, travel that has<br />

little or no business purpose, <strong>and</strong> automobiles used <strong>for</strong> both personal<br />

<strong>and</strong> business transportation. Some of these expenditures are legally<br />

deductible under current law as business expenses. Others are<br />

improperly claimed as deductions, both by unscrupulous taxpayers <strong>and</strong><br />

by generally honest taxpayers who give themselves the benefit of the<br />

doubt in marginal or uncertain cases. When the expenses are deducted,<br />

the government effectively pays part of the cost of personal<br />

consumption that others must purchase with after-tax dollars.<br />

As long ago as 1962, this abuse of the tax system was recognized<br />

<strong>and</strong> criticized by President Kennedy: '' ... (Tloo many firms <strong>and</strong><br />

individuals have devised means of deducting too many personal living<br />

expenses as business expenses, thereby charging a large part of their<br />

cost to the Federal Government. Indeed, expense account living has<br />

become a byword in the American scene. This is a matter of national<br />

concern, affecting not only our public revenues, OUL sense of<br />

fairness, <strong>and</strong> our respect <strong>for</strong> the tax system, but our moral <strong>and</strong><br />

business practice as well."<br />

The 1984 tax re<strong>for</strong>ms addressed the issue of unjustified business <br />

deductions <strong>for</strong> expensive automobiles, aircraft, personal computers <strong>and</strong> <br />

other mixed-use property. To reduce abuse in this area further,<br />

several re<strong>for</strong>ms are proposed. No deduction will be allowed <strong>for</strong> most <br />

entertainment expenses; allowable deductions <strong>for</strong> meals <strong>and</strong> lodging<br />

will be limited; <strong>and</strong> deductions <strong>for</strong> travel involving a substantial <br />

personal element will be curtailed in order to avoid government


- 05 -<br />

subsidies to thinly disguised vacation trips. The Treasury Department<br />

proposal also establishes bright line rules <strong>for</strong> determining deductible <br />

travel expenses in areas that have generated large numbers of audits <br />

<strong>and</strong> substantial amounts of litigation in the past. These re<strong>for</strong>ms will <br />

improve the image of the income tax by preventing its abuse by those <br />

who take tax deductions <strong>for</strong> personal. expenses. It will also simplify<br />

tax administration by providing sharp guidelines as to deductibility. <br />

These proposals would increase the price of purchasing travel <strong>and</strong> <br />

entertainment indirectly through a business to the same price paid by<br />

the typical taxpayer, who does not have access to business perks. The <br />

dem<strong>and</strong> by businesses <strong>and</strong> certain executives <strong>for</strong> expensive meals <strong>and</strong> <br />

various <strong>for</strong>ms of entertainment would decline. As a result, the price<br />

of such services <strong>and</strong> goods would also tend to decline, benefitting the <br />

typical citizen who is unable to obtain a subsidy <strong>for</strong> consumption<br />

expenditures by characterizing them as business expenses. Because the <br />

providers of these high-priced meals <strong>and</strong> entertainment would face <br />

reduced dem<strong>and</strong>, the production of these goods <strong>and</strong> services would also <br />

tend to fall. At the same time, providers of nonsubsidized consump­<br />

tion goods <strong>and</strong> services, such as moderately-priced meals, would face <br />

an increased dem<strong>and</strong>. <br />

It is doubtful that aggregate employment in food services will <br />

decline at all as a result of the Treasury Department proposals. For <br />

most taxpayers, consumption of restaurant meals is not subsidized. <br />

Elimination of many other preferences throughout the tax law will <br />

increase the relative dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> unsubsidized consumption such as <br />

this. In assessing the impact on this industry, as well as others, it <br />

would be a mistake to look only at the elimination of one type of <br />

preference in attempting to assess the overall impact of the tax <br />

re<strong>for</strong>m package. <br />

2. Income shifting. Progressive tax rates make it attractive <strong>for</strong><br />

parents to shift taxable income to their children in order to reduce<br />

taxes. Income can be shifted by giving income-earning assets to the<br />

children or by establishing trusts that pay income to the children.<br />

Though such arrangements clearly can have valid non-tax motivations,<br />

their tax consequences violate both the principle that families with<br />

equal incomes should pay equal taxes <strong>and</strong> the notions of vertical<br />

equity embodied in the schedule of tax rates, regardless of their<br />

motivation in a particular case. Moreover, they contribute to the<br />

perception that the tax system is unfair. Although income shifting<br />

would be less attractive under the less highly graduated rate<br />

structure proposed, it would continue to occur.<br />

The Treasury Department proposes several steps to prevent income<br />

shifting. First, under most circumstances unearned income of children<br />

under 14 derived from property given to the child by the parents, to<br />

the extent it exceeds the child's personal exemption, would be taxed<br />

at the parent's marginal tax rate. With a personal exemption of<br />

$2,000 <strong>and</strong> an interest rate of 10 percent, a child with investments of<br />

less than $20,000 would not be affected by this proposal. This<br />

provision would affect very few taxpayers. In recent years, only


- 86 -<br />

about 250,000 children under age 14 claimed as dependents on another’s<br />

tax return reported unearned income in excess of the personal<br />

exemption.<br />

Second, in both the case of a trust that reverts to the creator of<br />

the trust <strong>and</strong> of trust income that i s not required to be distributed<br />

to beneficiaries or set aside <strong>for</strong> them, the income of the trust would<br />

be taxed to its creator, rather than to the trust or its beneficiaries.<br />

This re<strong>for</strong>m, though intended primarily to preserve the fairness<br />

of the tax system, also would have substantial advantages in<br />

terms of simplification. It would reduce the incentive to create<br />

elaborate trusts or engage in other complicated transactions designed<br />

to shift income to others.<br />

IV.<br />

Simplification <br />

Many of the proposals described in this chapter, though intended <br />

primarily to increase the neutrality <strong>and</strong> fairness of the tax system,<br />

would allow simplification of the tax system <strong>for</strong> most individuals. <br />

Yet others, described in this section, are proposed with the primary<br />

objective of further simplifying taxpayer compliance. <br />

A. A Return-Free System,<br />

To simplify taxpayer compliance, the Internal Revenue Service will <br />

consider initiation of a system under which many individual taxpayers<br />

would no longer be required to prepare <strong>and</strong> file tax returns. Instead,<br />

the IRS, at the election of eligible taxpayers, would calculate tax <br />

liability, based on withholding <strong>and</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mation returns currently<br />

submitted by employers <strong>and</strong> third parties. The IRS will not need any<br />

in<strong>for</strong>mation <strong>for</strong> this purpose that it would not receive from third <br />

parties under current law. All taxpayers included in the return-free <br />

system would be provided copies of the calculation of tax liability<br />

prepared <strong>for</strong> them by the IRS <strong>and</strong> would be allowed to question the <br />

computation of their taxes. <br />

The return-free system would initially be limited to single wage <br />

earners with uncomplicated financial transactions, the population of <br />

roughly 15 million taxpayers now filing the simplified <strong>for</strong>m 1040EZ. <br />

After a pilot program, the system could be extended to other indi­<br />

vidual taxpayers, <strong>and</strong> by 1990, roughly 66 percent of all taxpayers<br />

could be covered by the return-free system. It is estimated that at <br />

this level of participation this system would save taxpayers annually<br />

approximately 97 million hours <strong>and</strong> $1.9 billion in fees paid to <br />

professional tax preparers. <br />

B. Other Simplification <strong>for</strong> Individuals <br />

Movement toward a broad-base tax requires that better measures of<br />

income be obtained <strong>and</strong> that currently excluded items be counted in<br />

income subject t o tax. 111 some cases, additional calculations would<br />

be needed, but on balance a broad-base income tax would reduce the<br />

complexity caused by current law. Many of the most important sources


- 87 -<br />

of complexity under current law arise from tax-induced changes in the<br />

economic affairs of millions of individuals. For example, the<br />

Treasury Department proposals will reduce the incentive to invest in<br />

tax shelters. Thus, many fewer individuals will need to appraise<br />

calculations of the after-tax benefits of complicated tax-shelter<br />

investments, much less shift assets in search of such shelters.<br />

similarly, if employers insist on providing free in-kind benefits to<br />

employees, then the calculation of taxable compensation may be made<br />

more difficult. But if they pay wages in cash, or charge appropriately<br />

<strong>for</strong> other goods they want to provide, then their wage <strong>and</strong><br />

fringe benefit structure, as well as the calculations they make <strong>for</strong><br />

tax purposes, will actually be simpler than be<strong>for</strong>e.<br />

Additional proposals will both simplify the income tax <strong>and</strong> make it<br />

more comprehensive. These include elimination of the preference <strong>for</strong><br />

capital gains; imposition of a uni<strong>for</strong>m tax on compensation income in<br />

whatever <strong>for</strong>m derived (with few exceptions); repeal of the $100/$200<br />

partial dividends received deduction; elimination of provisions such<br />

as the credit <strong>for</strong> political contributions <strong>and</strong> the presidential<br />

campaign checkoff; <strong>and</strong> restricting eligibility <strong>for</strong> income averaging.<br />

Itemized deductions <strong>for</strong> expenses of earning income <strong>and</strong> certain other<br />

deductions will be combined into one adjustment (an above-the-line<br />

deduction) subject to a floor of one percent of AGI. Because of the<br />

floor, taxpayers with only minimal expenses of this kind willnot need<br />

to bother with recording the expenses <strong>and</strong> claiming a deduction.<br />

V. Reducing Noncompliance <br />

A. The <strong>Tax</strong> Gap<br />

During recent years considerable attention has been focused on the<br />

existence <strong>and</strong> size of the "underground economy." That term has<br />

multiple definitions but in the minds of many the focus is on illegal<br />

activities or cl<strong>and</strong>estine economic operations. Those engaged in<br />

totally legal activities may, nonetheless, improperly fail to comply<br />

with the tax laws. This report employs the term "tax gap," in lieu of<br />

"underground economy," to encompass the revenues lost from all<br />

failures to comply with the tax law.<br />

The tax gap is, thus, a broad concept which represents the<br />

difference between total payments received through voluntary<br />

compliance <strong>and</strong> the total amount of tax that would be collected if<br />

there were full compliance with the tax law. Thus, the tax gap<br />

includes not only the tax due on all unreported income, regardless of<br />

whether the underlying activities are legal or illegal, but also the<br />

tax that is not paid because of overstated business expenses <strong>and</strong><br />

personal deductions.<br />

Largely on the basis of studies of taxpayer compliance, the IRS<br />

estimated that in 1981 the tax gap was $90.5 billion. (See Table<br />

5-5.) Nine billion dollars of the gap represents a minimal estimate<br />

of the lost income tax revenue from illegal activities, primarily<br />

illegal drugs, gambling, <strong>and</strong> prostitution. The remaining $81.5


- 88 -<br />

Table 5-5<br />

Income <strong>Tax</strong> Gap - 1981<br />

(in billions of dollars)<br />

Legal Sector <strong>Tax</strong> Gap, Total <br />

Corporation tax gap, Total <br />

Individual tax gap, Total <br />

Individual income tax lii<br />

lity reporting gap,Total<br />

Nonfilers' income tax liability<br />

(Net of prepayments <strong>and</strong> credits)<br />

Filer's income tax liability<br />

Unreported income <br />

Overstated business expenses<br />

Overstated personal deductions -1/<br />

Net calculation errors <br />

Individual income tax remittance gap, Total <br />

Employer underdeposit of withholding<br />

Individual balances due after remittance <br />

Illegal sector tax gap (partial) 2/ <br />

Total legal <strong>and</strong> illegal tax gap <br />

$81.5<br />

6.2<br />

75.3<br />

68.5<br />

2.9<br />

65.6<br />

52.2<br />

6.3<br />

6.6<br />

0.5<br />

6.8<br />

2.4<br />

4.4<br />

$9.0<br />

$90.5<br />

Office of the Secretary of the Treasury November 19, 1984<br />

Office of <strong>Tax</strong> Analysis<br />

-1/ Includes itemized deductions, personal exemptions, <strong>and</strong><br />

statutory adjustments.<br />

-2/ Income from illegal drugs, gambling, <strong>and</strong> prostitution only.<br />

Source: Internal Revenue Service. Income <strong>Tax</strong> Compliance<br />

Research, Estimates <strong>for</strong> 1973-1981. (July, 1983)


- 89 -<br />

billion of the gap was from omitted income or overstated deductions in <br />

activities that are otherwise completely legal. Of the $81.5 billion,<br />

$6.2 billion is attributable to corporations, $6.8 billion results <br />

from acknowledged but unpaid liabilities (essentially collection <br />

problems), <strong>and</strong> $2.9 billion is due to those who improperly fail to <br />

file tax returns. The remaining $65.6 billion gap is on returns of <br />

individuals who file income tax returns but who omit or understate <br />

income or overstate expenses: $52.2 billion is attributable to <br />

unreported or underreported income; $12.9 billion is due to overstated <br />

deductions; <strong>and</strong> $0.5 billion is due to net calculation errors in the <br />

taxpayer's favor. <br />

The total unreported income <strong>for</strong> individuals (both filers <strong>and</strong> non-<br />

filers) in 1981 was $250 billion. The eight largest areas of omission <br />

were: wages <strong>and</strong> salaries ($94.6 billion) with a 94 percent compliance<br />

rate; non-farm proprietorships (including partnership <strong>and</strong> small <br />

business corporations) ($58.4 billion) with a 79 percent compliance <br />

rate; interest income ($20.5 billion) with a compliance rate of 86 <br />

percent; capital gains ($17.7 billion) with a 59 percent compliance<br />

rate; "in<strong>for</strong>mal supplier" income ($17.1 billion) with a 21 percent<br />

compliance rate; farm income ($9.5 billion) with an 88 percent<br />

compliance rate; pension <strong>and</strong> annuities ($8.8 billion) with an 85 <br />

percent compliance rate; <strong>and</strong> dividends ($8.8 billion) with an 84 <br />

percent compliance rate. The causes of these underpayments vary, <strong>and</strong> <br />

resolution will require a number of actions. Fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m <br />

will help to stem the growth of the tax gap. Although the Treasury<br />

Department study was directed primarily toward restoring simplicity<br />

<strong>and</strong> equity to the tax system, its proposals will have some impact on <br />

the tax gap. <br />

The breakdown in tax compliance <strong>and</strong> taxpayer morale during the<br />

last 20 years seems to be attributable, at least in part, to growing<br />

perceptions of unfairness in the current tax system. For example, a<br />

public opinion survey conducted <strong>for</strong> the IRS during the summer of 1984<br />

supports the view that many taxpayers fail to comply because they<br />

believe inequities in the tax structure inherently favor others.<br />

Loopholes such as tax shelters, personal use of business assets,<br />

deductions <strong>for</strong> what are essentially personal expenses (e.g., disguised<br />

vacations), <strong>and</strong> nontaxable fringe benefits contribute to this<br />

perception. By sharply curtailing these avenues of tax avoidance <strong>and</strong><br />

evasion, the proposa1.s will diminish this <strong>for</strong>m of rationalization <strong>for</strong><br />

failure to comply with the tax laws.<br />

Enactment of the re<strong>for</strong>ms described above will reduce the number of <br />

taxpayers claiming itemized deductions by about one-third. AS the <br />

list of deductible expenses is curtailed, the opportunities to inflate <br />

itemized deductions will disappear. Also, lower tax rates reduce the <br />

benefits of cheating. Hence, though broadening the tax base to allow <br />

a reduction in tax rates is the primary objective of these proposals, <br />

an important by-product of base-broadening is a reduction in the tax <br />

gap.


- 90 -<br />

The tax gap is not entirely a consequence of cheating by taxpayers.<br />

In many cases it is a result of oversight or carelessness.<br />

This may explain much of the underreporting of interest <strong>and</strong> wages.<br />

IRS statistics indicate that 81 percent of the approximately 25<br />

million taxpayers who make errors in the reporting of interest do so<br />

in amounts of $200 or less. In other cases individuals admit to owing<br />

tax, but do not have the resources to pay the tax. If the amount of<br />

tax owed is small, the cost of collection may exceed the outst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

liability.<br />

The proposal to eliminate filing of returns <strong>for</strong> a majority of <br />

individual taxpayers is motivated primarily by the objective of <br />

simplification. However, coincident with this change, the IRS <br />

contemplates continued development <strong>and</strong> exp<strong>and</strong>ed use of in<strong>for</strong>mation <br />

returns. Accordingly, in the return-free system, the unreported income <br />

from wages, dividends, interest, capital gains <strong>and</strong> all other <strong>for</strong>m of <br />

income on which third-party reports are made to IRS will be subject to <br />

greater scrutiny. As a result, it is reasonably anticipated that a <br />

significantly greater part of the currently unreported income will be <br />

included in the computation of tax liabilities. <br />

While a simpler <strong>and</strong> fairer tax system reduces both the <br />

opportunities <strong>and</strong> the incentives <strong>for</strong> tax evasion, some opportunities<br />

will remain, <strong>and</strong> determined taxpayers will continue to use them. <br />

There will always be a trade-off between the types <strong>and</strong> Levels of <br />

en<strong>for</strong>cement activities <strong>and</strong> the amounts of tax evasion. The balance <br />

between the two must be determined by public policy, consistent with <br />

the traditions <strong>and</strong> institutions of our free <strong>and</strong> democratic society. <br />

From the point of view of tax policy <strong>and</strong> tax administration in a <br />

free society, we must recognize that eliminating the tax gap<br />

attributable to illegal sector activities is essentially hopeless.<br />

If, despite our best attempts, we cannot stop the underlying illegal<br />

activity, we should not delude ourselves into believing that we can <br />

actually collect taxes on that activity. Thus, tax re<strong>for</strong>m by itself <br />

will not help to convert the illegal sector tax gap into tax receipts. <br />

The $81.5 billion tax gap previously estimated <strong>for</strong> 1981 may<br />

substantially overstate the actual gap under current law. The 23<br />

percent rate reduction enacted in the Economic Recovery <strong>Tax</strong> Act of<br />

1981 (ERTA) substantially lowered the tax consequences of omitted<br />

incomes. The 1981, 1982, <strong>and</strong> 1983 enactments of exp<strong>and</strong>ed in<strong>for</strong>mation<br />

reporting <strong>for</strong> certain income such as tips, capital gains, <strong>and</strong> mortgage<br />

interest payments, <strong>and</strong> the backup withholding requirements <strong>for</strong><br />

dividend <strong>and</strong> interest permanently improved compliance in these areas.<br />

The lower tax rates <strong>and</strong> doubled personal exemptions that The Treasury<br />

Department is proposing will further lower the tax gap.<br />

While tax re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>and</strong> lower tax rates may reduce the benefits of <br />

evasion, some benefits would remain. In the so-called "in<strong>for</strong>mal" <br />

sector <strong>and</strong> in both farm <strong>and</strong> non-farm small businesses where business <br />

is transacted in cash or where there is a mixing of business <strong>and</strong>


- 91 -<br />

personal activit es, many of the problems that lead to the current tax<br />

gap will remain.<br />

B. Amnesties <br />

Several states have recently enacted amnesties <strong>for</strong> past failures<br />

to comply with their tax laws, <strong>and</strong> the possibility of a Federal<br />

amnesty has been discussed. Advocates of amnesties view them as a<br />

means of encouraging future compliance. They reason that amnesties<br />

will improve compliance by those who may be otherwise less than<br />

<strong>for</strong>thright with the tax authorities. Some even see amnesties as a<br />

source of substantial short-run revenue as delinquent taxpayers<br />

discharge past liabilities. In a well-documented study on tax amnesty<br />

titled "<strong>Tax</strong> Amnesty: State <strong>and</strong> European Experience," the<br />

Congressional Research Service elaborates on many of the difficulties<br />

associated with amnesty programs.<br />

The Treasury Department rejects the idea of <strong>for</strong>giving past tax <br />

liabilities, civil penalties, <strong>and</strong> interest. To include tax, civil <br />

penalties, <strong>and</strong> interest in an amnesty would further undermine taxpayer<br />

morale by sending a clear signal to the American public concerning<br />

non-compliance <strong>and</strong> tax fraud: "Don't bother to pay now. We may<br />

<strong>for</strong>get you owe anything. Even if you have to pay tax, we won't charge<br />

interest." Even a limited amnesty that applied only to criminal <br />

prosecution, without affecting liabilities <strong>for</strong> tax, penalties, <strong>and</strong> <br />

interest, would have very much the same effect. <br />

Amnesties can only rein<strong>for</strong>ce the growing impression that the tax <br />

system is unfair <strong>and</strong> encourage taxpayer non-compliance. After <br />

reviewing state <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong>eign experience with amnesties, the Treasury<br />

Department rejects their use by the Federal Government.


- 93 -<br />

APPENDIX 5-A<br />

LIST OF PROPOSED REFORMS<br />

INCOME TAX REFORM AND SIMPLIFICATION FOR INDIVIDUALS<br />

A. Rate Reauction<br />

1. Reduce rates <strong>and</strong> collapse present 15 tax rates <strong>for</strong> single<br />

taxpayers <strong>and</strong> 14 tax rates <strong>for</strong> married taxpayers <strong>and</strong> heads of<br />

households into 3 rates.<br />

8. <strong>Fairness</strong> <strong>for</strong> Families<br />

1. Increase the zero-bracket amount from $2,510 t o $2,800 <strong>for</strong><br />

single filers, from $2,510 to $3,500 <strong>for</strong> heads of households,<br />

<strong>and</strong> from $3,710 to $3,800 <strong>for</strong> joint filers.<br />

2. Increase personal exemptions from $1,090 to $2,000. <br />

3. Fold additional exemptions <strong>for</strong> the blind <strong>and</strong> elderly into an <br />

exp<strong>and</strong>ed credit <strong>for</strong> the elderly <strong>and</strong> disabled, <strong>and</strong> make all <br />

taxable disability income eligible <strong>for</strong> the credit. <br />

4. Repeal deduction <strong>for</strong> two-earner married couples. <br />

5. Index earned income tax credit. <br />

6. Replace child <strong>and</strong> dependent care credit with a deduction from <br />

gross income with same cap ($2,400 if one child, $4,800 if <br />

two or more). <br />

C. Fair <strong>and</strong> Neutral <strong>Tax</strong>ation<br />

1. Excluded Sources of Income <br />

a. Fringe Benefits <br />

1. Repeal exclusion of health insurance above a cap<br />

($175 per month <strong>for</strong> family coverage, $70 per month <br />

<strong>for</strong> individual coverage).<br />

2. Repeal exclusion of group-term life insurance. <br />

3. Repeal exclusion of employer-provided death benefits. <br />

4. Repeal exclusion of dependent care services or reim­<br />

bursement. <br />

5. Repeal special treatment of cafeteria plans.<br />

6. Repeal exemption of voluntary employee's beneficiary<br />

associations <strong>and</strong> trusts <strong>for</strong> supplemental unemployment<br />

compensation <strong>and</strong> black lung disability.<br />

7. Repeal special treatment of incentive stock options. <br />

8. Repeal exclusion of employee awards.<br />

9. Repeal exclusion of certain military compensation,<br />

with offsetting adjustments in military pay<br />

schedules. <br />

459-370 0 - 84 - 5


- 94 -<br />

10. Repeal exclusion of rental allowances or rental value <br />

of a minister's home. <br />

b. Wage Replacement Payments <br />

1. Repeal tax-exempt threshold <strong>for</strong> unemployment insurance<br />

compensation.<br />

2. Repeal tax exemption of workers' compensation, black <br />

lung, <strong>and</strong> certain veterans' disability payments, but <br />

make all such income eligible <strong>for</strong> the credit <strong>for</strong> the <br />

elderly, blind, <strong>and</strong> disabled. <br />

c. Other Excluded Sources of Income <br />

1. Repeal exclusion of scholarships <strong>and</strong> fellowships in<br />

excess of tuition.<br />

2. Repeal exclusion of awards <strong>and</strong> prizes.<br />

2. preferred Uses of Income<br />

D. <strong>Tax</strong> Abuses<br />

a. Repeal the itemized deduction <strong>for</strong> state <strong>and</strong> local taxes.<br />

b. Repeal the above-the-line deduction <strong>for</strong> charitable con­<br />

tributions. <br />

c. Limit itemized deductions <strong>for</strong> charitable contributions to <br />

those in excess of 2% of gross income. <br />

d. Limit deduction <strong>for</strong> charitable contributions of appre­<br />

ciated property to indexed basis. <br />

e. Repeal 50% <strong>and</strong> 30% limits on individual contributions.<br />

f. Repeal 10% limit on corporate contributions (but retain<br />

5% limit in certain cases).<br />

1. Business Deductions <strong>for</strong> Personal Expenses <br />

a. Deny all entertainment expenses including club dues <strong>and</strong><br />

tickets to public events, except <strong>for</strong> business meals furnished<br />

in a clear business setting. Limit deduction <strong>for</strong><br />

business meals on a per meal per person basis.<br />

b. Limit deductions <strong>for</strong> meals <strong>and</strong> lodging away from home in<br />

excess of 200% of the Federal per diem. When travel<br />

lasts longer than 30 days in one city, limit deductions<br />

to 150% of the Federal per diem.<br />

c. Establish bright-line rules to separate indefinite <strong>and</strong> <br />

temporary assignments at one year.<br />

d. Deny any deduction <strong>for</strong> travel as a <strong>for</strong>m of education. <br />

e. Deny deductions <strong>for</strong> seminars held aboard cruise ships.<br />

f. Deny any deduction <strong>for</strong> travel by ocean liner, cruise<br />

ship, or other <strong>for</strong>m of luxury water transportation<br />

above the cost of otherwise available business<br />

transportation with medical exception.


2. Income Shifting <br />

- 95 -<br />

a. Revise grantor trust rules to eliminate shifting of in-<br />

come to lower rate beneficiaries through trusts in which <br />

the creator retains an interest. <br />

b. During creator's lifetime, tax trusts at the creator's <br />

tax rate <strong>and</strong> allow deductions only <strong>for</strong> non-discretionary<br />

distributions <strong>and</strong> set-asides. After creator's death, tax <br />

all undistributed trust or estate income at the top mar­<br />

ginal rate. <br />

c. <strong>Tax</strong> unearned income of children under 14 at the<br />

parents' rate ( to the extent such income exceeds the<br />

child's personal exemption).<br />

d. Revise income taxation of trusts. <br />

E. Further Simplification<br />

1. Non-filing system, in which IRS would compute taxes <strong>for</strong> many <br />

taxpayers. <br />

2. Repeal individual minimum taxes (only if basic re<strong>for</strong>ms are <br />

fully implemented). <br />

3. Move miscellaneous deductions above the line, combine with<br />

employee business expenses, <strong>and</strong> make subject to a floor.<br />

4. Repeal preferential treatment of capital gains.l/ -<br />

5. Repeal political contribution credit. <br />

6. Repeal presidential campaign checkoff. <br />

7. Repeal deduction of adoption expenses <strong>for</strong> children with<br />

special needs, <strong>and</strong> replace with a direct expenditure program.<br />

8. Disallow income averaging <strong>for</strong> taxpayers who were full-time<br />

students during the base period.<br />

9. Repeal $100/$200 exclusion <strong>for</strong> dividend income. -1/<br />

F. Other Miscellaneous <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong>s<br />

1. Increase limits on moving expenses. <br />

2. Special rule <strong>for</strong> allowing deduction of some commuting expenses<br />

by workers (-, construction workers) who have no<br />

regular place of work.<br />

-1/ Discussed at greater length in Chapter 6.


- 97 -<br />

Chapter 6<br />

BASIC TAXATXON OF CAPITAL AND BUSINESS 2NCOPlE<br />

I. Summary<br />

The Treasury Department proposals <strong>for</strong> fundamental re<strong>for</strong>m of the<br />

taxation of capital <strong>and</strong> business income are described in this chapter.<br />

<strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong>s directed at specific industries <strong>and</strong> at tax shelters are<br />

covPred in chapter 7.<br />

General re<strong>for</strong>ms of three basic types are proposed. First, in<br />

order to measure real economic income more accurately, the Treasury<br />

Department proposes that inflation adjustments be made in the<br />

calculation of depreciation allowances, capital gains, the cost of<br />

goods sold from inventories, <strong>and</strong> interest income <strong>and</strong> expense. This<br />

will eliminate the need <strong>for</strong> the current arbitrary ad hoc adjustments<br />

<strong>for</strong> inflation incorporated in the investment tax credit, the<br />

accelerated write-off of depreciable property, <strong>and</strong> the partial<br />

exclusion of long-term capital gains.<br />

Second, the Treasury Department proposes that current incentives<br />

<strong>for</strong> retirement savings be exp<strong>and</strong>ed by increasing the limits on<br />

contributions to individual retirement accounts (IRAs) <strong>and</strong> extending<br />

the availability of IRAs to spouses not employed in the marketplace.<br />

Also, the treatment of all tax-favored retirement plans will be<br />

rationalized by subjecting all pre-retirement distributions to uni<strong>for</strong>m<br />

rules <strong>and</strong> simplifying the contribution limits applied to various<br />

plans.<br />

Third, the Treasury Department proposes that corporations <strong>and</strong><br />

partnerships be taxed in more nearly the same way by granting<br />

corporations a partial deduction <strong>for</strong> dividends paid <strong>and</strong> by taxing<br />

certain partnerships as corporations.<br />

11. Lower Corporate <strong>Tax</strong> Rates<br />

The Treasury Department's proposals to define the corporate tax<br />

base more comprehensively <strong>and</strong> eliminate most tax credits would allow<br />

the corporate tax rate to be reduced to 33 percent. All corporate<br />

income, except income of S corporations, which is accorded passthrough<br />

treatment, will be subject to this single rate. With a flat<br />

corporate rate only 2 percentage points below the proposed top<br />

individual rate, the personal holding company tax can be repealed.<br />

The current preferential rates <strong>for</strong> small corporations will be<br />

unnecessary once the corporate tax rate is reduced, especially since<br />

the re<strong>for</strong>m package will substantially improve the competitiveness of<br />

small businesses.


111. <strong>Tax</strong>ing Real Economic Income<br />

- 98 -<br />

The U.S. tax law takes a schizophrenic view toward the taxation of<br />

business income. On the one h<strong>and</strong>, some <strong>for</strong>ms of income zre treated<br />

quite favorably. Capital gains are taxed only when they are realized,<br />

60 percent of long-term gains are excluded from the tax base, <strong>and</strong><br />

gains on appreciated property transferred at death escape tax<br />

completely. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, nominal gains are subject to tax<br />

without an adjustment <strong>for</strong> inflation. Whether, on balance, real<br />

capital gains are taxed more or less heavily than ordinary real income<br />

depends on complicated interactions between the rate of inflation, the<br />

rate of appreciation, <strong>and</strong> the holding period of the particular asset.<br />

Much the same is true of income from depreciable assets. On the<br />

one h<strong>and</strong>, the investment tax credit (ITC) lowers equipment costs, <strong>and</strong><br />

asset lives under the Accelerated Cost Recovery System (ACRS) are<br />

shorter than economic lives. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, depreciation<br />

allowances are based on historic costs without adjustment <strong>for</strong><br />

inflation.<br />

The combination of the ITC <strong>and</strong> ACRS may be more or less generous<br />

than real economic depreciation, depending on the particular asset <strong>and</strong><br />

the rate of inflation. At current rates of inflation, the ITC <strong>and</strong><br />

ACRS generally provide capital recovery allowances that exceed the<br />

present value of the real economic depreciation which is required <strong>for</strong><br />

the accurate measurement of income. Indeed, <strong>for</strong> short-lived machinery<br />

<strong>and</strong> equipment, the present value of capital recovery allowances under<br />

XRS <strong>and</strong> the ITC is roughly equivalent to expensing (<strong>and</strong> in some<br />

instances is even more favorable); that is, at current inflation<br />

rates, there is no tax on (or even a subsidy to) the income earned by<br />

such assets.<br />

The present tax treatment of depreciable assets is inappropriate<br />

in the context of an income tax. It gives rise to a <strong>for</strong>m of tax<br />

arbitrage; taxpayers can borrow, receive a full deduction <strong>for</strong> interest<br />

paid, <strong>and</strong> invest in assets where the return is not fully subject to<br />

income tax. (Lenders are generally in lower rate brackets than<br />

borrowers, due to the "clientele effect;" that is, high-bracket<br />

taxpayers tend to be borrowers while low-bracket taxpayers tend to be<br />

lenders under a progressive income tax). Moreover, capital recovery<br />

allowances under ACRS <strong>and</strong> the ITC are "front-loaded,'' in that they<br />

greatly exceed the value of economic depreciation in the early years<br />

of an investment; this feature has been an important contributing<br />

factor to both the stockpiling of unused tax deductions <strong>and</strong> credits by<br />

some firms <strong>and</strong> the recent dramatic growth of tax shelters.<br />

The tax treatment of inventories is also rather schizophrenic.<br />

Firms are allowed to use last-in, first-out (LIFO) accounting, which<br />

provides an approximate adjustment <strong>for</strong> inflation in the calculation of<br />

goods sold from inventory. However, due to the "LIFO con<strong>for</strong>mity<br />

requirement," firms using LIFO <strong>for</strong> tax purposes must use the same<br />

accounting method <strong>for</strong> financial reporting purposes. This requirement<br />

discourages the adoption of LIFO, since many firms apparently think


that the use of LIFO <strong>for</strong> financial reports would put them at a<br />

competitive disadvantage in attracting investment funds relative to<br />

firms that report profits using first-in, first-out (FIFO) accounting.<br />

The Treasury Department proposes that the taxation <strong>and</strong> measurement<br />

of capital income be rationalized. The most critical element of a<br />

rational system is the accurate measurement of real economic income in<br />

an inflationary environment. To this end, the present system, with<br />

its ad hoc adjustments <strong>for</strong> inflation, such as the partial exclusion of<br />

long-term capital gains <strong>and</strong> the combination of accelerated depreciation<br />

<strong>and</strong> the ITC, will be replaced with explicit inflation adjustments<br />

<strong>for</strong> the basis used in calculating both depreciation allowances <strong>and</strong><br />

capital gains. Since depreciation will no longer need to be<br />

accelerated to compensate <strong>for</strong> the effects of inflation, ACRS will be<br />

replaced with economic depreciation. With taxation based on real<br />

capital gains <strong>and</strong> real economic depreciation, the partial exclusion of<br />

long-term capital gains <strong>and</strong> the investment tax credit will be<br />

repealed. To prevent inflation-induced tax discrimination against<br />

industries that invest heavily in inventories, the availability of<br />

LIFO inventory accounting will be exp<strong>and</strong>ed by eliminating the LIFO<br />

con<strong>for</strong>mity requirement. Indexed first-in, first-out (FIFO) accounting,<br />

a more accurate method of accounting <strong>for</strong> the effects of inflation<br />

on the cost of goods sold from inventory, will be made available, but<br />

not required.<br />

Allowing inflation adjustment <strong>for</strong> capital gains, depreciation, <strong>and</strong><br />

inventories, without also adjusting interest income <strong>and</strong> expense, would<br />

be neither fair nor neutral. Nominal interest rates include an<br />

inflationary component which merely compensates the lender <strong>for</strong> the<br />

reduction in real value of principal resulting from inflation.<br />

Without indexing of interest, the income of lenders would be<br />

overstated, since they would continue to pay tax on the inflationary<br />

component of nominal interest that represents a return of capital,<br />

rather than real income. Conversely, the income of borrowers would be<br />

understated, since they would continue to take a deduction <strong>for</strong> the<br />

full amount of nominal interest paid including the inflationary<br />

component. This problem is particularly serious in an indexed world,<br />

since borrowers can invest in assets that benefit from inflation<br />

adjustment. In order to mitigate this problem of income measurement,<br />

the Treasury Department proposes that both interest expense (in excess<br />

of home mortgage interest plus $5,000) <strong>and</strong> interest income be indexed<br />

<strong>for</strong> inflation, using the fractional exclusion method described below.<br />

The proposed inflation adjustments will assure that taxpayers no<br />

longer pay tax on fictitious income from capital that merely reflects<br />

inflation; similarly interest deductions subject to the inflation<br />

adjustment will not be bloated by inflation premiums that do not<br />

represent real costs. For all adjustments, inflation will be measured<br />

by the change in the consumer price index <strong>for</strong> urban households<br />

(CPI-U); this index was chosen because it is familiar, readily<br />

available, <strong>and</strong> not subject to revision after it is published.


- 100 -<br />

Allowing deductions <strong>for</strong> real economic depreciation <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> the<br />

real cost of goods sold from inventories will improve the measurement<br />

of real income from business <strong>and</strong> capital. This, in turn, will<br />

increase tax equity <strong>and</strong> reduce tax-induced distortions in investment<br />

decisions. Many tax shelters are motivated by the combination of the<br />

up-front benefits of the investment tax credit <strong>and</strong> accelerated<br />

depreciation, the deductibility of nominal interest expense, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

preferential taxation of capital gains. Eliminating the ITC, indexing<br />

capital gains <strong>and</strong> taxing them as ordinary income, indexing interest<br />

expense, <strong>and</strong> gearing depreciation allowances <strong>for</strong> tax purposes more<br />

clearly to real economic depreciation will substantially reduce the<br />

benefits of investments in tax shelters. These measures will<br />

simultaneously increase the return to investments in industries that<br />

are currently disadvantaged by the tax system, including established<br />

industries with disproportionately large inventories or use of<br />

structures, as well as new, emerging industries such as those in the<br />

"high technology ' area. Also, decreased use of tax shelters <strong>and</strong> the<br />

taxation of real corporate income will increase the perceived fairness<br />

of the income tax.<br />

Inflation adjustment inherently involves complexity. Nonetheless,<br />

the Treasury Department believes that the economic advantages flowing<br />

from improvement in the measurement of real economic income during<br />

inflation more than offset the cost of increased complexity.<br />

Indexing <strong>for</strong> inflation may give the impression that inflation is<br />

expected; indeed, some will argue that indexation weakens the private<br />

sector's resistance to inflation <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e makes inflation more<br />

likely. The proposal <strong>for</strong> inflation adjustment should not be interpreted<br />

as a prediction that high inflation will resume. Prudent<br />

monetary policy would keep the inflation rate at the low level<br />

<strong>for</strong>ecast by the Administration. Nor does inflation adjustment in the<br />

measurement of taxable income necessarily produce higher inflation.<br />

While indexing may reduce private resistance to inflation, it also<br />

eliminates the possibility of using inflation to raise taxes on real<br />

capital <strong>and</strong> business income.<br />

Inflation adjustment is best seen as insurance against inflation<br />

<strong>for</strong> taxpayers <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> the nation. High rates of inflation are not<br />

expected, but if they occur, Americans will not be <strong>for</strong>ced, as they<br />

were during the 1970s, to suffer the inequities, distortions, <strong>and</strong><br />

adverse impacts on capital <strong>for</strong>mation that result from an unindexed tax<br />

system. Increased complexity is part of the price <strong>for</strong> that insurance.<br />

A. Capital Gains<br />

Capital gains on assets held <strong>for</strong> at least a prescribed period have<br />

long benefitted from preferential tax treatment. In particular, tax<br />

on accrued gains is postponed until gains are realized (usually<br />

through the sale of an asset), 60 percent of long-term nominal capital<br />

gains are excluded from the tax base, <strong>and</strong> gains on assets transferred<br />

at death completely escape income taxation. Nevertheless, during an<br />

inflationary period, capital gains may be subject to very high


- 101 -<br />

effective tax rates because purely inflationary gains are included in<br />

the tax base; <strong>for</strong> example, during the high inflation years of the<br />

1970s, effective tax rates on real capital gains frequently exceeded<br />

100 percent, despite the 50 percent exclusion then in <strong>for</strong>ce.<br />

Similarly, despite the current 60 percent exclusion, real capital<br />

gains can be taxed at rates greater than those applied to ordinary<br />

income if the rate of inflation is sufficiently high. Moreover, under<br />

current law the effective tax rate on capital gains varies<br />

tremendously with the inflation rate.<br />

In addition to compensating poorly <strong>for</strong> the effects of inflation,<br />

the current exclusion of 60 percent of long-term nominal capital gains<br />

effectively overtaxes taxpayers who have little or no investment<br />

success (since sufficiently small nominal gains are actually capital<br />

losses), <strong>and</strong> it undertaxes very successful investors (since the<br />

exclusion overcompensates <strong>for</strong> inflation <strong>for</strong> sufficiently large gains).<br />

This treatment is clearly inequitable.<br />

The Treasury Department proposes that the tax treatment of capital<br />

gains be rationalized by making a precise adjustment <strong>for</strong> inflation<br />

through indexing the basis of capital assets <strong>for</strong> the inflation which<br />

has occurred since purchase of the asset or January 1, 1965, whichever<br />

is later. Since roughly 84 percent of the inflation during the<br />

postwar period has occurred since 1964, this will result in nearly<br />

complete inflation adjustment <strong>for</strong> almost all assets, while limiting<br />

the size of the table of inflation adjustment factors. Inflationadjusted<br />

gains will be taxed as ordinary income at the proposed<br />

reduced individual rates; that is, the current 60 percent exclusion<br />

would be repealed.<br />

In order to limit the transition problems associated with an<br />

unexpected change to the new system of taxing indexed capital gains as<br />

ordinary income, indexing of assets held as of the date of enactment<br />

will be delayed until 1989 <strong>and</strong> the current approach to taxing capital<br />

gains on those assets will be maintained through 1988. (That is,<br />

nominal gains will be taxed at a maximum rate of roughly 20 percent<br />

through 1988). Assets acquired after enactment, however, will be<br />

subject to indexing under the new tax rules as of the date of<br />

acquisition.<br />

The existing preferential tax treatment of capital gains has been<br />

justified by the need to avoid taxing fictitious gains that merely<br />

reflect inflation, to stimulate investments in risky undertakings, to<br />

avoid applying highly progressive rates to gains bunched in one year,<br />

<strong>and</strong> to prevent investors from having investments in appreciated assets<br />

"locked in" by the tax system. The effects of the Treasury Department<br />

proposal in each of these problem areas will be examined in turn.<br />

Inflation adjustment. The current exclusion of 60 percent of<br />

long-term capital gains is a very rough way of allowing <strong>for</strong> the<br />

effects of inflation. At high rates of inflation it is inadequate,<br />

but at low rates it is too generous.


- 102 -'<br />

In contrast with the current ad hoc adjustment <strong>for</strong> inflation, the<br />

proposed adjustment will be precise. At current cates of inflation<br />

(4.0 percent in 1983 <strong>and</strong> 1984), most taxpayers will be subject to<br />

roughly the same effective tax rate on long-term capital gains as<br />

under current law (preferential taxation of nominal capital gains at a<br />

maximum 20 percent rate). At rates of inflation experienced in recent<br />

years (an average annual rate of 7.9 percent between 1972 <strong>and</strong> 1982),<br />

the proposal will significantly reduce the effective tax rate on real<br />

capital gains. This is shown by Table 6-1, which provides maximum<br />

effective tax rates on real capital gains under current law <strong>for</strong><br />

various combinations of inflation rates, rates of real appreciation,<br />

<strong>and</strong> holding periods. In each part of the table, effective rates below<br />

the broken line are higher than the 35 percent maximum rate on<br />

ordinary income proposed in this Report; only the current law effective<br />

rates above the broken line are less than this proposed rate.<br />

Only <strong>for</strong> assets held <strong>for</strong> very long periods is current law likely<br />

to be preferred to the proposed 35 percent rate on real gains. If,<br />

<strong>for</strong> example, the real rate of appreciation is 4 percent <strong>and</strong> the inflation<br />

rate is 4 percent or more, a tax rate of 20 percent applied to<br />

nominal gains produces an effective rate in excess of 35 percent,<br />

except <strong>for</strong> assets held 10 years or longer. The story is only slightly<br />

different if the real rate of appreciation is a rather high 7 percent<br />

per year. At an inflation rate of 5 to 7 percent, current law<br />

produces effective tax rates on gains on assets held <strong>for</strong> less than 5<br />

years that do not differ greatly from 35 percent.<br />

Although current inflation rates are relatively low, the<br />

"insurance" benefits of a tax system which guarantees an explicit<br />

inflation adjustment should not be minimized, For example, inflation<br />

averaged I percent per year between 1971 <strong>and</strong> 1975. Over that period,<br />

nominal capital gains on sales of corporate stock totaled $24.6<br />

billion. However, once adjusted <strong>for</strong> inflation, these sales actually<br />

represented a loss of $0.4 billion. Similarly, reported nominal gains<br />

on sales of real estate over the same period totaled $13.2 billion,<br />

while the inflation-adjusted gain was only $5.3 billion. The 50<br />

percent exclusion rate in effect during that period clearly was far<br />

from adequate in terms of allowing <strong>for</strong> inflation. Indeed, no<br />

exclusion rate can make up <strong>for</strong> a negative real rate of appreciation.<br />

By comparison, under the Treasury Department proposal, the<br />

inflationary component of nominal capital gains will always be<br />

excluded from the tax base. The associated reduction in variation in<br />

effective tax rates caused by inflation should stimulate investment in<br />

capital assets. Thus, the Treasury Department believes that with<br />

inflation indexing, reduced tax rates, <strong>and</strong> a rate structure with only<br />

a few wide income brackets there is no need <strong>for</strong> preferential tax<br />

treatment of realized capital gains, beyond that provided by the<br />

substantial benefits of deferral of tax until gains are realized <strong>and</strong><br />

the exemption of gains on assets transferred at death.<br />

Effect on risk-taking. The effect of capital gains taxation on<br />

private risk-taking in the economy is of critical importance. Venture<br />

capital <strong>and</strong> associated high-technology industries seem particularly


- 103 -<br />

Table 6-1 <br />

Effective <strong>Tax</strong> Rates on Realized Capital Gains <br />

Under Current Law <strong>for</strong> 50 Percent Bracket <strong>Tax</strong>payer<br />

With Different Real Rate of Return Assumptions<br />

Inflation<br />

Rate<br />

APercent)<br />

: Nominal<br />

:Appreciation : Holding Period in Years :<br />

Rate<br />

: (Percent) : 1 : 3 : 5 : 10 : 20 :<br />

CONSTANT 4<br />

PERCENT REAL RATE OF RETURN<br />

0<br />

2<br />

3<br />

4<br />

6<br />

8<br />

10<br />

12<br />

0<br />

2<br />

4<br />

5<br />

6<br />

7<br />

8<br />

10<br />

12<br />

4<br />

6<br />

7<br />

8<br />

10<br />

12<br />

14<br />

16<br />

CONSTANT 7<br />

7<br />

9<br />

11<br />

12<br />

13<br />

14<br />

15<br />

17<br />

19<br />

20.0<br />

30.0<br />

--_-I<br />

35.01<br />

I<br />

40.0<br />

50.0<br />

60.0<br />

70.0<br />

80.0<br />

20.0 20.0 20.0 20.0<br />

29.4 28.9 27.7 25.6<br />

34.0 33.1 31.0 27.8<br />

-I_-_------<br />

38.5 37.1<br />

47.3 44.9<br />

55.9 52.0<br />

64.0 58.8<br />

71.9 65.1<br />

34.1 29.6<br />

----_ I<br />

39.71 32.5<br />

I<br />

44.5) 34.7<br />

--------<br />

48.6 36.3<br />

52.1 37.6<br />

PERCENT REAL RATE OF RETURN<br />

20.0 20.0 20.0 20.0 20.0<br />

25.7 25.2 24.9 23.8 22.4<br />

31.4 30.3 29.1 27.1 24.1<br />

34.3 32.8 31.4 28.5 24.7<br />

--______-I<br />

37.1 35.21 I 33.4 29.9 25.3<br />

I ----_I<br />

40.0 37.5 35.41 31.1 25.8<br />

42.9 39.9 37.31 I 32.2 26.3<br />

I<br />

48.6 44.5 41.0) I<br />

34.4<br />

I<br />

27.0<br />

54.3 48.9 44.4 36.31 27.6<br />

Note: Figures in bold face type below the broken line indicate<br />

combinations of inflation rates <strong>and</strong> holding periods <strong>for</strong> which the<br />

proposed treatment is more favorable than current law.


- 104 -<br />

sensitive to changes in effective tax rates. The supply of venture<br />

capital largely dried up during the 1970s when effective tax rates on<br />

real gains were high due to inflation <strong>and</strong> other provisions in the<br />

Code, but revived dramatically after the 1978 <strong>and</strong> 1981 tax changes<br />

reduced the maximum tax rate on realized long-term capital gains to 20<br />

percent <strong>and</strong> inflation rates fell significantly from earlier levels.<br />

In light of this experience, the likely effects of the proposed<br />

treatment of capital gains m the supply of venture capital <strong>and</strong> "high<br />

technology" industries are of particular interest. <strong>Tax</strong>ing real<br />

(indexed) capital gains at a maximum ordinary income rate of 35<br />

percent will result in a greater tax burden on the most successful<br />

investments made by venture capitalists. If one assumes safficiently<br />

high rates of return <strong>and</strong> moderate rates of inflation, indexing <strong>for</strong><br />

inflation, even over the approximately 7 to 10-year life of the<br />

average venture capital investment, will not be as generous as the 60<br />

percent exclusion. Some argue that this treatment, even if desirable<br />

on equity grounds, will unduly inhibit investment in the high<br />

technology industries typically funded by venture capitalists.<br />

The basic principle underlying the Treasury Department proposals<br />

-- that all income should be taxed equally -- suggests that the<br />

taxation of real capital gains as ordinary income is the appropriate<br />

policy <strong>for</strong> all industries, including the venture capital industry.<br />

Perhaps more importantly, the Treasury Department believes the<br />

proposed treatment of capital gains is unlikely to have significantly<br />

negative effects on these industries. Several arguments can be made<br />

to support this position. More accurate measurement of economic<br />

losses <strong>and</strong> reduced variation in effective tax rates resulting from<br />

inflation will stimulate all investment, including investment in the<br />

venture capital <strong>and</strong> high technology industries.<br />

Moreover, a maximum marginal tax rate of 35 percent on indexed<br />

capital gains will produce effective rates that are not substantially<br />

above those experienced during the last two venture capital booms.<br />

(Rates of 25 percent during the 1960s <strong>and</strong> 28 percent from 1978-81 on<br />

nominal gains were actually higher effective rates due to inflation.)<br />

Such an environment should be favorable to risky venture capital<br />

investments.<br />

Also, the increase in saving stimulated by reductions in individual<br />

marginal rates <strong>and</strong> expansion of IRAs, as well as the elimination<br />

of many industry-specific tax preferences coupled with the<br />

enactment of measures to reduce the advantages of investment in<br />

unproductive tax shelters, should increase the supply of capital<br />

available to high technology industries. Finally, roughly one-half of<br />

the funds committed to so-called venture capital firms come from taxexempt<br />

entities, such as pension funds, endowments, <strong>and</strong> foundations,<br />

or from <strong>for</strong>eign investors. To the extent that these are equity funds,<br />

their supply will not be affected by changes in the tax treatment of<br />

capital gains. For these reasons, the Treasury Department believes


- 105 -<br />

that taxation of indexed capital gains as ordinary income is unlikely<br />

to have significantly negative effects on the supply of venture<br />

capital to high-technology industries.<br />

Other issues. Implementation of the Treasury Department proposal<br />

will. have little effect on effective capital gains tax rates at<br />

moderate rates of inflation, <strong>and</strong> will significantly reduce effective<br />

rates at high rates of inflation. While the proposed treatment will<br />

have little effect on lock-in <strong>and</strong> bunching problems at moderate rates<br />

of inflation, it will mitigate them considerably at high rates of<br />

inflation, when they are most serious.<br />

Simplification. <strong>Tax</strong>ing real (inflation-adjusted) capital gains as<br />

ordinary income will complicate the tax system in some respects but,<br />

on balance, should result in simplification. Adjusting the basis of<br />

assets <strong>for</strong> inflation will result in some complexity, but taxpayers<br />

will not need to per<strong>for</strong>m overly complex calculations since they will<br />

derive the applicable adjustment from a table. On the other h<strong>and</strong>,<br />

significant simplification will result from eliminating the distinction<br />

between capital gains <strong>and</strong> ordinary income, including repeal of<br />

recapture rules as well as the extremely complicated collapsible<br />

partnership <strong>and</strong> corporation provisions. Real gains from the sale of<br />

most assets will simply be taxed in the same way as all other income.<br />

Many elaborate schemes designed to obtain capital gains treatment <strong>for</strong><br />

ordinary income will lose much of their attraction; as a result, fewer<br />

resources will be wasted in tax planning activities as well as in<br />

auditing returns with questionab1,e conversion schemes. Once the<br />

proposed new tax treatment of business income is fully phased-in <strong>and</strong><br />

a11 (or most) gr<strong>and</strong>fathered assets are out of the system, the<br />

corporate minimum tax could be repealed.<br />

6. Capital Consumption Allowances<br />

The investment tax credit (ITC) <strong>and</strong> the accelerated cost recovery<br />

system (ACRS) were introduced during a period of rapid inflation to<br />

stimulate investment by preventing capital consumption allowances<br />

based on historical cost from being eroded by inflation. Without<br />

explicit indexing of depreciation allowances, the effects of rapid<br />

inflation on the return to investment in depreciable assets are so<br />

deleterious that something like ACRS <strong>and</strong> the ITC was essential to<br />

prevent confiscatory taxation of income from capital. Under the<br />

Treasury Department proposal, ad hoc accelerated capital recovery<br />

allowances like the combination of ITC <strong>and</strong> ACRS would be unnecessary;<br />

explicit indexing <strong>for</strong> inflation would ensure that future depreciation<br />

allowances would maintain their real value, regardless of the rate of<br />

inflation.<br />

Since current rates of inflation are significantly lower than<br />

those prevailing when the ITC <strong>and</strong> ACRS were enacted, current law<br />

allows investment in depreciable assets to be recovered far more<br />

rapidly than under a neutral system of income taxation. Table 6-2<br />

indicates the effective tax rates applied to income from various types


- 106 -<br />

of assets under current law; the figures apply to equity-financed<br />

investments by corporate taxpayers subject to the 46 percent statutory<br />

rate, <strong>for</strong> inflation rates between 0 <strong>and</strong> 10 percent.<br />

As shown dramatically in Table 6-2, the combination of ACRS <strong>and</strong><br />

the ITC results in a system where, at the rates of inflation covered<br />

by the table, effective tax rates are lower than statutory rates but<br />

vary, often significantly, with the rate of inflation. For example,<br />

at an inflation rate of 5 percent, the effective tax rates paid by a<br />

taxpayer subject to a 46 percent statutory rate vary from -8 percent<br />

<strong>for</strong> equipment with a 3 year ACRS life to 40 percent <strong>for</strong> a structure<br />

with an 18 year ACiiS life. (A negative tax rate is the equivalent of<br />

the Federal Government paying a business to buy the asset <strong>and</strong> earn<br />

income tax-free.) Effective tax rates are lower, (that is, even more<br />

negative), <strong>for</strong> short-lived assets with lower inflation rates. At<br />

higher inflation rates such as those prevailing at the time of<br />

enactment of ACRS, effective tax rates are somewhat closer to the<br />

statutory tax rate, especially <strong>for</strong> longer-lived asset. (See Table 6-2<br />

<strong>for</strong> effective tax rates under an inflation rate of 10 percent.)<br />

The current system is obviously deeply flawed, since effective tax<br />

rates vary tremendously among asset types <strong>and</strong> with inflation.<br />

Moreover, by reducing effective tax rates below the statutory rate,<br />

the tax system favors investment in depreciable assets such as<br />

equipment <strong>and</strong> real estate over investments in labor <strong>and</strong> in inventories.<br />

This results in effective tax rates which vary widely among<br />

industries, as demonstrated in Table 6-3.<br />

Nevertheless, returning to the non-indexed economic depreciation<br />

of the pre-ACRS period is clearly unacceptable; the high effective tax<br />

rates on business plant <strong>and</strong> equipment during the 1970s that resulted<br />

from the failure to allow tax-free recovery of the real cost of<br />

capital reduced investment <strong>and</strong> economic growth. Instead, the Treasury<br />

Department proposes that the investment tax credit be repealed, that<br />

the basis of depreciable assets be indexed <strong>for</strong> inflation, <strong>and</strong> that<br />

depreciation allowances <strong>for</strong> tax purposes be set to approximate real<br />

economic depreciation. A combination of indexing <strong>for</strong> inflation <strong>and</strong><br />

economic depreciation -- a Real Cost Recovery System, or RCRS -- will<br />

retain, <strong>and</strong> even reduce, the effective tax rates <strong>for</strong> depreciable<br />

assets that are present in the ACRS system, reduce the uncertainty<br />

about future changes in effective tax rates that occur without indexed<br />

depreciation, <strong>and</strong> eliminate the current tax bias toward investment in<br />

depreciable assets.<br />

The enactment of the Treasury Department proposal will have four<br />

very significant advantages over current law. First, the benefits of<br />

economic neutrality will be realized. Effective tax rates on<br />

depreciable as-ets will no longer vary according to asset life, as<br />

depreciation a lowarices will be approximately equal to the real<br />

economic depreciation of assets. Effective tax rates will also no<br />

longer vary actoss industries, as investment in all industries will<br />

face the same reduced corporate tax rate. As a result of tax<br />

treatment which is economically neutral, the allocation of the<br />

nation's scarce resources will be greatly improved.


- 107 -<br />

Table 6-2<br />

Effective <strong>Tax</strong> Rates on Equity-Financed Investments<br />

with various Rates of Inflation <strong>for</strong> a 46 Percent <strong>Tax</strong>payer<br />

Under Current Law -1/<br />

Asset class<br />

(years) 0<br />

Inflation<br />

5<br />

Rate<br />

3 -90 -0 22<br />

5 Equipment -51 -3 19<br />

10 -5 20 32<br />

15 9 35 45<br />

Structures<br />

18 28 40 45<br />

10<br />

Cpercent)<br />

-1/ Assumptions: Real return after tax is 4 percent. The investment<br />

credit rate selected is the maximum allowable (6 percent on 3-year<br />

equipment <strong>and</strong> 10 percent on 5-, lo-, <strong>and</strong> 15-year equipment).<br />

Effective tax rates are the difference between the real be<strong>for</strong>e tax<br />

rate of return <strong>and</strong> the real after-tax rate of return divided by<br />

the be<strong>for</strong>e-tax rate of return.


- 108 -<br />

Table 6-3<br />

Effective <strong>Tax</strong> aates on Equity Financed Investments in Equipment<br />

<strong>and</strong> Structures by Industry with Various Rates of Inflation<br />

<strong>for</strong> a 46 Percent <strong>Tax</strong>payer Under Current Law<br />

Industry<br />

Agriculture<br />

Mining<br />

Logging<br />

Wood products <strong>and</strong> furniture<br />

Glass, cement <strong>and</strong> clay<br />

Primary metals<br />

Fabricated metals<br />

Machinery <strong>and</strong> instruments<br />

Electrical equipment<br />

Motor vehicles<br />

Transportation equipment<br />

Food<br />

Tobacco<br />

Textiles<br />

Appa r e 1<br />

Pulp <strong>and</strong> paper<br />

Printing <strong>and</strong> publishing<br />

Chemicals<br />

Petroleum refining<br />

Rubber<br />

Leather<br />

Transport services<br />

Utilities<br />

Communications<br />

Service <strong>and</strong> trade<br />

Inflation Rate (percent)<br />

5 10<br />

29 37<br />

13 31<br />

21 34<br />

28 38<br />

20 31<br />

16 28<br />

28 38<br />

26 36<br />

26 38<br />

8 26<br />

25 36<br />

25 35<br />

18 30<br />

19 32<br />

28 38<br />

12 26<br />

22 34<br />

19 32<br />

12 26<br />

18 30<br />

30 40<br />

9 26<br />

2e 38<br />

19 33<br />

31 40<br />

Office of the Secretary of Treasury<br />

Office of <strong>Tax</strong> Analysis<br />

November 24, 1984


- 109 -<br />

Second, effective tax rates will no longer vary with the rate of<br />

inflation. Businesses planning investments will be assured that the<br />

value of future depreciation allowances will be automatically<br />

corrected <strong>for</strong> inflation; they will not have to depend on Congress <strong>for</strong><br />

periodic ad hoc <strong>and</strong> imperfect adjustments in tax laws to accomplish<br />

this correction. The reduced uncertainty implied by enactment of the<br />

Treasury Department proposals should stimulate investment in all<br />

industries.<br />

Third, capital recovery allowances will no longer be "frontloaded,"<br />

or accelerated to the early years of the productive life of<br />

an investment. Because the advantages of the ITC <strong>and</strong> ACRS are frontloaded,<br />

these provisions are of relatively little value to new <strong>and</strong><br />

rapidly growing firms or to firms i n ailing industries, neither of<br />

which can fully utilize their benefits. The Treasury Department<br />

proposal would thus eliminate a tax penalty faced by new firms <strong>and</strong><br />

would eliminate incentives <strong>for</strong> tax-motivated mergers. @he result will<br />

be increased competitiveness <strong>and</strong> more incentive <strong>for</strong> innovation. Also,<br />

elimination of front-loading of tax benefits will reduce the<br />

advantages of tax shelters, many of which are abusive <strong>and</strong> create<br />

severe administrative burdens <strong>for</strong> the Internal Revenue Service.<br />

Fourth, these re<strong>for</strong>ms will broaden the corporate tax base, just as<br />

many re<strong>for</strong>ms in the individual income taxation area broaden the<br />

individual tax base. The most important effect in the corporate area<br />

is that the maximum corporate tax rate will be reduced from 46 to 33<br />

percent.<br />

The new method <strong>for</strong> taxing business income proposed by the Treasury<br />

Department is best appraised by examining the combined tax burden at<br />

the corporate <strong>and</strong> individual levels, in order to reflect the benefits<br />

of the dividend-paid deduction. Table 6-4 presents combined effective<br />

tax rates <strong>for</strong> a variety of alternative ways of taxing income from<br />

depreciable assets <strong>and</strong> inventories. Under the Treasury Department<br />

proposal the combined effective tax rate is 44 percent, regardless of<br />

the rate of inflation. This is substantially more generous than the<br />

tax treatment under ACRS, without the ITC or dividend relief, which at<br />

an inflation rate of 5 percent, produces a combined effective tax rate<br />

of about 58 percent. At an inflation rate of 10 percent the Treasury<br />

Department proposal is more generous than ACRS, even with the ITC.<br />

Even at an inflation rate of 5 percent, it is more favorable than<br />

current law, except <strong>for</strong> investment i n equipment.<br />

Table 6-5 shows effective tax rates at only the corporate level.<br />

The Treasury Department proposal <strong>for</strong> a Real Cost Recovery System<br />

produces approximately the same effective tax rate on income from all<br />

<strong>for</strong>ms of investment, while the alternative approaches produce widely<br />

varying effective rates that depend on the rate of inflation.<br />

C. Inventories<br />

Under current law, taxpayers are allowed two basic options in<br />

calculating the cost of goods sold from inventories. They can either


Pre1981 b y<br />

- 110 -<br />

Table 6-4<br />

Effective Caprate <strong>and</strong> Rrsanal In- <strong>Tax</strong> btes cn Wey F-4 Invesbrents<br />

-R2hirns to Capital D i s t r W m l y -been Dividerds ad capital Gzim-l/<br />

Wmt<br />

an3<br />

RU capital stmtures Structures Invrntories<br />

at 10 p-t inflation 63 63 51 66 61<br />

i m ?/<br />

With invffibrent tax credit<br />

at 10 pr-t inflation 58 57 43 61 61<br />

at 5 p rmt inRation 53 50 26 56 61<br />

Withwt invffihrerit tax credit<br />

at 5 p-t inflation 58 57 57 56 61<br />

Redl emnonic ckpreiation 6/<br />

Withwt divided relief z/ 49 49 49 49 49<br />

With divii3?& relief %/ 44 44 44 44 44<br />

Office of tk -kretary of t2E Reasury W&r 21, 1984<br />

Mfice of <strong>Tax</strong> nnalysis<br />

-1/ Assures a 4 prmt real retum efter mwrate tax. Assures tm-thirds of capital gains<br />

deferred idefinitely, an3 the rerJiniw third tax& at th saw effective tax rate (35%)<br />

m 4 gain in order to eliminate any prssible bias against current law, tfcause the<br />

effective tax rate on capital gains der current Lw d e w M tk interrelaticwhip<br />

te- Wion, real appreciaticn, <strong>and</strong> t2E blding pricd.<br />

-2/ Nl capital inclui2s equipmiit, structures an3 inventories.<br />

-3/ Ass- LI170 amwntjlq with M reduction in inventories aid inventory prim rising with<br />

t t ~Wral price level.<br />

-4/ Assures 46 pr-t mprate statutory tax rate an3 45 pmt personal tax rate<br />

urder current law. Fssuns sun of years digits ckpreciatiwi mer 9 yevs <strong>and</strong> 10 praent<br />

invsbt credit <strong>for</strong> quiprent an3 150 pxoent asll- Mane over a 34.4 year average<br />

life <strong>for</strong> structUrE5.<br />

-5/ Assures 46 praent mprate tax rate an3 45 prcent prsonal tax rate. Ass- 5ys%<br />

depreciatim schaule with half-basis aijusbrent <strong>for</strong> equi-t an3 18- &de <strong>for</strong><br />

sttuzbres.<br />

-6/ Assirrej 33 p rmt mprate rate <strong>and</strong> 35 pmt prsaral rate m?er re<strong>for</strong>m. <strong>Tax</strong><br />

depreci3tion rates assured epzd to econcmic &prpCgiaticn rats. Bviations m y slightly<br />

alter tax rates.<br />

-l/ Effective tax rates are overstated. In a revenw wutml props&,<br />

relief muld inply lcwer statutory tax rats.<br />

-8/ pss- 50 pmnt mrprate deduction <strong>for</strong> fet divided pia.<br />

elhhticn of divided


- 111 -<br />

assume that the first goods put into inventory are the first ones out<br />

(FIFO), or they can assume that the last goods in are the first ones<br />

out ( LIFO). Roughly 95 percent of firms with inventories use FIFO<br />

accounting <strong>for</strong> tax purposes. In an inflationary period the use of<br />

FiFO overstates current taxable i,ncome,because the deduction <strong>for</strong> cost<br />

of goods sold is based on lower prices that prevailed earlier. Nonetheless,<br />

many firms are dissuaded from switching to LIFO by, among<br />

other considerations, the "LIFO con<strong>for</strong>mity requirement," which<br />

specifies that if LIFO is used <strong>for</strong> tax purposes it also must also be<br />

used <strong>for</strong> financial accounting. The overstatement of'taxable income<br />

that results from the use of FIFO under inflationary conditions<br />

implies t.hat the tax system imposes a penalty on inventory-intensive<br />

activities.<br />

The important role of inventories in the economy is often overlooked.<br />

Inventories account <strong>for</strong> approximately one-fifth of corporate<br />

non-financial assets, <strong>and</strong> more than one-third of corporate depreciable<br />

assets. For many types of industries, particularly the wholesale <strong>and</strong><br />

retail trade <strong>and</strong> service industries, inventories are more important<br />

than depreciable assets. (See Table 6-6.) Thus, in a system which<br />

indexes depreciation allowances <strong>and</strong> capital gains, indexing inventories<br />

is essential <strong>for</strong> economic neutrality across types of business<br />

assets <strong>and</strong> across industries.<br />

The Treasury Department suggests repeal of the LIFO con<strong>for</strong>mity<br />

requirement since it induces many firms to use accounting practices in<br />

calcuiating taxable income that seriously mismeasure income during<br />

inflationary periods; it is an anachronism that has no counterpart in<br />

other parts of the tax law.<br />

In addition, the Treasury Department proposes that firms be given<br />

the option of employing indexed FIFO, instead of either LIFO or<br />

unindexed FIFO. Under indexed FIFO, the value of all goods in<br />

inventory will be adjusted (written up or down) <strong>for</strong> the amount of<br />

inflation that has occurred since their acquisition. Thus, since<br />

inflationary gains are permanently removed from the tax base, indexed<br />

FIFO measures income more accurately than does LIFO, where<br />

inflationary gains are only deferred until the firm reduces its<br />

inventory or liquidates. Also, indexed FIFO is thought to be somewhat<br />

simpler than LIFO. Adoption of indexed FIFO will not be m<strong>and</strong>atory,<br />

however .<br />

D. Indexing Interest<br />

Nominal interest rates include an inflation premium that<br />

compensates lenders <strong>for</strong> the loss of principal. Under current law,<br />

interest income <strong>and</strong> expense are overstated during a time of inflation,<br />

since nominal interest receipts are fully taxable <strong>and</strong> nominal interest<br />

payments are fully deductible. As a result, interest income is overtaxed<br />

during an inflationary period, <strong>and</strong> saving is discouraged; similarly,<br />

borrowing <strong>and</strong> debt finance are encouraged. A completely<br />

inflation-adjusted tax system wouid exclude the inflationary component<br />

of nominal interest rates from taxation.


- 112 -<br />

W<br />

-3<br />

m<br />

v)<br />

7.-<br />

m<br />

m<br />

P'


- 113 -<br />

---<br />

Wle 6-6<br />

Inventories as Percent of 'Ibtal Physical &sets ad Cepreciable Assets<br />

: Inventories as Percent of Total:<br />

. pfivsical : Net Dwreciable<br />

&piculture<br />

Mining<br />

Construction<br />

Manufacturing<br />

Transportation<br />

Wholesale Trade<br />

Retail Trade<br />

Finance, Real<br />

Estate<br />

Srvies<br />

14.3 % 31.7%<br />

9.1 18.1<br />

34.8 87.5<br />

29.2 54.3<br />

5.1 5.6<br />

61.2 216.5<br />

50.9 135.3<br />

3.8 11.7<br />

10.1 14.5<br />

motdl<br />

22.4% 39.3%<br />

Office of the Secretarv of the Treasury November 21, 1984<br />

IJ<br />

Physical assets include inventories, net depreciable, depletable, <strong>and</strong> intangible<br />

assets, l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> other non-financial assets.<br />

Source: 1981 Statistics of Incane Corporate Incane <strong>Tax</strong> Returns.


- 114 -<br />

Perfect adjustment of debt or interest <strong>for</strong> inflation would require<br />

that lenders receive an annual deduction <strong>for</strong> each outst<strong>and</strong>ing loan<br />

equal to the product of the inflation rate <strong>and</strong> the principal of the<br />

loan; borrowers would report an offsetting amount of taxable income on<br />

each loan. Such an approach would be extremely complicated, <strong>and</strong> thus<br />

is not recommended. The Treasury Department does, however, propose a<br />

rough surrogate <strong>for</strong> an exact inflation adjustment. Under this<br />

proposal a given fraction of interest income will be excluded from<br />

tax, <strong>and</strong> the deduction of interest expense (in excess of the sum of<br />

mortgage interest attributable to the principal residence of an<br />

individual taxpayer <strong>and</strong> $5,000) will be reduced by the same fraction.<br />

Corporations will also exclude this fraction of interest income or<br />

expense.<br />

The fraction of interest income <strong>and</strong> expense to be excluded will be<br />

set to reflect the approximate relationship between the current inflation<br />

rate <strong>and</strong> the long-run real interest rate. In an ideal world, the<br />

exclusion rate that would result in accurate measurement of real<br />

interest income <strong>and</strong> expense would equal the ratio of the inflation<br />

rate to the nominal rate. This relationship was used in calculating<br />

Table 6-7, which provides the proposed relationship between inflation<br />

<strong>and</strong> the exclusion rate; these results are based on the conservative<br />

assumption of a 6 percent real interest rate (a lower real interest<br />

rate would result in higher exclusion rates). The exclusion rate to<br />

be used in calculating interest income <strong>and</strong> expense will be announced<br />

each year. Inflation will be measured by the percentage increase in<br />

the consumer price index (CPr) over the previous twelve months. ~ f ,<br />

<strong>for</strong> example, the CPI increases by 4 percent, 40 percent of nominal net<br />

interest income will not be taxed.<br />

The proposed approach provides only a rough adjustment <strong>for</strong><br />

inflation. Although the inflation adjustment will not be exact most<br />

of the time, it will clearly be more appropriate than the zeroinflation<br />

assumption implicit in the current law's treatment of all<br />

nominal interest as taxable income or deductible expense.<br />

As long as neither interest receipts nor interest payments are<br />

indexed, lenders will be taxed too heavily <strong>and</strong> borrowers too lightly.<br />

This tax treatment accentuates the incentive under the current<br />

progressive rate structure <strong>for</strong> low-bracket taxpayers to acquire<br />

interest-bearing assets <strong>and</strong> avoid borrowing, while high-bracket taxpayers<br />

borrow <strong>and</strong> avoid interest-bearing assets. Moreover, these<br />

undesirable distortions of behavior would be accentuated if<br />

depreciation deductions <strong>and</strong> capital gains are indexed but interest<br />

receipts <strong>and</strong> payments are not. Investors in high tax brackets would<br />

have a strong incentive to out-bid other investors <strong>for</strong> borrowed funds<br />

in order to finance the acquisition of depreciable assets <strong>and</strong> assets<br />

expected to yield indexed capital gains. These incentives will be<br />

mitigated under a system with fractional exclusion of interest<br />

receipts <strong>and</strong> expenses. As a result, high-bracket investors will have<br />

less incentive to borrow <strong>and</strong> a stronger incentive to equity-finance<br />

their acquisition of assets. In addition, interest indexing will


- 115 -<br />

Tabla 6-1 <br />

Fractional Exclusion Rate Table <br />

Constant Reel Be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>Tax</strong> Rata of Return of 6 Percent<br />

Inflation : Isominal : opt inal<br />

Rate : Interest : Exclusion<br />

.(pi).. : Rate (%) Rate (%)<br />

0 G 0 <br />

a 7 14 <br />

2 8 25 <br />

3 9 33 <br />

4 IO 00 <br />

5 11 45 <br />

6 12 50 <br />

7 13 54 <br />

8 14 57 <br />

9 15 60 <br />

10 16 62 <br />

11 17 65 <br />

12 18 67 <br />

Office of the Secretary November 21, 1904<br />

of the Treasury<br />

Office of <strong>Tax</strong> Analysis


- 116 -<br />

reduce the tax disadvantage of taxable debt relative to tax-exempt<br />

bonds. This in turn will make it easier <strong>and</strong> cheaper <strong>for</strong> other<br />

investors to obtain borrowed funds.<br />

IV. Retirement Savings<br />

By encouraging taxpayers to save <strong>for</strong> retirement, the tax-preferred<br />

treatment of retirement plans serves two important public purposes.<br />

It helps retirees accumulate funds so they can live out their lives in<br />

dignity without becoming wards of society, <strong>and</strong> it produces saving that<br />

can be made available <strong>for</strong> capital <strong>for</strong>mation. In the latter sense,<br />

tax-preferred retirement plans have much the same benefits as a<br />

consumed income tax, but without its other disadvantages (discussed<br />

more fully in chapter 9 ). The Treasury Department believes that the<br />

present tax incentives <strong>for</strong> such retirement plans should be retained<br />

but made more consistent. The retirement saving proposals should<br />

increase saving, provide greater protection <strong>for</strong> spouses, <strong>and</strong> simplify<br />

compliance <strong>and</strong> administration.<br />

Under current law, individual retirement plans (IRAs) are fully<br />

available only to those who are employed. Whereas an employee can<br />

contribute up to $2,000 per year tax-free on his or her own behalf,<br />

only an additional $250 can be contributed to a "spousal" IRA. The<br />

Treasury Department supports the Administration's proposal that IRAs<br />

be available on equal terms to spouses working in the home <strong>and</strong> in the<br />

market. Further, the Treasury Department proposes that the limits on<br />

an IRA be raised to $2,500 <strong>for</strong> both employees <strong>and</strong> those working at<br />

home, that is, to $5,000 <strong>for</strong> husb<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> wife. With the present<br />

limits, over one-half of tax returns with payments to IRAs showed<br />

maximum contributions; thus the availability of IRAS provided little<br />

incentive at the margin <strong>for</strong> additional saving. Increasing the limits<br />

will make this general saving incentive more effective.<br />

Employees of employers that maintain qualified cash or deferred<br />

arrangements (401(k) plans) effectively can avoid the IRA limitations<br />

of current law by making additional deductible contributions to these<br />

plans. The Treasury Department believes that this disparity among<br />

individuals is inappropriate <strong>and</strong> thus, coupled with increasing the<br />

limits on IRAs, proposes to repeal the current provisons that accord<br />

cash or deferred arrangements preferential tax treatment. Employers<br />

will be able to set up IRA plans <strong>for</strong> their employees, as under current<br />

law.<br />

I Other revisions are required to provide consistent treatment of<br />

various types of retirement plans. Under current law the tax<br />

treatment of both contributions to retirement plans <strong>and</strong> subsequent<br />

distributions may be different, depending upon the particular type of<br />

plan. The Treasury Department proposes to establish a consistent <strong>and</strong><br />

uni<strong>for</strong>m policy that will apply to all retirement plans. Certain early<br />

distributions to finance first-time purchases of homes <strong>and</strong> college<br />

education will be subject to a 10 percent tax; the tax will be raised<br />

to 20 percent <strong>for</strong> other early distributions.


- 117 -<br />

Current law contains annual limits on contributions <strong>and</strong> benefits<br />

that may be provided to an individual under an employer's tax-favored<br />

retirement plans. There are separate rules limiting contributions to<br />

two types of pension plans, those where a fixed contribution is<br />

required (defined contribution plans) <strong>and</strong> those that promise a fixed<br />

benefit (defined benefit plans). The defined contribution plan dollar<br />

limit, at $30,000 per year, is much more generous than the defined<br />

benefit limit, which allows deductions to finance future benefits of<br />

up to $90,000 per year. In addition, complex rules are required to<br />

limit contributions <strong>and</strong> benefits on behalf of employees who<br />

participate in both types of plans.<br />

The Treasury Department proposes to eliminate the overall limit<br />

<strong>for</strong> individuals participating in both defined contribution <strong>and</strong> defined<br />

benefit plans that provide significant benefits to rank-<strong>and</strong>-file<br />

employees. To replace the overall limit, <strong>and</strong> to limit the ability of<br />

an individual to accrue excessive benefits by working <strong>for</strong> separate<br />

employers, the Treasury Department proposes to apply an excise tax on<br />

extraordinary withdrawals made in any year from either type of plan.<br />

This <strong>and</strong> more specific re<strong>for</strong>ms will both simplify considerably the<br />

task of employers who must deal with the present complex rules <strong>and</strong><br />

provide greater rationality <strong>and</strong> consistency in this area.<br />

V. Neutrality Toward the Form of Bu6inees Organization<br />

Under present law, equity income originating in the corporate<br />

sector is taxed twice -- first as corporate profits <strong>and</strong> then as<br />

dividends. This double taxation of dividends, coupled with the<br />

deductibility of interest payments, discourages the use of equity<br />

finance <strong>and</strong> favors debt finance. Double taxation of dividends also<br />

discourages saving <strong>and</strong> discriminates against investment in the<br />

corporate sector. By comparison, opportunities <strong>for</strong> tax shelters, the<br />

benefits of which are usually most easily available through partnerships,<br />

artificially encourage the use of that <strong>for</strong>m of business<br />

organization.<br />

Between 1963 <strong>and</strong> 1982 the value of all partnership assets<br />

increased almost twelve-fold, from an estimated $71.8 billion in 1963<br />

to $845 billion in 1982. Assets owned by partnerships in the two most<br />

important <strong>and</strong> popular tax shelter industries, oil <strong>and</strong> gas drilling <strong>and</strong><br />

real estate, grew even more rapidly, increasing roughly sixteen-fold<br />

during the same period. By comparison, between 1963 <strong>and</strong> 1982 the<br />

value of corporate assets increased slightly more than six-fold, from<br />

$1.48 trillion to $9.1 trillion.<br />

The Treasury Department proposes several fundamental changes that<br />

will foster neutrality in the selection of organizational <strong>for</strong>m, <strong>and</strong> in<br />

the choice among alternative methods of finance. Without these<br />

changes, both corporations <strong>and</strong> partnerships would continue to rely too<br />

heavily on debt finance, the recent tax-induced shift of assets away<br />

from the corporate sector would continue, <strong>and</strong> tax administration would<br />

be needlessly difficult.


- iia -<br />

A. Relief <strong>for</strong> Double <strong>Tax</strong>ation of Dividends<br />

With a comprehensive corporate income tax base, income derived<br />

from equity investment in the corporate sector would be taxed twice --<br />

once when earned by a corporation <strong>and</strong> again when distributed to<br />

shareholders. The double taxation o f dividends has several<br />

undesirable effects. It encourages corporations to rely too heavily<br />

on debt rather than equity finance. By increasing the risk of<br />

bankruptcy, this artificial inducement <strong>for</strong> debt finance increases the<br />

incidence of bankruptcies during business downturns.<br />

The double taxation of dividends also creates an inducement <strong>for</strong><br />

firms to retain earnings, rather than pay them out as dividends.<br />

There is, however, no reason to believe that firms with retained<br />

earnings are necessarily those with the best investment opportunities.<br />

Instead, they may have more funds than they can invest productively,<br />

while new enterprises lack capital. If retained earnings are used to<br />

finance relatively low productivity investments, including uneconomic<br />

acquisitions of other firms, the quality of investment suffers. In<br />

addition, both corporate investment <strong>and</strong> aggregate saving are<br />

discouraged, because the double taxation of dividends increases the<br />

cost of capital to corporations <strong>and</strong> reduces the return to individual<br />

irivesto rs.<br />

These problems cannot be solved by simply eliminating the<br />

corporate income tax. If there were no corporate tax, dividends would<br />

be taxed properly, at the tax rates of the shareholders who receive<br />

them, but earnings retained by corporations would not be taxed until<br />

distributed, <strong>and</strong> thus would be allowed to accumulate tax-free. As a<br />

result, there would be a substantial incentive to conduct business in<br />

corporate <strong>for</strong>m, in order to take advantage of these benefits of tax<br />

exemption <strong>and</strong> deferral.<br />

Nor can the corporate <strong>and</strong> individual income taxes be fully<br />

integrated by treating the corporation as a partnership <strong>for</strong> tax<br />

purposes. Technical difficulties such as those described below<br />

preclude adoption of this approach. The Treasury Department thus<br />

proposes that the United States, following the practice of many other<br />

developed countries, continue to levy the corporate incom- tax on<br />

earnings that are retained, but provide partial relief from double<br />

taxation of dividends.<br />

There are two alternative ways to provide dividend relief. The<br />

approach more commonly employed in other countries is to allow<br />

shareholders a credit <strong>for</strong> a portion of the corporate tax attributable<br />

to the dividends they receive. The credit is generally available only<br />

to residents, although it is sometimes extended to <strong>for</strong>eigners by<br />

treaty. The credit can be denied tax-exempt organizations, if that is<br />

desired.<br />

The simpler method, an2 the one proposed by the Treasury<br />

Department, will allow corporations a deduction <strong>for</strong> dividends paid<br />

similar to the deduction or interest expense. Dividends paid to


- 119 -<br />

nonresident shareholders will be subject to a compensatory withholding<br />

tax, equivalent to the reduction in tax at the corporate level. The<br />

proposal will not impose such a compensatory tax where it would be<br />

contrary to a tJ.S. tax treaty; nor will the compensatory tax apply to<br />

dividends paid to U.S. tax-exempt organizations. However, the initial<br />

decision to extend the benefits of dividend relief to these two groups<br />

of shareholders will be subject to continuing review.<br />

Despite the advantages of full relief from double taxation of<br />

dividends, the Treasury Department proposal would provide a deduction<br />

cjf only one-half of dividends paid from income taxed to the<br />

corporation. This decision is based primarily on considerations of<br />

revenue loss, <strong>and</strong> can be reconsidered once the proposal is fully<br />

phased in.<br />

The deduction will not be allowed <strong>for</strong> dividenls paid from income<br />

that had not been subject to corporate tax; firms wishing to pay out<br />

tax-preferred income will not receive a deduction, but dividends will<br />

be presumed to be paid first from fully taxed income. For this<br />

purpose, income that did not bear a corporate tax because of allowable<br />

credits, including <strong>for</strong>eign tax credits, will not be eligible <strong>for</strong> the<br />

deduction.<br />

Reduction of the double taxation of corporate equity income will<br />

tend to increase initially the market value of existing corporate<br />

shares of companies that distribute an above-average proportion-of<br />

current earnings as dividends. It will reduce the current tax bias<br />

against equity finance in the corporate sector <strong>and</strong> make equity<br />

securities more competitive with debt. Because dividend relief will<br />

also reduce the tax bias against distributing earnings, corporations<br />

will be likely to pay greater dividends <strong>and</strong> to seek new funds in<br />

financial markets. Corporations will there<strong>for</strong>e, be more subject to<br />

the discipline of the marketplace <strong>and</strong> less likely to make relatively<br />

unproductive investments simply because they have available funds.<br />

Similarly, the pool of funds available to new firms with relatively<br />

high productivity investment opportunities will be larger. As a<br />

result, the productivity of investment should be improved<br />

substantially.<br />

Dividend relief will be phased in gradually in order to match the<br />

phase-in of the correct rules <strong>for</strong> measurement of corporate income <strong>and</strong><br />

to minimize unjusti.fied windfaLl profits to current shareholders.<br />

Moreover, phasing.in dividend relief will prevent a large loss of tax<br />

revenue <strong>and</strong> any associated reduction in the tax burden of high-income<br />

shareholders.<br />

The current exclusion from individual income taxation of $100 of<br />

dividends received serves no useful purpose <strong>and</strong> will be repealed<br />

immediately. It loses considerable revenue without stimulating<br />

significant investment in corporate equities. It would have no<br />

justification i n a system that allows dividend relief.


- 120 -<br />

8. <strong>Tax</strong> Treatment of Large Partnerships<br />

Large modern partnerships have many of the attributes commonly<br />

associated with corporations, especially when there is limited<br />

liability <strong>for</strong> most partners in the enterprise. The interests in some<br />

large partnerships are even traded on organized stock exchanges. Yet<br />

partnerships still benefit from preferential tax treatment that was<br />

more fitting in a simpler world in which partnerships were typically<br />

comprised of small groups of individuals, each of whom was responsible<br />

<strong>for</strong> the liabilities of the business.<br />

The main tax advantage of the partnership <strong>for</strong>m is that gains,<br />

losses <strong>and</strong> tax credits pass through to partners, rather than being<br />

taxed to the entity. Thus, unlike corporations who cannot benefit<br />

fully from tax credits, deductions <strong>for</strong> recovery of capital costs , <strong>and</strong><br />

interest expense if taxable income becomes negative, partnerships are<br />

able to pass any net operating losses through to partnet-s, who can use<br />

the losses to shelter other income from tax. AS a result, partnerships<br />

are an attractive vehicle <strong>for</strong> investment in tax shelter<br />

activities that initially may produce positive cash flow but result in<br />

losses <strong>for</strong> tax purposes; once the venture begins to show a profit <strong>for</strong><br />

tax purposes, it is converted to corporate <strong>for</strong>m or is sold so that<br />

deferred income is realized as tax-preferred 1.ong-term capital gains.<br />

Moreover, since debt finance magnifies the benefits of tax<br />

preferences, the tax Code encourages partnerships, as well as<br />

corporations, to rely too heavily on debt finance.<br />

Until the mid-l960s, the corporate <strong>for</strong>m of ownership was often<br />

considered the optimal way in which to hold large aggregations of<br />

assets. The corporation presented the advantages of both limited<br />

liabil-ity <strong>and</strong> a simple administrative vehicle <strong>for</strong> business transactions<br />

when large numbers of owners were involved. Because of the<br />

recent shift to the use of partnerships as tax shelters, however,<br />

ownership of more <strong>and</strong> more assets has been switched to partnership<br />

<strong>for</strong>m. In many cases, the assets are actually transferred from<br />

corporations, while in other cases, new businesses that normally would<br />

be <strong>for</strong>med as corporations are now established as partnerships.<br />

Pass-through treatment of large limited partnerships creates<br />

enormous administrative <strong>and</strong> compliance burdens <strong>for</strong> the Internal<br />

Revenue Service. Any time a partnership is audited <strong>and</strong> an adjustment<br />

is made, the tax liability of each partner must be adjusted. This<br />

process can be time consuming <strong>and</strong> expensive, as collection of additional<br />

tax can be required from hundreds of individual taxpayers, many<br />

of whom may have moved, died, or suffered substantial declines in<br />

income since the original partnership return was filed. Administrative<br />

problems such as these are among the reasons why the corporate<br />

<strong>and</strong> individual income taxes cannot be fully integrated by according<br />

corporations the pass-through treatment used <strong>for</strong> partnerships. In<br />

view of the problems encountered in .applying pass-through treatment to<br />

large partnerships with many partners, it is especially appropriate to<br />

tax large partnerships as corporations where they possess important<br />

characteristics of corporations, particularly the limited liability of


partners. *The recent proliferation of many such large partnerships<br />

suggests that the implications <strong>for</strong> tax administration of not doing so<br />

could be serious indeed.<br />

In order to restore competitive balance between the corporate <strong>and</strong><br />

partnership <strong>for</strong>ms of business organization, <strong>and</strong> to avoid these<br />

administrative problems, the Treasury Department proposes that large<br />

limited liability partnerships be subject to taxation as corporations.<br />

Losses of such entities will not pass through to partners, earnings<br />

retained by the partnership will be subject to tax at the entity<br />

level, <strong>and</strong> distributions of partnership earnings will qualify <strong>for</strong><br />

dividend relief. This proposal will reduce the interference of the<br />

tax law in the decision of whether to use the partnership or corporate<br />

<strong>for</strong>m <strong>for</strong> ventures in which many owners are involved. Current passthrough<br />

treatment is appropriate <strong>for</strong> those corporations <strong>and</strong><br />

partnerships that are truly mere economic extensions of their owners.<br />

Accordingly, so-called S corporations, limited partnerships with 35 or<br />

fewer limited partners, <strong>and</strong> general partnerships, including those with<br />

more than 35 partners, will continue to be accorded pass-through<br />

treatment.<br />

The Treasury Department’s proposals would promote greater<br />

neutrality in the choice of business organizational <strong>for</strong>m. Additional<br />

study should be devoted to the continuing differences in the taxation<br />

of corporations <strong>and</strong> partnerships of all sizes, <strong>and</strong> of ways to make the<br />

taxation of both <strong>for</strong>ms of business organization as consistent as<br />

possible. Such study also should consider the tax treatment of the<br />

trust entity <strong>and</strong> how to ensure that the use of trusts is limited to<br />

their traditional non-business functions.


- 123 -<br />

APPENDIX 6-A<br />

LIST OF PROPQSED REFORNS<br />

5ASIC TAXATION OF CAPITAL AND BUSINESS INCOME<br />

A. Lower Corporate <strong>Tax</strong> Rates<br />

1. Reduce maximum corporate rate to 33%.<br />

2. Repeal graduated corporate rate structure.<br />

3. Repeal personal holding company tax.<br />

5. <strong>Tax</strong>ing Real Economic Income<br />

1. Index basis (cost) of assets <strong>and</strong> tax real gains as ordinary<br />

income.<br />

2. Index depreciation <strong>for</strong> inflation <strong>and</strong> set depreciation allowances<br />

to approximate economic depreciation.<br />

3. Repeal investment tax credit.<br />

4. Repeal collapsible corporation rules.<br />

5. Allow expensing of the first $5,000 of depreciable business<br />

property, but repeal currently scheduled increases in that<br />

dollar limit.<br />

6. Allow indexed FIFO <strong>and</strong> repeal LIFO con<strong>for</strong>mity requirement.<br />

7. Index interest receipts <strong>and</strong> payments in excess of mortgage<br />

interest plus $5,000.<br />

C. Retirement Savings<br />

1. Raise IRA limits to $2,500.<br />

2. Make IRA’S available to both employees <strong>and</strong> spouses working in<br />

the home.<br />

3. Subject all tax-favored retirement plans to uni<strong>for</strong>m distribution<br />

rules.<br />

a. Subject all pre-retirement distributions from tax-favored<br />

retirement plans to a 20 percent premature distributions<br />

tax generally, (but 10 percent if used <strong>for</strong> tuition or<br />

first-home purchase).<br />

b. Subject all tax-favored retirement plans to uni<strong>for</strong>m minimum<br />

distribution rules.<br />

c. Repeal 10-year averaging <strong>for</strong> lump-sum distributions.<br />

d. Eliminate special - recovery rules <strong>for</strong> qualified plan dis­<br />

~<br />

tributions.<br />

e. Repeal special treatment <strong>for</strong> distributions of employer<br />

sekuritiGs.


-124-<br />

4. Simplify the deduction, contribution, <strong>and</strong> benefit limits <strong>for</strong><br />

tax-favored retirement plans.<br />

a. Repeal aggregate-based deduction limit <strong>for</strong> profit-sharing<br />

<strong>and</strong> stock bonus plans.<br />

b. Subject excess contributions to a 6 percent excise tax<br />

to recapture excessive tax benefits.<br />

c. Repeal combined plan limit <strong>for</strong> non-top-heavy plans.<br />

d. Subject all distributions in excess of $112,500 per year<br />

to a 10 percent excise tax.<br />

5. Miscellaneous changes.<br />

a. Extend deduction limits <strong>for</strong> tax-favored retirement plans<br />

to employee stock ownership plan <strong>and</strong> repeal the employee<br />

stock ownership plan credit.<br />

b. Repeal "cash or deferred arrangements."<br />

c. Subject reversions of funds from tax-favored retirement<br />

plans to employers to a 10 percent excise tax.<br />

D. Neutrality Toward the Form of Business Organization<br />

1. Reduce double taxation of distributed corporate earnings by<br />

allowing 50% dividends paid deduction. (Allow 50% dividendsceceived<br />

deduction <strong>for</strong> intercorporate dividends).<br />

2. Repeal $l00/$200 exclusion of dividend income.<br />

3. Require that all limited partnerships with more than 35<br />

limited partners be taxed as corporations.


- 125 -<br />

Chapter 7<br />

INDUSTRY-SPECIFIC SUBSIDIES, TAX SHELTERS, AND OTHER TAX ISSUES <br />

I. Introduction <br />

Over the course of the last 70 years, the income tax has been<br />

riddled by special tax preferences <strong>and</strong> subsidies <strong>for</strong> certain<br />

industries <strong>and</strong> activities. These special rules have no place in a<br />

comprehensive income tax. This chapter discusses the Treasury<br />

Department's proposals to modify or eliminate most of these subsidies.<br />

In addition, this chapter discusses proposals that will improve the<br />

rules <strong>for</strong> measuring income, require more consistent accounting of<br />

receipts <strong>and</strong> expenses, <strong>and</strong> further reduce the opportunities <strong>for</strong> tax<br />

she1ters.<br />

Two large sectors of the economy -- natural resources <strong>and</strong><br />

financial institutions -- have special tax rules that are inconsistent<br />

with both a comprehensive income tax <strong>and</strong> the goal of increased<br />

reliance on the market allocation of investment <strong>and</strong> saving. TO ensure<br />

that saving <strong>and</strong> investment in the economy are channeled to their most<br />

productive uses, these sectors should be accorded tax treatment<br />

similar to that of other businesses.<br />

The tax exemption of interest on debt of state <strong>and</strong> local governments<br />

is inconsistent with a comprehensive income tax. Nonetheless,<br />

to the extent that the exemption is confined to governmental activity,<br />

it has come to be an accepted part of the fiscal l<strong>and</strong>scape. In recent<br />

years, however, state <strong>and</strong> local governments have exp<strong>and</strong>ed the use of<br />

tax-exempt bonds in ways which are often abusive <strong>and</strong> which compete<br />

directly with both government purpose issues of State <strong>and</strong> local<br />

governments <strong>and</strong> private financial intermediation. The proposal will<br />

repeal the use of tax-exempt bonds <strong>for</strong> nongovernmental purposes <strong>and</strong><br />

tighten restrictions that prevent state <strong>and</strong> local governments from<br />

earning arbitrage profits.<br />

The general income measurement rules proposed will greatly reduce<br />

the attractiveness of existing tax shelters. Yet opportunities <strong>for</strong><br />

tax shelters may remain, <strong>and</strong> the Treasury Department proposes<br />

tightening provisions designed to prevent taxpayers from borrowing to<br />

invest in tax-preferred assets or from taking deductions that exceed<br />

the amount of funds "at risk."<br />

The Treasury Department proposals will retain the basic system of<br />

U.S. taxation of international transactions. The reduction in the<br />

corporate tax rate necessitates changing the <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit to<br />

apply on a country-by-country basis. Source rules should be modified<br />

to reflect more closely the economic substance of transactions. The<br />

possessions tax credit will be revised to direct the credit to<br />

employment-producing investment by U.S. corporations.<br />

453-370 0 - 84 - G


- 126 -<br />

Finally, the Treasury Department proposals will unify <strong>and</strong> simplify<br />

the taxation of estates <strong>and</strong> gifts, simplify the adminstration of <br />

penalty provisions, <strong>and</strong> allow certain provisions to expire. In <br />

addition, the proposals would have beneficial indirect effects on the <br />

financial solvency of the social security system. <br />

19. General Issues of Income Measurement <br />

The current tax law does not account satisfactorily <strong>for</strong> the timing<br />

of many receipts <strong>and</strong> expenses. Too frequently, taxable receipts can<br />

be deferred until later years <strong>and</strong> deductible expenses can be<br />

accelerated. This mismatching of receipts <strong>and</strong> expenses results in tax<br />

deferral, <strong>and</strong> the Federal Government effectively provides to the<br />

taxpayer an interest-free loan equal to the deferred tax liability.<br />

The value of tax deferral is greater, the longer the deferral <strong>and</strong> the<br />

higher the taxpayer's marginal tax rate. Table 7-1 indicates how much<br />

tax deferral reduces effective tax rates. For example, at an 8<br />

percent after-tax interest rate, a 10-year tax deferral. effectively<br />

reduces a 50 percent marginal tax rate to only 23 percent.<br />

Several general income measurement rules in current law require<br />

modification in order to eliminate opportunities <strong>for</strong> tax deferral.<br />

The matching of receipts <strong>and</strong> expenses <strong>for</strong> activities extending over<br />

several years (multiperiod production) requires more comprehensive <strong>and</strong><br />

more uni<strong>for</strong>m cost capitalization rules. The use of the cash method of<br />

accounting should be available only to businesses that do not use the<br />

accrual method <strong>for</strong> financial accounting purposes, carry no<br />

inventories, <strong>and</strong> are too smali to have access to professional accounting<br />

expertise. Vendors should not be permitted to report sales income<br />

on the installment method when their receivables are effectively<br />

converted into cash. The deduction <strong>for</strong> bad debt losses should be<br />

restricted to the actual losses experienced in the current year. Once<br />

these an2 other income measurement changes have been fully<br />

implemented, the retention of the corporate minimum tax will be<br />

unnecessary because the underlying tax preferences will have been<br />

eliminated.<br />

A. aultiperiod Production <br />

Activities that involve multiperiod production, or sales that<br />

occur in years after expenses are incurred, often benefit from the<br />

mismatching of expenses <strong>and</strong> receipts. For instance, most of the<br />

expenses involved in growing timber are deducted long be<strong>for</strong>e the<br />

timber is sold <strong>and</strong> payments are received. Any acceleration of<br />

deductions effectively shelters other income from current taxation.<br />

$latching of receipts <strong>and</strong> expenses is achieved if the costs of<br />

producing long-lived assets are capitalized, that is, included in the<br />

basis of the asset, <strong>and</strong> recovered when the asset is sold or<br />

depreciated.<br />

under current law, certain indirect costs, such as fringe benefits <br />

<strong>and</strong> the cost of borrowing to carry multiperiod production to <br />

completion, generally are not capitalized. In addition, the


- 127 -<br />

Table 7-1<br />

Effective <strong>Tax</strong> Rate Per Dollar of Income Deferred by a <br />

50 Percent <strong>Tax</strong>payer<br />

<strong>for</strong> Different Deferral Periods <strong>and</strong> Interest Rates <br />

Interest rate :<br />

Deferral period<br />

1 : 3 : 5<br />

(in years)<br />

: 1 0 : 2 0 : 3 0<br />

4 percent 48.1 44.4 41.1 33.8 22.8 15.4<br />

6 percent 47.2 41.0 37.4 27.9 15.6 0.7<br />

8 percent 46.3 39.7 34.0 23.2 10.7 5.0<br />

10 percent 45.4 37.6 31.0 19.3 1.4 2.9<br />

12 percent 44.6 35.6 28.4 16.1 5.2 1.7<br />

Office of the Secretary of the Treasury November 25, 1984<br />

Office of <strong>Tax</strong> Analysis


- 128 -<br />

capitalization rules do not apply uni<strong>for</strong>mly to all activities, <strong>and</strong><br />

they vary depending on whether the output is sold or used in the<br />

producer's own business. Long-term contracts, self-constructed<br />

assets, inventories, minerals, <strong>and</strong> timber all have different cost<br />

capitalization rules. The Treasury Department proposals will make the<br />

cost capitalization rules more comprehensive <strong>and</strong> apply a uni<strong>for</strong>m rule<br />

to all multiperiod production act'ivities.<br />

Making cost capitalization rules more uni<strong>for</strong>m would ensure<br />

neutrality across types of businesses, reduce tax shelters, <strong>and</strong><br />

improve equity. Uni<strong>for</strong>m rules would eliminate the current tax<br />

incentive <strong>for</strong> businesses to construct their own plant <strong>and</strong> equipment,<br />

even when they are not the most efficient producers.<br />

In addition, due<br />

to the incomplete capitalization rules, industries with long<br />

production processes -- the so-called "natural deferral" industries,<br />

such as timber <strong>and</strong> minerals -- are dominated by tax shelter investors.<br />

Thus, current law results in serious dislocations <strong>and</strong> inequities.<br />

Among the many consequences, shelter investors bid up l<strong>and</strong> prices <strong>and</strong><br />

drive down product prices in these tax-favored industries; as a<br />

result, low-bracket individuals <strong>and</strong> businesses with little taxable<br />

income to shelter can no longer earn a sufficient after-tax rate of<br />

return from investments in these activities.<br />

B. Use of Cash Nethod of Accounting<br />

Allowing taxpayers to choose between cash <strong>and</strong> accrual accounting<br />

methods results in significant mismatching of taxable receipts <strong>and</strong><br />

deductions. For instance, mismatching occurs in the case of<br />

prepayments of expenses when the buyer uses the cash method <strong>and</strong><br />

deducts payments currently, but the seller uses a method of accounting<br />

that defers income until a later period.<br />

The use of the cash method of accounting is not in accord with<br />

generally accepted accounting principles <strong>and</strong>, there<strong>for</strong>e, is not<br />

permissible <strong>for</strong> financial accounting purposes. Yet, many taxpayers<br />

that use an accrual method <strong>for</strong> financial accounting purposes choose to<br />

use the cash method <strong>for</strong> tax purposes solely because this method defers<br />

taxable income by accelerating deductions. The proposal will restrict<br />

the use of the cash method to businesses that do not use the accrual<br />

method <strong>for</strong> financial accounting purposes, carry no inventories, <strong>and</strong><br />

have gross receipts of less than $5 million.<br />

The restriction on the use of the cash method would only affect<br />

businesses that are already using accrual accounting in some part of<br />

their business or are sufficiently large to have access to<br />

professional accounting expertise. The taxpayers that would be most<br />

affected by the proposal would be banks that use accrual accounting<br />

<strong>for</strong> financial reporting purposes, but the cash method <strong>for</strong> tax<br />

purposes, <strong>and</strong> large cash-method service organizations, such as<br />

accounting, engineering, law, <strong>and</strong> advertising firms.


C. Bad Debt Deductions <br />

- 129 -<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>payers generally are not allowed to deduct the cost of future<br />

liabilities or losses. The deduction <strong>for</strong> bad debt reserves is an<br />

exception from the general realization principle that losses on an<br />

asset are not deducted until the sale or sxchange of the asset. The<br />

current reserve deduction accelerates the timing of the deduction <strong>for</strong><br />

bad debts, <strong>and</strong> thus allows businesses to defer tax on a portion of<br />

their income.<br />

The current bad debt reserve rule allows taxpayers a deduction <strong>for</strong><br />

actual bad debt losses in the current year plus any increase in the<br />

reserve. For example, a beginning firm with $150 of loan losses might<br />

deduct $250 in the first year: $150 <strong>for</strong> the actual loan losses plus<br />

$100 <strong>for</strong> an increase in the allowable reserve <strong>for</strong> future losses. AS<br />

long as the firm's total loan losses never fell below $100, the excess<br />

deductions would never be recaptured. Because firms effectively<br />

deduct their current loan losses, the accumulated reserve <strong>for</strong> a<br />

growing firm is never brought into taxable income. Indefinite tax<br />

deferral is virtually equivalent to tax exemption. Only firms that<br />

have declining loan losses are taxed on their deferred income. Thus,<br />

the current rule mismeasures the timing of taxable income, <strong>and</strong><br />

provides differential tax treatment across types of firms. In<br />

addition, the current treatment of bad debt losses encourages debt<br />

financing <strong>for</strong> risky projects by reducing the risk premium that lenders<br />

charge.<br />

The proposal will restrict the deduction <strong>for</strong> bad debts to the<br />

actual loan losses i n the current year. This will eliminate the<br />

preferential tax treatment of risky loans <strong>and</strong> treat bad debt losses<br />

consistently with other types of losses.<br />

D. Installment Sales <br />

The tax system is not neutral with respect to the <strong>for</strong>m of<br />

financing of property sales. The current rules <strong>for</strong> taxation of<br />

installment sales allow taxpayers that can af<strong>for</strong>d to provide seller<br />

financing to defer tax liability on the sale of property. In<br />

contrast, sellers that receive cash directly, or whose sales are<br />

financed by a third party, pay tax on the giiin currently. Charging<br />

interest on the amount of the deferred tax liability <strong>for</strong> taxpayers<br />

electing the installment method would make the tax law neutral as to<br />

the financing of property sales <strong>and</strong> would end use of installment sales<br />

as a vehicle <strong>for</strong> tax deferral.<br />

The Treasury Department does not propose charging interest on<br />

installment sales, however, because of the increased complexity <strong>and</strong><br />

taxpayer perception problems that such an approach would create. Most<br />

taxpayers would not readily comprehend why they should pay interest on<br />

the deferred taxes when the taxes are only paid as installment<br />

payments are received.


- 130 -<br />

The installment sale method originally was intended to alleviate<br />

the seller's liquidity problems. The method is now commonly used to<br />

defer tax liability on gain from sales by individuals <strong>and</strong> businesses<br />

that have no liquidity problems. For example, sales income may be<br />

reported on the installment method, even though the installment notes<br />

received are immediately pledged as collateral <strong>for</strong> loans. In such<br />

cases, the seller has received cash immediately, has no liquidity<br />

problem, <strong>and</strong> is simply using the installment method <strong>for</strong> tax deferral.<br />

The Treasury Department proposes to deny use of the installment sale<br />

method in such circumstances.<br />

E. Coruorate Minimum <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

Minimum taxes reflect an attempt to maintain the equity <strong>and</strong> <br />

neutrality of a tax system that is riddled with special preferences.<br />

The corporate minimum tax would be necessary only if the underlying<br />

special preferences were retained. Because the Treasury Department's<br />

comprehensive tax re<strong>for</strong>m package repeals almost all special<br />

preferences directly, eventual repeal of the corporate minimum tax <br />

would be possible. However, the minimum tax should not be repealed<br />

unless <strong>and</strong> until the basic re<strong>for</strong>ms are fully implemented. <br />

If, after enactment of tax re<strong>for</strong>m, individuals <strong>and</strong> corporations<br />

with significant economic income still find mechanisms by which to pay<br />

little or no income tax, the Treasury Department would support the<br />

enactment of appropriate minimum taxes on the economic income of<br />

individuals <strong>and</strong> corporations.<br />

II3.<br />

Subsidies <strong>for</strong> Specific Industries <br />

A, Energy <strong>and</strong> Bthes Minerals<br />

Proper measurement of income in natural resource industries <br />

requires that costs of exploration <strong>and</strong> development be capitalized.<br />

Such expenses should then be recovered over the productive life of a <br />

natural resource property as resources are extracted <strong>and</strong> income is <br />

earned. The proper recovery of exploration <strong>and</strong> development costs is <br />

achieved through cost depletion; it is analogous to economic <br />

depreciation. Where only "dry holes" occur <strong>and</strong> an entire property is <br />

ab<strong>and</strong>oned, the related costs should be written off at the time of <br />

ab<strong>and</strong>onment. <br />

<strong>Tax</strong>ation of natural resources in general, <strong>and</strong> of oil <strong>and</strong> gas in<br />

particular, has long deviated from principles required <strong>for</strong> the<br />

accurate measurement of income. The energy industry is currently<br />

favored over other business activities through the tax system in two<br />

unique ways. First, "intangible drilling costs" -- the expenses of<br />

drilling, other than <strong>for</strong> the purchase of physical assets -- can be<br />

deducted currently even if drilling is fruitful. This acceleration of<br />

cost recovery produces several adverse effects. Investment in oil<br />

production is favored relative to other investments with higher pretax<br />

returns. Drilling is favored relative to less expensive means of<br />

exploration that are not tax-preferred. Investment in energy sources


- 131 -<br />

where capital costs are a relatively high share of total costs are<br />

favored relative to others. <strong>Tax</strong> burdens on energy corporations <strong>and</strong> on<br />

individuals investing in the energy sector are reduced, interfering<br />

significantly with tax equity. As a result, the perception of<br />

fairness of the tax system i.s tarnished.<br />

Second, except <strong>for</strong> major integrated oi,l companies <strong>and</strong> certain<br />

large independent producers, cost depletion is not required <strong>for</strong> those<br />

costs of exploration <strong>and</strong> development that are not written off<br />

immediately. Instead, qualified producars of petroleum <strong>and</strong> all<br />

producers of certain other natural resources are allowed to deduct<br />

from taxable income a flat percentage of gross income (ranging from 5<br />

to 22 percent, depending on the mineral), subject to a limitation that<br />

the deduction cannot exceed 50 percent of net income from the<br />

property. Deductions based on percentage depletion, plus previously<br />

deducted investment costs, generally exceed 100 percent of actual<br />

costs of exploration <strong>and</strong> development. Thus, percentage depletion is<br />

not merely an accelerated alternative to cost depletion' as a means of<br />

recovering investments in natural resources; rather it is a subsidy to<br />

the exploitation of natural resources that is administered through the<br />

tax system. This subsidy increases with the prices of natural<br />

resources. Percentage depletion encourages over-production of scarce<br />

domestic resources, adds complexity to the tax system, unfairly<br />

benefits owners of thosz resources, <strong>and</strong> erodes the perception of<br />

fairness of the tax system.<br />

The oil industry is also subject to the windfall profit tax, a<br />

special excise tax on revenues from crude o il produced domestically.<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>able crud- oil i s classified in three tiers. Generally, oil in<br />

tier one is oil that has been subject to price controls; oil in tier<br />

two consists of stripper well oil; <strong>and</strong> oil in tier three is newly<br />

discovered oil, incremental o il <strong>and</strong> heavey oil. The tax base is the<br />

difference between a statutory base price <strong>and</strong> the amount <strong>for</strong> which the<br />

oil is sold, less a severance tax adjustment. The tax rate is highest<br />

<strong>for</strong> tier one oil <strong>and</strong> is progressively reduced <strong>for</strong> tiers two <strong>and</strong> three<br />

(with a greater reduction <strong>for</strong> newly discovered oil).<br />

The windfall profit tax was enacted in 1980 at a time when crude <br />

oil prices were rising rapidly. Its enactment was associated with <br />

decontrol of crude oil prices. Since that time crude oil prices have <br />

moderated <strong>and</strong>, in fact, have significantly declined from record high<br />

levels. Consequently, the perceived "windfall" <strong>for</strong> producers has <br />

generally vanished. Furthermore, ?he tax offset some of the <br />

additional stimulus to domestic production provided by oil decontrol. <br />

The goal. of increased reliance on free-market <strong>for</strong>ces underlies<br />

this Administration's energy policy, as well as the Treasury<br />

Department study of fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m. As stated i n the Budget<br />

<strong>for</strong> Fiscal. Year 1985:<br />

The Nation needs adequate supplies of economical<br />

energy. The most promising way to meet this<br />

need is to let market <strong>for</strong>ces work ... The


primary role of the Federal Government with<br />

respect to energy is to establish <strong>and</strong> maintain<br />

sound policies based on economic principles that<br />

promote efficient energy production <strong>and</strong> use.<br />

This strategy ... emphasizes the importance of<br />

allowing our market economy to function to<br />

ensute that these decisions are as productive<br />

<strong>and</strong> efficient as possible.<br />

The Treasury Department there<strong>for</strong>e proposes that the windfall<br />

profit tax be repealed ana that the option of expensing intangible<br />

drilling costs <strong>and</strong> percentage depletion be replaced by cost depletion.<br />

Repeal of expensing on intangible drilling costs <strong>and</strong> percentage<br />

depletion should not be viewed as penalizing or singling out the<br />

energy industry. The proposed rules are identical to proposed changes<br />

in the general rules <strong>for</strong> income measurement <strong>for</strong> all multiperiod<br />

production, which require cost capitalization in order to match deductions<br />

with taxable receipts.<br />

Some will argue that these subsidies <strong>for</strong> the production of<br />

minerals provided by special tax treatment cannot be eliminated,<br />

because doing so would reduce domestic production <strong>and</strong> increase<br />

American dependence on <strong>for</strong>eign sources of oil <strong>and</strong> other minerals.<br />

Further, they will argue that enactment of the Treasury Department<br />

proposals would raise prices of minerals, even though the magnitude of<br />

this effect would probably be small bocaiise the prices of most<br />

minerals are set in international markets. While these effects may<br />

occur <strong>and</strong> might be burdensome in the short run, the proposed re<strong>for</strong>ms<br />

would be beneficial in the long run because the capital <strong>and</strong> labor<br />

released from the energy <strong>and</strong> minerals sector as a result of a more<br />

neutral tax policy would be employed more productively in other<br />

industries. Higher prices <strong>for</strong> oil <strong>and</strong> gas, lower marginal tax rates,<br />

indexation of the basis against which depletion allowances are taken,<br />

<strong>and</strong> repeal of the windfall profit tax would partially offset the<br />

elimination of the subsidy, cushion any drop in domestic production,<br />

<strong>and</strong> encourage the development of alternative domestic energy sources.<br />

AS the Administration's announced policy on energy makes clear, the<br />

public would gain froin a more rational allocation of resources among<br />

competing energy modes, Prices more reflective of the actual<br />

replacement costs of energy would encourage greater conservation, <strong>and</strong><br />

that, plus less rapid depletion of domestic resources, would, over the<br />

long run, reduce vulnerability to <strong>for</strong>eign supply disruptions.<br />

13. Financial Institutions<br />

Most types of financial institutions presently benefit from<br />

preferential tax treatment. Besides being unfair <strong>and</strong> distortionary<br />

relative to the taxation of the rest of the economy, these tax<br />

preferences create distortions within the financial sector that are<br />

inconsistent with the Administration's ef<strong>for</strong>ts to deregulate financial<br />

markets. Equity <strong>and</strong> neutrality dem<strong>and</strong> that all financial institutions<br />

be taxed uni<strong>for</strong>mly on all of their net income. These special


- 133 -<br />

preferences are especially inappropriate in a world in which the<br />

corporate tax rate is lowered <strong>and</strong> both individuals <strong>and</strong> other<br />

corporations are taxed on their economic income.<br />

Banks <strong>and</strong> thrift institutions are allowed to deduct an arbitrary<br />

fraction of outst<strong>and</strong>ing loans or otherwise taxable income as an<br />

addition to a reserve against bad debts, without regard to the actual<br />

losses they experience on bad debts. In theory, reserve accounting is<br />

consistent with accrual accounting; but in practice reserve accounting<br />

<strong>for</strong> banks <strong>and</strong> thrift institutions has borne little relation to<br />

expected losses, <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e little relation to proper accrual<br />

accounting. The special bad debt deduction <strong>for</strong> thrift institutions is<br />

tied to specialization in residential mortgage lending, <strong>and</strong> only<br />

benefits profitable thrift institutions. The special rules are at<br />

variance with the general rules that are applied to non-depository<br />

institutions <strong>and</strong> the correct income measurement rule. This arbitrary<br />

deduction involves a tax subsidy <strong>for</strong> financial institutions that has<br />

no place in an income tax system; it should be repealed.<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>payers generally are prohibited from deducting interest on debt<br />

incurred to finance holdings of tax-exempt bonds. Banks benefit from<br />

an exception to this rule; they are able to deduct 80 percent of<br />

interest incurred to carry tax-exempt securities, <strong>and</strong> thus offset<br />

taxable income from other sources, in many cases totally eliminating<br />

income tax liability. Because of the special rule that allows banks<br />

to earn arbitrage profits, borrowing costs of state <strong>and</strong> local<br />

governments are subject to greater volatility because of the excessive<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> created <strong>for</strong> their tax-preferred bonds. The Treasury Department<br />

proposes extending to banks the general rule that fully disallows<br />

interest deductions on debt incurred to carry tax-exempt securities.<br />

Credit unions, which compete with banks <strong>and</strong> thrift institutions,<br />

currently are tax exempt. This exemption allows deferral of tax on<br />

members' interest income that is retained in the credit union. This<br />

tax break <strong>for</strong> their members gives credit unions a competitive<br />

advantage in attracting deposits from other financial institutions.<br />

The exemption should be repealed.<br />

Life insurance companies traditionally have been allowed a<br />

deduction <strong>for</strong> increases in policy reserves that exceed the amount of<br />

policyholders' savings <strong>and</strong> interest income represented by the actual<br />

increase in the cash value of the policies they underwrite. In<br />

addition, they are allowed a special deduction <strong>for</strong> 20 percent of<br />

otherwise taxable income (60 percent <strong>for</strong> small companies). This extra<br />

deduction is equivalent to applying a lower tax rate to the income of<br />

life insurance companies. Deductions <strong>for</strong> increases in reserves should<br />

be limited to increases in cash value, <strong>and</strong> the special deduction<br />

should be repealed.<br />

Amounts earned by policyholders on the cash value of life<br />

insurance (the "inside buildup") generally escape income tax under<br />

present law. As a result, income earned on investments i n life<br />

insurance policies is treated substantially more favorably than


interest on deposits in banks <strong>and</strong> thrift institutions, which is taxed<br />

currently. In addition, tax-deferred income from annuities can be<br />

earned in unlimited amounts. rn order to make the taxation of income<br />

flowing through financial institutions more neutral, the Treasury<br />

Department proposes that the exclusion of the inside buildup in life<br />

insurance be repealed <strong>and</strong> that annuity interest income be subject to<br />

current taxation. <strong>Tax</strong>payers will be allowed to treat the savings<br />

portion of life insurance premiums as deposits in an individual<br />

retirement account (IRA), subject to the overall IRA limitations.<br />

Income earned on these savings will be tax exempt until withdrawn from<br />

the IRA.<br />

Property <strong>and</strong> casualty (P&C) insurance companies are allowed a<br />

deduction <strong>for</strong> additions to accounts <strong>for</strong> protection against losses that<br />

bears no relation to actual losses. In addition, P&C companies are<br />

allowed current deductions <strong>for</strong> losses expected to be incurred in the<br />

future, with no recognition that the future losses are worth<br />

substantially less, in present value terms, than the deductions being<br />

allowed currently. (Another way of saying this is that to meet future<br />

losses a much smaller amount can be set aside today because of the<br />

interest earned be<strong>for</strong>e the loss is incurred.) Both of these excessive<br />

deductions are inconsistent with a comprehensive income tax; the first<br />

should be repealed, <strong>and</strong> the second should be altered to reflect the<br />

value of an early deduction <strong>for</strong> Euture losses.<br />

The proposed tax changes at both the individual <strong>and</strong> corporate<br />

levels would make the "playing field" <strong>for</strong> financial institutions more <br />

level <strong>and</strong> more comparable to that of nonfinancial institutions. These <br />

changes are consistent with <strong>and</strong> necessary <strong>for</strong> the deregulation of the <br />

financial sector. All financial institutions would be affected, but <br />

they would generally be compensated by the reduction in the corporate <br />

tax rate. <br />

Banks would no longer find it advantageous to eliminate Federal<br />

tax liability by investing in tax-exempt bonds; the lower tax rate<br />

would make their after-tax return on taxable investments generally<br />

higher than the current tax-exempt yields. Eliminating the special<br />

rule that enables many banks to pay little, or no, Federal income tax<br />

would improve the perception of fairness of the tax system. Repeal of<br />

the special deductions of thrift institutions <strong>and</strong> life insurance<br />

companies will be offset by the lower tax rate. Credit unions will be<br />

taxed on the same basis as banks <strong>and</strong> other thrift institutions.<br />

Individuals would buy life insurance <strong>and</strong> annuity policies <strong>for</strong> the<br />

primary purpose of protecting against premature death or longevity,<br />

rather than as a tax shelter. And P&C insurance companies would have<br />

no tax advantage in selling casualty insurance coinpared with companies<br />

willing to self-insure against the risk of property loss.<br />

The total amount of saving flowing through financial institutions <br />

would increase as rate reductions increase the after-tax return to <br />

saving. The proposed changes would remove the tax distortions that <br />

encourage saving to flow through life insurance companies at the


- 135 -<br />

expense of other financial institutions. The change in the bad debt <br />

deduction would remove the tax incentive <strong>for</strong> banks <strong>and</strong> thrift <br />

institutions to make risky loans. <br />

C. Debt of State <strong>and</strong> Local Governments<br />

Interest on debt issued by State <strong>and</strong> local governments <strong>for</strong> governmental<br />

purposes, such as schools, roads, <strong>and</strong> sewers ("governmental<br />

bonds"), has long been exempt from tax. The exemption of this<br />

interest is inconsistent with a comprehensive income tax. Moreover,<br />

the subsidy it provides to the borrowing of State <strong>and</strong> local governments<br />

is an inefficient one because much of its benefits are received<br />

by high-income bondholders, rather than producing cost savings <strong>for</strong><br />

state <strong>and</strong> local governments. The exemption of interest on<br />

governmental bonds originated in earlier views about the fiscal<br />

relationship between the Federal <strong>and</strong> State <strong>and</strong> local governments under<br />

the Constitution. However outmoded that underst<strong>and</strong>ing of federalism<br />

may appear today, this exemption appears to be an accepted part of the<br />

fiscal l<strong>and</strong>scape.<br />

State <strong>and</strong> local governments have recently exp<strong>and</strong>ed the use of taxexempt<br />

bonds in ways that should not be accepted. Proceeds from taxexempt<br />

bonds have been used <strong>for</strong> non-governmental purposes: <strong>for</strong><br />

economic development (via industrial development bonds or IDBs), <strong>for</strong><br />

low-interest mortgages on owner-occupied housing, <strong>for</strong> student loans,<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> private hospital <strong>and</strong> educational facilities. In addition,<br />

State <strong>and</strong> local governments have invested proceeds of tax-exempt bonds<br />

in higher-yielding taxable securities to earn arbitrage profits.<br />

The use of State <strong>and</strong> local governments' tax-exempt borrowing<br />

privilege <strong>for</strong> the direct benefit of private businesses, nonprofit<br />

organizations, <strong>and</strong> individuals has increased rapidly in recent years.<br />

Non-governmental bonds issued in 1975 totaled only $9 billion,<br />

accounting <strong>for</strong> 30 percent of long-term tax-exempt bond volume. In<br />

1983, non-governmental tax-exempt bonds totaled $58 billion <strong>and</strong><br />

accounted <strong>for</strong> 62 percent all new long-term tax-exempt bond issues.<br />

(See Figure 7-1.) Despite recently enacted volume limitations on<br />

certain non-governmental bonds, their share of the total tax-exempt<br />

bond market will continue to increase in the future in the absence of<br />

further restrictions. This will bid up the interest rates that must<br />

be paid on debt of State <strong>and</strong> local governments issued <strong>for</strong> governmental<br />

purposes.<br />

Seen from the perspective of any one State or local government,<br />

issuance of such non-governmental tax-exempt bonds appears attractive;<br />

a local business or resident obtains a Federal subsidy at no cost to<br />

the local government. In many cases the local government would not<br />

provide a direct subsidy to the same business or resident. From a<br />

national perspective, however, the subsidies provided through taxexempt<br />

financing to private businesses <strong>and</strong> individuals are<br />

inefficient, costly <strong>and</strong> distortionary. If all of the States compete<br />

<strong>for</strong> economic development by issuing industrial development bonds,<br />

economic activity will not be significantly greater than in the


- 136 -<br />

0 <br />

-0<br />

(1:<br />

0 <br />

a <br />

C <br />

cu<br />

0 <br />

-I<br />

c<br />

C <br />

e,<br />

-0<br />

3<br />

5


absence of the bonds <strong>and</strong> it will probably not be located very<br />

differently. Firms not benefitting from IDBs are placed at a<br />

competitive disadvantage. Moreover, the loans are not allocated to<br />

their best use, but rather to those who best know how to manipulate an<br />

administrative or political process.<br />

The primary effects of non-governmental tax-exempt bonds are a<br />

lower interest rate <strong>for</strong> the private business or individual benefitting<br />

from tax-exempt financing, tax savings <strong>for</strong> wealthy bondholders, higher<br />

borrowing costs on tax-exempt bonds issued <strong>for</strong> governmental purposes,<br />

less Federal revenues as a result of tax exemption of interest on the<br />

bonds, <strong>and</strong> correspondingly higher tax rates on wages <strong>and</strong> salaries <strong>and</strong><br />

other <strong>for</strong>ms of taxable income. If below-market mortgages or student<br />

loans benefitting local residents are thought to be worthy of local<br />

support, they should be financed locally, not through inefficient<br />

Federal subsidies to local borrowing that drive up tax rates<br />

throughout the country. The Treasury Department proposals will<br />

eliminate the future issuance of all tax-exempt bonds resulting in<br />

proceeds used by persons or organizations which are not governments,<br />

tighten the restrictions on arbitrage, rely on market <strong>for</strong>ces to di.rect<br />

private investment to its most efficient use, exp<strong>and</strong> the tax base, <strong>and</strong><br />

lower tax rates.<br />

The proposed elimination of: non-governmental bonds should be of<br />

financial benefit to State <strong>and</strong> local governments. Reducing the volume<br />

of tax-exempt bonds will improve the market <strong>for</strong> bonds issued <strong>for</strong><br />

government purposes, thus reducing interest costs to governments.<br />

v. -special Rules<br />

In addition to the industry-specific subsidies previously<br />

described, the tax law is littered with credits, exclusions, <strong>and</strong><br />

special exceptions to general rules. These implicit subsidies should<br />

be repealed as part of tax re<strong>for</strong>m designed to free markets from the<br />

intrusions of government via the tax system.<br />

b<strong>and</strong> is not depreciable because its productive capacity is not<br />

expected to decline measurably over time. Yet certain capital<br />

expenditures have special recovery rules, even though some of these<br />

expenditures are <strong>for</strong> assets siinilar to l<strong>and</strong>. For instance, companies<br />

are allowed to recover the cost of railroad grading <strong>and</strong> tunnel bores<br />

over 50 years, even though such improvements may have undiminished<br />

economic value <strong>for</strong> hundreds of years or even indefinitely.<br />

Other special rules were intended to encourage a particular<br />

activity by allowing accelerated write-offs <strong>and</strong> the advantages of tax<br />

deferral. The current law allows 5-year write-off of certified<br />

pollution control facilities. This provision was intended to reduce<br />

the cost of businesses complying with regulatory requirements. Since<br />

the enactment of ACRS in 1981, this provision has not been used,<br />

because accelerated cost recovery over 5 years is more generous than<br />

straight-line recovery over the same period. However, compared with<br />

the indexing <strong>and</strong> recovery over economic lives proposed <strong>for</strong> all other


- 138 -<br />

assets, this special provision would be extremely advantageous. As<br />

part of comprehensive tax re<strong>for</strong>m, these special rules that mismeasure<br />

economic income <strong>and</strong> benefit specific industries should be repealed.<br />

The Merchant Marine Capital Construction Fund is an example of a<br />

tax subsidy program that has become outdated <strong>and</strong> distorted from its<br />

original purpose. In 1936, special tax treatment, along with direct<br />

appropriations programs, were provided <strong>for</strong> U.S. citizens owning or<br />

leasing U.S.-flag vessels to assure an adequate shipping capacity in<br />

the event of war. The direct appropriations programs have heen phased<br />

out because an adequate number of vessels are owned or controlled by<br />

U.S. citizens, though perhaps registered elsewhere. The tax subsidy,<br />

on the other h<strong>and</strong>, has been exp<strong>and</strong>ed to fishing vessels <strong>and</strong> ships<br />

plying the inl<strong>and</strong> waterways -- a result inconsistent even with the<br />

original, but antiquated, purpose <strong>for</strong> the Fund. This tax subsidy<br />

program should be repealed.<br />

The R&E credit, which is designed to encourage businesses to<br />

undertake additional private research activities, will be extended.<br />

To improve the effectiveness of the credit, however, the scope of<br />

qualifying expenses will be focused so that the credit is available<br />

only <strong>for</strong> private research activities that are likely to lead to<br />

technological innovations. A revised definition of eligible expenses<br />

will target the credit more narrowly <strong>and</strong> provide a greater incentive<br />

<strong>for</strong> business to undertake research ef<strong>for</strong>ts which will lead to<br />

productivity-enhancing innovations.<br />

The tax Code also contains a number of credits that should be<br />

repealed. Rehabilitation tax credits provide Federal subsidies <strong>for</strong><br />

the renovation of older buildings <strong>and</strong> historic property. These tax<br />

credits were intended to match the favorable tax treatment of new<br />

buildings resulting from accelerated depreciation <strong>and</strong> investment tax<br />

credits. With repeal of the investment tax credit <strong>and</strong> the use of<br />

indexed, economic depreciation, the rehabilitation tax credits should<br />

be repealed. The subsidization of historic preservation expenditures,<br />

if believed to be desirable, should be provided through direct<br />

appropriations, rather than through the tax system.<br />

ISr.<br />

Further Curtailment of <strong>Tax</strong> Shelters<br />

Participation in a variety of tax shelter investments has<br />

increased steadily since the 1960s. One indication is the growth in<br />

the number of individual tax returns claiming partnership losses, as<br />

partnerships are the most common vehicle <strong>for</strong> investing in tax<br />

shelters. Between 1963 <strong>and</strong> 1982 the number of taxpayers claiming<br />

partnership losses increased almost five-fold to 2.1 million. By<br />

comparison, the total number of tax returns filed during the same<br />

period increased by only 50 percent.<br />

In 1981 <strong>and</strong> 1982, U.S. partnerships actually reported aggregate<br />

net losses <strong>for</strong> tax purposes. Over one-half of all partnership losses<br />

were concentrated in three broad areas: farming, mining <strong>and</strong> other<br />

extractive industries, <strong>and</strong> real estate. These industries benefit


- 139 ­<br />

especi,ally from opportunities <strong>for</strong> shelte.ring created by the<br />

combination of deferral of taxes, preferential treatment of long-term<br />

capital gains, <strong>and</strong> the deductibility of interest.<br />

<strong>Tax</strong> deferral arises whenever investors are able to accelerate<br />

deductions or defer reporting of taxable receipts. Opportunities <strong>for</strong><br />

such deferral are created by a variety of tax rules. In the case of<br />

farms, current deductions are allowed <strong>for</strong> costs incurred to earn<br />

income which is not reported until a later taxable year; in the case<br />

of oil <strong>and</strong> gas drilling, intangible drilling costs may be expensed in<br />

the current taxable year, rather than capit.alized <strong>and</strong> recovered over a<br />

number of years; in the case of real estate, deferral is made possible<br />

by tax depreciation rules which permit deductions in excess of true<br />

economic depreciation to be taken in the early years of the<br />

investment.<br />

A second aspect of tax shelters is the conversion of ordinary<br />

income to tax-preferred capital gains. <strong>Tax</strong> deferral <strong>and</strong> conversion of<br />

ordinary income to capital gains occur together when accelerated<br />

depreciation deductions are used to offset ordinary wage <strong>and</strong> salary<br />

income, while a significant portion of the annual return on the<br />

investment is realized as preferentially taxed Long-term capital gain<br />

at some future date.<br />

Moreover, when taxation of income from an asset can be deferred or<br />

converted into tax-preferred income, investors will often have a<br />

strong incentive to finance the acquisition of the asset by means of<br />

borrowing, as this allows the investor to engage in interest-related<br />

tax arbitrage. Interest-related tax arbitrage transactions occur when<br />

an investor borrows funds, fully deducts the interest expenses<br />

incurred to borrow those funds, <strong>and</strong> then uses the funds to purchase<br />

investments which earn either partially or entirely tax-exempt or taxdeferred<br />

income.<br />

It is the combination of tax deferral <strong>and</strong> leveraged financing<br />

which is the principal cause of the substantial losses reported by tax<br />

shelter partnerships in the a<strong>for</strong>ementioned three industries -- some<br />

$33 billion in 1982. Yet <strong>for</strong> reasons just mentioned, these "losses"<br />

overstate true economic losses incurred by those partnerships. A<br />

substantial portion of the accounting losses simply reflect preferential<br />

tax treatment of certain sources <strong>and</strong> uses of income.<br />

As a consequence of these tax accounting losses, affluent investors<br />

are able to shelter other income from tax. This is undesirable<br />

primarily because preferential treatment of particular activities<br />

interferes with the market-determined allocation of resources <strong>and</strong><br />

unfairly benefits investors in tax shelters.<br />

The proliferation of tax shelters has other undesirable consequences.<br />

Auditing tax shelters absorbs valuable resources of the<br />

Internal Revenue Service that could better be devoted to other tasks.<br />

Beyond that, the widespread existence of legitimate shelters makes it<br />

far more difficult <strong>for</strong> the Internal Revenue Service to identify <strong>and</strong>


- 140 -<br />

control. abusive shelters involving tax fraud. Perhaps worse,<br />

unsophisticated taxpayers who cannot af<strong>for</strong>d legal advice also cannot<br />

distinguish between legitimate <strong>and</strong> abusive shelters <strong>and</strong> thus<br />

increasingly invest in the latter with disastrous results. To lower<br />

<strong>and</strong> middle-income taxpayers who cannot benefit from tax shelters, the<br />

distinction between legal tax avoidance <strong>and</strong> illegal evasion may be too<br />

subtle to prevent a widespread impression that the tax system is<br />

unfair because high-income taxpayers are escaping taxation. This impression<br />

of unfairness lies at the root of many complaints about the<br />

tax system <strong>and</strong> undermines voluntary compliance with the tax law. Of<br />

course, this perception is accentuated by widely publicized stories<br />

about abusive shelters.<br />

<strong>Growth</strong> in tax shelter activity has also played a significant role<br />

in the erosion of the Federal income tax base, particularly among<br />

affluent taxpayers. Estimates from the 1983 Treasury individual tax<br />

model indicated that total partnership losses (losses claimed by<br />

individuals -- as distinct from corporations, who also own partnership<br />

interests) may have sheltered as much as $35 billion of all individual<br />

income from taxation. Roughly $28.6 billion or 82 percent of total<br />

partnership losses claimed on individual tax returns were reported by<br />

taxpayers with gross incomes (be<strong>for</strong>e losses) of $100,000 or more, <strong>and</strong><br />

60 percent, or $21.0 billion, were reported by taxpayers with gross<br />

income (be<strong>for</strong>e losses) in excess of $250,000. By comparison, these<br />

groups reported considerably smaller shares of all gross income be<strong>for</strong>e<br />

losses -- 9 percent <strong>and</strong> 4 percent, respprtively.<br />

Several of the Treasury Department's proposals <strong>for</strong> example,<br />

lower tax rates, taxation of real capital gains as ordinary income,<br />

capital consumption allowances that approximate economic depreciation,<br />

indexing of interest expense, matching expenses <strong>and</strong> receipts from<br />

multiperiod production, <strong>and</strong> tax treatment of certain large<br />

partnerships as corporations -- will greatly reduce the attractiveness<br />

of tax shelters. Yet opportunities <strong>for</strong> tax shelters will remain. The<br />

proposals in this sect.ion will further reduce these opportunities.<br />

A. Limiting Interest Deductions <br />

Under the present income tax, certain <strong>for</strong>ms of investment income<br />

are not fully taxed. Notable examples include interest from State <strong>and</strong><br />

local securities, long-term capital gains, <strong>and</strong> the earnings on many<br />

insurance <strong>and</strong> retirement accounts. Moreover, certain expenditures<br />

give rise to deductions <strong>and</strong> credits that can be used to offset tax<br />

that would otherwise be due on other income. The most important of<br />

these are accelerated depreciation, the investment tax credit, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

immediate deduction <strong>for</strong> intangible drilling costs.<br />

When investments benefitting from tax preferences are debtfinanced,<br />

the preferences generally are magnified. This problem has<br />

long been recognized, <strong>and</strong> since 1921 deduction of interest incurred to<br />

carry tax-exempt securities has been disallowed. Because it is<br />

difficult <strong>for</strong> the Internal Revenue Service to associate a particular<br />

debt with investment in tax-exempt securities or other tax-preferred<br />

--


investments, this type of restriction is not fully effective. More<br />

recently, the deduction <strong>for</strong> investment interest expense was limited to<br />

the sum of investment income plus $l0,000, in order to prevent<br />

taxpayers from taking large deductions <strong>for</strong> interest expense incurred<br />

to earn tax-preferred income. However, the limitation does not<br />

adequately take into account interest incurred to finance investments<br />

in many tax-preferred activities.<br />

The Treasury Department proposes tightening the interest<br />

limitation rules. Individuals would be allowed no current deduction<br />

<strong>for</strong> investment interest expense in excess of the sum of passive<br />

investment income, mortgage interest on the taxpayer's principal<br />

residence, <strong>and</strong> $5,000, For this purpose, passive investment income<br />

will not include business <strong>and</strong> investment income from general partnerships<br />

interests, sole proprietorships, S corporations actively managed<br />

by the taxpayer, <strong>and</strong> farms, but will include dividends, interast, <strong>and</strong><br />

income from limited partnership interests, Similarly, investment<br />

interest subject to the limitation will include all interest now<br />

deducted as an itemized deduction (other than interest on the<br />

taxpayer's principal residence) plus the taxpayer's allocable share of<br />

interest incurred through any limited partnership interest <strong>and</strong> any S<br />

corporation in which the taxpayer is a passive investor. This<br />

limitation will not prevent the deduction of mortgage interest on the<br />

principal residence of the taxpayer, nor the deduction of interest<br />

incurred in the conduct of a trade or business. The $5,000 allowance<br />

would prevent the limitation from affecting most taxpayers.<br />

As long as high-income investors are able to borrow funds to<br />

acquire investments which pay tax-preferred income, <strong>and</strong> deduct<br />

currently the interest expenses incurred to borrow those funds, tax<br />

equity will suffer <strong>and</strong> the marginal tax rate needed to raise a given<br />

amount of tax revenue will be higher than would otherwise be required.<br />

Moreover, the arbitrage availability encourages high-income investors<br />

to compete aggressively <strong>for</strong> borrowed funds in capital markets,<br />

reducing the supply of capital available <strong>for</strong> low-income borrowers,<br />

including prospective homeowners <strong>and</strong> new businesses. The proposed<br />

limitation on interest expense would reduce the extent to which highincome<br />

investors engage in tax-motivated borrowing, but would not<br />

discourage borrowing <strong>for</strong> active business pursuits. Tfiis would both<br />

lower marginal tax rates, <strong>and</strong> make it easier <strong>for</strong> moderate-income<br />

investors to compete <strong>for</strong> borrowed funds with high-income investors.<br />

8. At-Bisk Rules<br />

Current law contains rules to prevent a taxpayer from taking<br />

deductions that exceed the amount he or she has "at risk" in a given<br />

investment. The at-risk rules apply primarily when the taxpayer is<br />

taking deductions related to assets that are heavily financed by nonrecourse<br />

debt -- debt <strong>for</strong> which the taxpayer is not personally liable.<br />

Non-recourse debt often plays an important role in tax shelters, as it<br />

permits taxpayers to report deductions in excess of the amount of the<br />

taxpayer's actual investment. The tax losses that these deductions<br />

produce <strong>for</strong> the investor are clearly artificial, since an investor


- 142 -<br />

cannot possibly lose more than he or she has at risk in an investment.<br />

Because the at-risk rules are complicated, it is tempting to<br />

propose that they be eliminated in the interest of simplification.<br />

But the at-risk rules could not be repealed without replacing them<br />

with an equally effective solution, such as a reduction in the basis<br />

used in calculating depreciation allowances by the amount of nonrecourse<br />

debt. Such a radical departure from current law would have<br />

an uncertain <strong>and</strong> perhaps severe economic impact. Thus despite t,he<br />

logic of such an approach, the Treasury Department does not propose<br />

it. Rather, the at-risk rules should be retained <strong>and</strong> applied to all<br />

investments.<br />

In the case of activities to which the at-risk rules do not<br />

currently apply, such as real estate <strong>and</strong> leasing, the tax benefits of<br />

the investment are so magnified that the true economic return of the<br />

inzrestment property is often a minor consideration in the ultimate<br />

decision of whether to invest. As a result, resources are allocated<br />

without due regard to the true (pre-tax) profit.ability of such<br />

ventures. Since pre-tax profitability can generally be trusted to<br />

guide the nation‘s resources to their best uses, this emphasis on<br />

after-tax profits, to the neglect of pre-tax profits, interferes with<br />

the market allocation of resources ,to their most productive uses.<br />

Extending the at-risk rules to cover all activities would allow<br />

deductions only to the extent of the investor‘s actual liability <strong>for</strong><br />

potential losses in that activity. As a result, investors in tax<br />

shelter activities could still claim sizable depreciation <strong>and</strong> interest<br />

deductions, provided that they were accountable <strong>for</strong> a commensurate<br />

share of the business risk associated with the investment. This would<br />

cause investors to pay more attention to the potential economic gain<br />

or loss from investments, rather than focusing on their tax<br />

consequences, <strong>and</strong> thereby promote greater efficiency in the allocation<br />

of the nation’s capital among competing activities. With investments<br />

based on economic realities, there would be less tendency <strong>for</strong> real<br />

estate prices to spiral upwards, driven by investors in tax shelters.<br />

v. Lnternational Issues .-<br />

In taxing the <strong>for</strong>eign income of U.S. taxpayers, the United States<br />

has sought a balanced treatment of <strong>for</strong>eign <strong>and</strong> domestic investment,<br />

tempered by concern <strong>for</strong> international competitiveness. U.S. taxpayers<br />

are subject to tax on their worldwide income. However, in order to<br />

avoid double taxation of <strong>for</strong>eign income also taxed by host countries,<br />

a credit is allowed <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>eign income taxes paid. In the interest of<br />

competitiveness, U.S. tax on income earned by <strong>for</strong>eign subsidiary<br />

corporations is generally deferred until that income is remitted to<br />

U.S. shareholders. (This tax deferral is not available with respect<br />

to tax haven income.) In addition, the Foreign Sales Corporation<br />

(“FSC”)provisions <strong>and</strong> the exclusion of individuals‘ <strong>for</strong>eign earned<br />

income provide special rules to promote exports. Other special rules<br />

are designed to promote investment in the U.S. possessions.


- 143 -<br />

The Treasury Department proposals will retain this basic system of<br />

1J.S. taxation of international transactions. For example, the <strong>for</strong>eign<br />

tax credit, the deferral of tax on undistributed <strong>for</strong>eign subsidiary<br />

earnings, the FSC provisions, <strong>and</strong> the <strong>for</strong>eign earned income exclusion<br />

would be retained. The present system of current taxation of certain<br />

tax haven earnings of <strong>for</strong>eign subsidiaries also would be continued,<br />

but consideration should be given to coordinating the various rules.<br />

Changes would be made in the <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit limitation <strong>and</strong> in<br />

certain source provisions to make those rules work more efficiently<br />

<strong>and</strong> equitably. The taxation of income from the possessions <strong>and</strong><br />

territories would be revised. Other more technical changes would<br />

rationalize the taxation of U.S. branches of <strong>for</strong>eign corporations <strong>and</strong><br />

the translation of certain <strong>for</strong>eign exchange transactions.<br />

The <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit is intended to prevent the U.S. tax from<br />

resulting in double taxation of <strong>for</strong>eign income. It is not intended to<br />

reduce the U.S. tax on U.S. income. To prevent credits <strong>for</strong> high<br />

<strong>for</strong>eign taxes from offsetting the U.S. tax on domestic income, a limit<br />

is placed on the amount of <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit which may be used in any<br />

given year (with provision <strong>for</strong> carryover of excess credits). Current<br />

law generally limits the allowable <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit to the U.S. tax<br />

on the taxpayer's aggregate <strong>for</strong>eign source income. Under this<br />

"overall" limitation, <strong>for</strong>eign income taxes paid to different countries<br />

are zveraged together; high <strong>for</strong>eign taxes paid to one country may be<br />

used by the taxpayer to offset the U.S. tax on income earned in a low<br />

tax country.<br />

Such an approach distorts investment decisions. A taxpayer has an<br />

incentive to generate low-taxed <strong>for</strong>eign income to utilize excess<br />

<strong>for</strong>eign tax credits. As a consequence, investments may be shifted<br />

from the United States to low tax countries. The U.S. tax base is<br />

eroded <strong>and</strong> capital may be allocated to less productive uses <strong>for</strong> tax<br />

reasons. Low-taxed <strong>for</strong>eign income also may be generated by using the<br />

existing source rules simply to shift income to low-tax jurisdictions.<br />

For example, income from certain sales may be sourced in any country<br />

by having the title pass there.<br />

The proposed reduction in the U.S. corporate tax rate will greatly<br />

increase excess <strong>for</strong>eign tax credits. This will correspondingly<br />

increase the incentives to divert investment <strong>and</strong> income to low-tax<br />

countries, if the overall limitation is left intact. It is there<strong>for</strong>e<br />

proposed that the <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit limitation be changed to apply<br />

country by country, <strong>and</strong> that certain source rules be modified to<br />

reflect more closely the economic substance of the transaction.<br />

There are those who will argue that the Treasury Department<br />

proposal will only aggravate the problem of excess <strong>for</strong>eign tax<br />

credits. But this defense of the overall limit on the credit is based<br />

on a misunderst<strong>and</strong>ing of the purpose of the credit. The purpose of<br />

the credit is to avoid double taxation of <strong>for</strong>eign source income. The<br />

per-country limit achieves that. Relief from taxes in excess of U.S.<br />

taxes on the same income must be sought elsewhere.


-- 144 -<br />

A "per country" limitation is used by most other countries that<br />

allow a <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit, <strong>and</strong> it was long used in the United States,<br />

either with the overall limitation or alone. It was repealed in 1976<br />

because large tax acc0untir.g losses in certain countries were<br />

offsetting U.S. income <strong>and</strong> reducing revenues. Proposed changes in<br />

accounting <strong>for</strong> depreciation <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> multiperiod production will<br />

largely eliminate the reasons <strong>for</strong> repealing the per country<br />

limitation. The treatment of economic losses will be addressed<br />

directly by allowing them to offset the pool of profits from all other<br />

countries, with an appropriate provision <strong>for</strong> recapture.<br />

In combination with the reduced rate of corporate tax, the<br />

proposed changes in the <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit limitation <strong>and</strong> source rules<br />

will result in a substantial net reduction in the U.S. tax on <strong>for</strong>eign<br />

income. In effect, the combination will make the <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit<br />

operate more efficiently <strong>and</strong> equitably without penalizing <strong>for</strong>eign<br />

investment.<br />

Another proposed change in international taxation affects the<br />

credit or income from U.S. possessions. The tax benefit of the<br />

existing credit rewards the shifting of income to the possessions,<br />

whether or not the income generated creates real economic activity<br />

there. The revenue cost of the credit is very high, <strong>and</strong> the tax saved<br />

per worker employed greatly exceeds the cost of employing that<br />

individual. In the long run, with a low-rate, broad-based tax, <strong>and</strong><br />

the deferral of U.S. tax on the earnings of <strong>for</strong>eign corporations, the<br />

special tax preference <strong>for</strong> income from the possessions should be<br />

phased out. In the meanwhile, the credit would be revised to relate<br />

it directly to the minimum wage <strong>for</strong> employees engaged in manufacturing<br />

activities in the possessions, <strong>and</strong> to allow the credit to be used<br />

against income from any source, not only possessions source income.<br />

These proposed changes are intended to bring the incentive more into<br />

line with its purpose, as stated by the Joint Committee on <strong>Tax</strong>ation,<br />

to "assist the U.S. possessions in obtaining employment-producing<br />

investments by U.S. corporations." The existing systems of taxation<br />

in effect in the U.S. territories also would be modified to resolve<br />

the inconsistencies <strong>and</strong> problems which have developed.<br />

Finally, the taxation of income earned by <strong>for</strong>eign corporations<br />

through u.S. branches would be rationalized to bring it more into line<br />

with the taxation of income earned through U.S. subsidiaries, <strong>and</strong><br />

certain rules concerning <strong>for</strong>eiqn currency transactions would be<br />

clarified.<br />

VI.<br />

Other <strong>Tax</strong> Issues<br />

A. Transfer <strong>Tax</strong>ation <br />

Transfers of wealth are subject to tax at the Federal level under<br />

an estate tax, a gift tax <strong>and</strong> a generation-skipping transfer (GST)<br />

tax. Transfers of wealth at death are subject to the estate tax,<br />

which is imposed at slightly progressive rates (with a large exemption<br />

level). The gift tax <strong>and</strong> the GST tax are designed on the whole to


- 145 -<br />

ensure that taxpayers cannot easily avoid the estate tax through<br />

lifetime gifts, multigenerational trusts, <strong>and</strong> similar arrangements.<br />

Ideally, the Federal transfer tax system should have as little<br />

impact as possible on the ways that individuals hold <strong>and</strong> transfer<br />

their wealth. In order to achieve this goal, the transfer tax system<br />

must be designed so that the amount of wealth that can be transferred<br />

from one individual to another net of tax does not depend on the <strong>for</strong>m<br />

or timing of the transfer. This requires close coordination among the<br />

three transfer taxes as well as attention to their interaction with<br />

the income tax.<br />

Major steps toward this goal were taken in 1976 with the unification<br />

of the estate <strong>and</strong> gift taxes <strong>and</strong> the enactment of the GST tax.<br />

Significant inequities <strong>and</strong> loopholes remain, however, leaving substantial<br />

opportunities <strong>for</strong> tax avoidance <strong>and</strong>, in some cases, resulting<br />

in double taxation. The principal thrust of the Treasury Department<br />

proposals <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m of the transfer tax system is to eliminate these<br />

inequities, thereby improving the fairness <strong>and</strong> neutrality of the<br />

system.<br />

Perhaps the most significant of these proposals is to complete the<br />

unification of the estate <strong>and</strong> gift tax systems by con<strong>for</strong>ming the<br />

computation of the gift tax base to that of the estate tax. Also of<br />

major importance is the proposal to replace the present GST tax with a<br />

new GST tax along the lines of Treasury Department's proposal of April<br />

1983. Together, these changes will assure that the <strong>for</strong>m of ownership<br />

<strong>and</strong> transfer of assets within a family will play a greatly reduced<br />

role in determining the transfer taxes paid by that family.<br />

These proposals are approximately revenue-neutral, even though<br />

they will result in a broader transfer tax base over the longer run.<br />

However, since transfer taxes are imposed on accumulations of wealth<br />

only once in each generation, the revenue effects of the base<br />

broadening will be felt only gradually. Hence, it is not possible to<br />

propose any reduction in transfer tax rates at the present time. Once<br />

the new rules are in place <strong>and</strong> the effects of the transition rules<br />

have been phased out, rate reductions may be possible. These will<br />

make the transfer tax system an even less obtrusive factor in taxpayers'<br />

decisions as to how to hold <strong>and</strong> transfer their wealth <strong>and</strong> will<br />

furher increase productivity <strong>and</strong> invention.<br />

These proposals also permit a number of simplifications in the<br />

transfer tax system. In particular, the rules relating to when a<br />

transfer is treated as complete, when a prior gift is included in the<br />

transferor's estate, <strong>and</strong> the power-of-appointment rules can be greatly<br />

simplified. Under the proposed rules, most transfers would be subject<br />

to the transfer tax system only once in each generation, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

number of occasions when a transfer would have to be valued on the<br />

basis of actuarial tables would be significantly reduced.<br />

One final major aspect of the transfer tax proposal relates to the<br />

timing of the payment of the estate tax. Under current law, many


- 146 -<br />

estates that have adequate cash to pay the Federal estate tax are<br />

nevertheless entitled to pay the tax in installments, with a preferred<br />

interest rate applicable to part of the deferred payment. On the<br />

other h<strong>and</strong>, some truly illiquid estates are denied the right to<br />

deferred payment. The proposal would alleviate this inequity by<br />

replacing the complex test of current law with a relatively simple<br />

test allowing an estate to pay its estate tax liability in<br />

installments based on its relative holding of liquid <strong>and</strong> illiquid<br />

assets. A market rate of interest on any deferred tax payments would<br />

be charged to ensure that the exp<strong>and</strong>ed liquidity relief provision is<br />

fair <strong>and</strong> revenue neutral.<br />

B. Penalties <br />

The numerous civil penalties imposed under current law <strong>for</strong> the<br />

violation of reporting <strong>and</strong> payment provisions are complex <strong>and</strong> often<br />

inconsistent in the treatment of similar violations. Moreover,<br />

because interest is not charged, current law provides,no incentive <strong>for</strong><br />

the timely payment of penalties. The proposal consolidates many of<br />

the in<strong>for</strong>mation-reporting penalties into one provision with uni<strong>for</strong>m<br />

penalty amounts. This would simplify administration of the penalty<br />

provisions <strong>and</strong> ensure their fair application. The proposal also<br />

assesses interest on delinquent penalty amounts in order to encourage<br />

timely payment.<br />

C. Expiring Provisions <br />

The following special tax provisions are scheduled to expire by<br />

1988: residential <strong>and</strong> business energy credits, the targeted jobs<br />

credit, the credit <strong>for</strong> testing orphan drugs, the special expensing<br />

rule <strong>for</strong> expenditures to remove architectural barriers to the elderly<br />

<strong>and</strong> h<strong>and</strong>icapped, the exclusions of employer-provided legal services,<br />

educational assistance, <strong>and</strong> van-pooling, <strong>and</strong> the special treatment of<br />

dividends reinvested in public utility stock. The Treasury Department<br />

proposes that these provisions be allowed to expire as scheduled.<br />

Several of these expiring provisions give preferred treatment to<br />

specific sectors, contrary to the spirit of neutrality. Others have<br />

outlived their usefulness. Most are believed to have had little<br />

effect on behavior or to provide only a weak incentive <strong>for</strong> the<br />

preferred activity. The credit <strong>for</strong> research <strong>and</strong> experimentation<br />

expenditures, however, would be extended <strong>for</strong> three years <strong>and</strong> targeted<br />

more effectively toward productivity-enhancing innovations.<br />

D. Social Security Issues <br />

Although the tax proposals presented by the Treasury Department<br />

deal primarily with the individual income tax, they would also have<br />

beneficial effects on the social security system. Within a few years<br />

after enactment, social security revenues would rise by about $5<br />

billion. The longer run impact, while harder to measure, will<br />

ultimately prove to be much more important. The increasing use of<br />

fringe benefits over the past few decades has led social security


<strong>for</strong>ecasters to predict continual declines in the taxable wage base<br />

relative to total compensation paid to workers. The long-run impact<br />

on the Social Security <strong>and</strong> Disability Trust Funds (which are now<br />

nearly in long-run blance) will be minor since benefits, as well as<br />

revenues, will be increased. However, the long-run impact on the<br />

Medicare Trust Fund will be measurable, since revenues will be<br />

increased without creating additional liabilities. Moreover, the cap<br />

on the exclusion of employer-provided health insurance will help stop<br />

the upward spiral of the cost of health care. This, too, will help<br />

reduce the cost of Medicare <strong>and</strong> other government-provided health<br />

programs.<br />

E. Items Not Included in the <strong>Tax</strong> <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong> Proposal<br />

Despite its comprehensi,venature, this study proposes no change in<br />

many sections of the tax Code. In some cases, this reflects the<br />

belief that current law is appropriate. In other cases, however,<br />

changes may be desirable, but specifying the appropriate changes will<br />

require more time <strong>for</strong> detailed analysis. There<strong>for</strong>e, t!ie fqct- that no<br />

change is preposed in a particular area should not be interpi:eted as<br />

Treasury endorsement of current law.<br />

This Report proposes no change in the iil3mized deductions <strong>for</strong><br />

mortgage interest on the taxpayer's principal residence, medjcal<br />

expenses, <strong>and</strong> casualty losses. In addition, extraordinary charitable<br />

contributions would remain deductible. No change is proposed in the<br />

current provisions which exclude all or part of each of the following<br />

from tax: soci,alsecurity benefits; income-conditioned transfers; inkind<br />

benefits; certain hard-to-value fringe benefits; employerprovided<br />

meals <strong>and</strong> lodging; personal injury awards; capital gains on<br />

appreciated assets transferred at death or by gift; capital gains on<br />

owner-occupied housing; earned income of U.S. citizens working abroad;<br />

<strong>and</strong> interest on state <strong>and</strong> local government bonds <strong>for</strong> "governmental"<br />

purposes. In addition, preferential tax treatment of IRAs <strong>and</strong> most<br />

retirement plans would be exp<strong>and</strong>ed, most employer-provided health<br />

insurance <strong>and</strong> most scholarships would remain untaxed, the earned<br />

income tax credit would be maintained <strong>and</strong> indexed, the credit <strong>for</strong> the<br />

elderly <strong>and</strong> disabled would be exp<strong>and</strong>ed <strong>and</strong> macle available to the<br />

blind, <strong>and</strong> income averaging would still be available <strong>for</strong> most<br />

taxpayers.<br />

Other provisions <strong>for</strong> which no changes are proposed include the<br />

following: subchapter S; corporate mergers, acquisitions,<br />

liquidations <strong>and</strong> reorganizations; export incentives (including FSC);<br />

deferral of tax on earnings of <strong>for</strong>eign corporations; rules <strong>for</strong> net<br />

operating losses; rules <strong>for</strong> pooled passive investment trusts; the<br />

accumulated earnings tax; rules <strong>for</strong> determining eligibility <strong>for</strong> the<br />

dependency exemption, marital status, <strong>and</strong> head-of-household status;<br />

related-party <strong>and</strong> attribution rules; rules governing the exemption of<br />

certain organizations from tax; <strong>and</strong> the tax treatment of cooperatives<br />

<strong>and</strong> their patrons <strong>and</strong> of partners <strong>and</strong> partnerships (except <strong>for</strong> limited<br />

partnerships irith more than 35 partners).


- 149 -<br />

APPENDIX 7 4<br />

LIST OF PROPOSED REFORPIS<br />

INDUSTRY--SPECIFIC SUBSIDIES, T.9x<br />

SHELTERS, AND OTHER TAX ISSUES<br />

A, General ISSU~Sof Income Heasuzement<br />

1. Match expenses <strong>and</strong> receipts from multiperiod production. <br />

2. Restrict use of cash accounting method.<br />

3. Limit bad debt deductions to actual loan losses. <br />

4. Disallow installment sales treatment when receivables are<br />

pledged.<br />

5. Repeal corporate minimum tax (only if basic re<strong>for</strong>ms are fully<br />

implemented).<br />

___ Subsidies DL Specific Industries<br />

1. Energy <strong>and</strong> Natural Resource Subsidies <br />

a. Repeal windfall profits tax. <br />

b. Repeal percentage depletion; use cost depletion, adjusted<br />

<strong>for</strong> inflation. <br />

C. Repeal expensing of intangible drilling costs. <br />

d. Reoeal - exoensinq- - of qualified .<br />

tertiary injectant<br />

expenses.<br />

e. Reoeal expensinq- of hard mineral exploration <strong>and</strong> developmekt<br />

cost;.<br />

f. Repeal special treatment of royalty income. <br />

9. Repeal special rules <strong>for</strong> mining reclamation reserves. <br />

h. Repeal non-conventional fuel production tax credit, alco­<br />

hol fuels credit <strong>and</strong> excise tax exemption. <br />

2. Special Rules of Financial Institutions<br />

a. Commercial banks <strong>and</strong> thrift institutions <br />

1. Repeal special bad debt deductions <strong>for</strong> banks <strong>and</strong> <br />

thrift institutions. <br />

2. Disallow 100% of interest incurred to carry taxexempt<br />

bonds by depository institutions.<br />

3. Repeal tax exemption of credit unions. <br />

4. Repeal special carryover rules, <strong>and</strong> repeal special <br />

merger rules <strong>for</strong> thrift institutions. <br />

b. Life Insurance Companies <br />

1. Limit life insurance reserve deductions to the in-<br />

crease in policyholders' cash surrender value. <br />

2. Repeal special deduction of percentage of taxable<br />

income of life insurance companies.


~<br />

- 150 -<br />

3. Repeal tax exemption <strong>for</strong> certain insurance companies.<br />

c. Property <strong>and</strong> Casualty (P&C) Insurance Companies <br />

1. Limit P&C reserves to the discounted present value of <br />

future liabilities. <br />

2. Repeal mutual P&C insurance companies' deduction <strong>for</strong><br />

additions to protection against loss account.<br />

3. Limit deductibility of P&C policyholder dividends.<br />

4. Repeal special tax exemption, rate reductions, <strong>and</strong> <br />

deductions of small mutual P&C insurance companies. <br />

3. Insurance Investment Income<br />

a. Repeal exclusion of investment income on life insurance<br />

policies.<br />

b. Treat policyholder loans as coming first from any taxexempt<br />

inside buildup.<br />

c. Repeal exclusion of current annuity income. <br />

4. State <strong>and</strong> Local Government Debt <strong>and</strong> Investments <br />

a. Repeal the tax exemption of nongovernmental purpose<br />

tax-exempt bonds.<br />

b. Tighten restrictions on tax arbitrage <strong>and</strong> adbance refunding<br />

<strong>for</strong> tax-exempt bonds.<br />

5. Special Expensing <strong>and</strong> Amortization Rules<br />

a. Repeal expensing of soil <strong>and</strong> water conservation expend­<br />

itures, expenditures by farmers <strong>for</strong> fertilizer <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> <br />

clearing fields. <br />

b. Repeal 5-year amortization of expenditures <strong>for</strong> rehabili­<br />

tation of low income rental housing. <br />

c. Repeal 5-year amortization of certified pollution control <br />

facilities. <br />

d. Repeal 50-year amortization of railroad grading <strong>and</strong><br />

tunnel bores.<br />

e. Repeal 5-year amortization of trademark expenses.<br />

f. Repeal 84-month amortization of re<strong>for</strong>estation expenditures<br />

<strong>and</strong> 10% tax credit <strong>for</strong> such expenditures.<br />

6. Other Specific Subsidies <br />

a. Repeal rehabilitation tax credits. <br />

b. Repeal special rules <strong>for</strong> returns of magazines <strong>and</strong> paper-<br />

back books <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> qualified discount coupons. <br />

c. Repeal exclusion relating to Nerchant Marine Capital Constuction<br />

Fund.<br />

d. Rationalize credit <strong>for</strong> research <strong>and</strong> experimentation.


- 151 -<br />

C. Further Curtailment of <strong>Tax</strong> Shelters <br />

1. Disallow most current interest deductions (with carry<strong>for</strong>ward)<br />

in excess of the sum of mortgage interest on the taxpayer's<br />

principal residence, invest,mentincome, income from limited <br />

partnerships <strong>and</strong> S corporations, <strong>and</strong> $5,000. <br />

2. Extend at risk limitations to real estate <strong>and</strong> equipment<br />

leasing.<br />

I). International Issues <br />

1. Change <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit limitation to a separate per coun-. <br />

try limitation. <br />

2. Modify rules defining source of income derived from sales of<br />

inventory-type property <strong>and</strong> intangible property.<br />

3. Repeal the secondary dividend rule <strong>and</strong> replace with a branch<br />

profits tax.<br />

4. Repeal special preference <strong>for</strong> 80/20 corporations.<br />

5. Repeal possessions tax credit <strong>and</strong> replace with phased out <br />

wage credit. <br />

6. Clarify treatment of certain transactions in <strong>for</strong>eign <br />

currency. <br />

E. Other <strong>Tax</strong> Issues <br />

1. Transfer <strong>Tax</strong>ation <br />

a<br />

b<br />

C<br />

d<br />

Unify estate <strong>and</strong> gift tax structure by grossing up the <br />

tax on gifts, <strong>and</strong> simplify rules <strong>for</strong> determining when a <br />

transfer is complete <strong>for</strong> gift tax purposes.<br />

Simplify taxation of generation-skipping transfers, <strong>and</strong><br />

modify credit <strong>for</strong> tax on prior transfers to a lower generation.<br />

Impose a rule to prevent abuse of minority discounts. <br />

Replace the rules governing payment of estate tax in <br />

installments with simplified rules based on estate li­<br />

quidity, but make interest incurred by an estate non-<br />

deductible <strong>for</strong> estate tax purposes. <br />

e. Reduce estate tax deduction <strong>for</strong> claims against an estate<br />

by the amount of income tax savings from payment of the<br />

expense.<br />

f. Simplify state death tax credit by making it a flat per­<br />

centage of fedetal estate tax collected. <br />

g. Repeal special tax rules <strong>for</strong> redemption of stock to pay<br />

death taxes. <br />

h. Tighten rules regarding powers of appointment.


- 152 -<br />

2. Penalties <br />

a. simplify in<strong>for</strong>mation return penalties.<br />

b. Repeal maximum limits on penalties. <br />

c. Replace failure-to-pay penalty with a cost-of-collection <br />

charges. <br />

3. Expiring Provisions <br />

a. Residential <strong>and</strong> certain business energy tax credits. <br />

b. Targeted jobs tax credit. <br />

C. Expensing of expenditures to remove architectural <br />

barriers to the elderly <strong>and</strong> h<strong>and</strong>icapped.<br />

d. Credit <strong>for</strong> testing orphan drugs. <br />

e. Speciai treatment <strong>for</strong> dividend reinvestment in public<br />

utility stock. <br />

f. Exclusion of employer-provided legal servic?. <br />

g. Exclusion of employer-provided educational assistance. <br />

h. Exclusion of employer-provided van-pooling.


- 153 -<br />

Chapter 8<br />

COMPARISON WITH OTHER TAX REFORM PLANS <br />

Over the past several years many proposals <strong>for</strong> tax re<strong>for</strong>m have<br />

been advanced by members of the U.S. Congress. These include<br />

proposals <strong>for</strong> a pure flat tax, a modified flat tax, a tax on consumed<br />

income, <strong>and</strong> a value-added tax. All of these plans share common<br />

objectives: to broaden the tax base <strong>and</strong> lower rates <strong>and</strong> thereby make<br />

the tax system fairer, simpler, <strong>and</strong> more neutral in its impact on the<br />

private economy. The same objectives motivated the Treasury<br />

Department study.<br />

The Treasury Department proposals <strong>for</strong> tax simplification <strong>and</strong><br />

re<strong>for</strong>m combine many of the best features of these Congressional plans<br />

<strong>for</strong> tax re<strong>for</strong>m. They go further in measuring taxable income<br />

comprehensively <strong>and</strong> consistently at both the corporate <strong>and</strong> individual<br />

levels. They deal more completely with problems of tax shelters <strong>and</strong><br />

abuses -- a growing threat to the tax system -- <strong>and</strong> address in greater<br />

detail the need to simplify the income tax. In short, though the<br />

Treasury Department plan draws heavily on the pioneering ef<strong>for</strong>ts by<br />

many members of Congress <strong>and</strong> by others, it goes further in achieving<br />

the m<strong>and</strong>ate to design a tax system that is broad-based, simple, <strong>and</strong><br />

fair.<br />

Two of the earliest <strong>and</strong> most detailed of the congressional<br />

proposals are those by Representative Jack Kemp <strong>and</strong> Senator Robert<br />

Kasten <strong>for</strong> a "Fair <strong>and</strong> Simple <strong>Tax</strong>" (S. 2948; H.R. 6165) <strong>and</strong> by Senator<br />

Bill Bradley <strong>and</strong> Representative Richard Gephardt <strong>for</strong> a "Fair <strong>Tax</strong>"<br />

(S. 1472; H.R. 3271). These bills include most of the specific<br />

proposals <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m contained in the other bills offered by members<br />

of Congress. This chapter compares the most important features of the<br />

Treasury Department proposals with those of the Kemp-Kasten <strong>and</strong><br />

Bradley-Gephardt plans. More detailed <strong>and</strong> more comprehensive<br />

comparisons with these <strong>and</strong> other congressional plans are provided in<br />

the appendices to this chapter.<br />

Like the discussion of tax re<strong>for</strong>m proposals in chapters 5, 6, <strong>and</strong><br />

7, the comparison of the Treasury Department, Bradley-Gephardt, <strong>and</strong><br />

Kemp-Kasten proposals is divided into provisions that affect virtually<br />

all individuals, regardless of whether they have important amounts of<br />

capital. or business income (section I), those that pertain almost<br />

exclusively to the basic taxation of capital <strong>and</strong> business income,<br />

including the tax treatment of retirement savings <strong>and</strong> the taxation of<br />

corporations <strong>and</strong> partnerships (section II), <strong>and</strong> those that pertain to<br />

specific industries <strong>and</strong> tax shelters (section 111), <strong>and</strong> those that<br />

pertain to other tax issues, including the taxation of transfers <strong>and</strong><br />

provisions that are currently planned to expire (section IV).


I. Individual Income <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

A. Income <strong>Tax</strong> Rates <br />

- 154 -<br />

One of the primary objectives of the Treasury Department study of <br />

tax simplification <strong>and</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m has been to broaden the income tax base <br />

enough that a given amount of revenue can be raised with substantially<br />

lower tax rates than under current law. This important objective is <br />

shared by the Kemp-Kasten <strong>and</strong> Bradley-Gephardt proposals, <strong>and</strong>, indeed,<br />

by all of the proposals <strong>for</strong> fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m that have been <br />

introduced in the Congress. <br />

Under the Treasury Department proposals all income of individuals<br />

above the tax-free amount will be taxed at three rates, 15 percent, 25<br />

percent, <strong>and</strong> 35 percent. Real capital gains -- that is, gains after<br />

adjustment <strong>for</strong> inflation -- will be taxed as ordinary income. By<br />

comparison, the Bradley-Gephardt proposal will impose three tax rates,<br />

14 percent, 26 percent, <strong>and</strong> 30 percent. This rate graduation will be<br />

achieved by levying the 14 percent rate on all income <strong>and</strong> surtaxes of<br />

12 <strong>and</strong> 16 percent on incomes above certain levels. Nominal capital<br />

gains will be taxed as ordinary income, without adjustment <strong>for</strong><br />

inflation.<br />

The Kemp-Kasten proposal contains only one statutory rate, 25<br />

percent. However, 20 percent of "earned income" -- wage <strong>and</strong> salary<br />

income <strong>and</strong> income from sole proprietorships <strong>and</strong> farms -- up to the<br />

social security ceiling ($39,600 in 1985), will be exempt from tax.<br />

(For this purpose the first $10,000 of income of single taxpayers <strong>and</strong><br />

$15,000 of income of a married couple with income below those levels<br />

is assumed to be earned income, even if it is from capital or business.<br />

These amounts are indexed <strong>for</strong> inflation.) That exemption is<br />

then phased out (at an income level of $102,960). Because this<br />

exemption is phased out, there is, in effect, a 20 percent rate on<br />

earned income up to the social security ceiling, a 28 percent rate<br />

over the phase-out range of income, <strong>and</strong> then a flat rate of 25 percent<br />

on income above the phase-out range.<br />

8. <strong>Fairness</strong> <strong>for</strong> Families<br />

Under current law, the personal exemption <strong>for</strong> taxpayers <strong>and</strong><br />

dependents <strong>for</strong> 1985 will be $1,040 per person (allowing <strong>for</strong><br />

indexation, which begins January, 1985); the elderly <strong>and</strong> the blind<br />

receive an additional $1,040 exemption. Under the Treasury Department<br />

proposals the taxpayer <strong>and</strong> dependent exemptions will be increased to<br />

$2,000 per person in 1986. The extra exemptions <strong>for</strong> the elderly <strong>and</strong><br />

the blind will be folded into an exp<strong>and</strong>ed credit <strong>for</strong> the elderly,<br />

blind, <strong>and</strong> disabled, so that the tax-free amount <strong>for</strong> the elderly will<br />

be increased slightly. The Kemp-Kasten proposal follows a similar<br />

approach, raising the taxpayer <strong>and</strong> dependent exemptions to $2,000; it<br />

will also increase the additional exemptions <strong>for</strong> the elderly <strong>and</strong> the<br />

blind to $2,000. The Bradley-Gephardt proposal distinguishes between<br />

personal exemptions <strong>for</strong> the taxpayer <strong>and</strong> spouse, which it sets at<br />

$1,600 (or $1,800 <strong>for</strong> a head of household), <strong>and</strong> those <strong>for</strong> dependents,


- 155 -<br />

the elderly, <strong>and</strong> the blind; the latter are set at $1,000. The<br />

Bradley-Gephardt plan allows personal exemptions to be deducted in<br />

computing income taxed at the 14 percent rate, but not <strong>for</strong> computing<br />

income subject to the 12 percent <strong>and</strong> 16 percent surtaxes.<br />

Under current law the zero-bracket amount in 1986 is estimated to<br />

be $2,510 <strong>for</strong> individuals, $2,510 <strong>for</strong> heads of households, <strong>and</strong> $3,710<br />

<strong>for</strong> joint returns. Under the Treasury Department proposals these<br />

amounts will be increased to $2,800, $3,500, <strong>and</strong> $3,800, respectively.<br />

By comparison, the Kemp-Kasten proposal (after indexing to 1986<br />

levels) increases them to $2,950, $2,950, <strong>and</strong> $3,820, respectively,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the Bradley-Gephardt proposal increases them to $3,000, $3,000,<br />

<strong>and</strong> $6,000. For a family of four filing a joint return <strong>and</strong> receiving<br />

only income from employment, the tax-free amount -- the level of<br />

income at which tax liability begins (including the earned income<br />

credit) -- would be $11,800 under the Treasury proposal, $11,200 under<br />

the Bradley-Gephardt proposal, <strong>and</strong> $15,675 under the Kemp-Kasten<br />

approach. Under current law a family of four will incur no income tax<br />

liability until adjusted gross income exceeds $9,613 (after indexing<br />

<strong>for</strong> the increase in prices projected <strong>for</strong> 1985).<br />

The Treasury Department proposals retain the indexati.on of the<br />

zero.-bracket amount, personal exemptions, <strong>and</strong> rate brackets that<br />

becomes effective on January 1, 1985. Without indexation inflation<br />

will continue to give rise to "bracket creep" that causes taxpayers<br />

with unchanged real incomes to pay increasingly higher rates of tax.<br />

Lack of indexation also allows inflation to lower real tax-exempt<br />

levels of income <strong>and</strong> impose taxes on persons in poverty. Whereas the<br />

Kemp-Kasten proposal also retains indexation, the Bradley-Gephardt<br />

proposal will repeal it. The Treasury Department <strong>and</strong> Kemp-Kasten<br />

proposals will also extend indexation to the dollar limits of the<br />

earned income tax credit.<br />

The choice of personal exemptions <strong>and</strong> zero-bracket amounts <br />

involves conflict between several competing goals. First are revenue <br />

considerations. Higher tax-exempt levels reduce revenues <strong>and</strong> require<br />

higher tax rates to reach a given revenue goal. In some proposals<br />

there is a tendency to raise taxes more E3r middle-income taxpayers to <br />

accomplish greltter reduction at lower income levels. <br />

Second, if personal exemptions <strong>and</strong> the ZBA are set in such a way<br />

that the tax threshold closely resembles the poverty level of income<br />

<strong>for</strong> taxpaying units of various types, a marriage penalty is produced.<br />

The marriage penalty occurs because at any level of income two persons<br />

living together have lower expenses than two single persons living<br />

alone. Thus two single persons living alone at the poverty level have<br />

an aggregate tax-free amount greater than a married couple at the<br />

poverty level, if the tax-free amount tracks the poverty level. If,<br />

on the other h<strong>and</strong>, the tax threshold <strong>for</strong> a married couple is set equal<br />

to the poverty line, a tax threshold <strong>for</strong> single persons of only half<br />

that amount will fall short of the poverty level of income <strong>for</strong> a<br />

sinole person.


- 156 -<br />

A third objective is to make adjustments according to family size <br />

<strong>for</strong> ability to pay. Personal <strong>and</strong> dependent exemptions are the primary <br />

means of accomplishing this goal. The Treasury Department plan, as <br />

well as the Kemp-Kasten proposal, recognizes the need to adjust<br />

personal exemptions <strong>for</strong> inflation. The Bradley-Gephardt proposal<br />

makes no adjustment in the dependent's exemption <strong>and</strong>, in fact, through<br />

lack of indexing allows the real value of current dependent's<br />

exemption to decrease. <br />

In its proposals the Treasury Department has attempted to balance <br />

the competing objectives of eliminating the marriage penalty, tracking <br />

poverty levels of income, not raising the tax on single persons too <br />

high relative to that on one-earner married couples, <strong>and</strong> adjusting<br />

appropriately <strong>for</strong> family size. The Treasury Department proposal, the <br />

Bradley-Gephardt proposal, <strong>and</strong> the Kemp-Kasten proposal will all <br />

repeal the two-earner deduction, which is needed less, once the rate <br />

structure is less steeply graduated. <br />

C. Fair <strong>and</strong> Neutral <strong>Tax</strong>ation <br />

If the U.S. tax system is to be made fair <strong>and</strong> more neutral, the <br />

tax base must be defined comprehensively. Base broadening under the <br />

Treasury Department proposals comes from three major sources: taxing<br />

currently excluded <strong>for</strong>ms of income, curtailment of existing tax <br />

subsidies to particular uses of income via itemized deductions, <strong>and</strong> <br />

limitations on existing abuses of the tax system. <br />

1. Excluded sources of income. Fringe benefits provided by<br />

employers represent substantial amounts of real income that are <br />

excluded from the tax base. These are commonly divided into two <br />

groups, statutory <strong>and</strong> non-statutory, to reflect the fact that the <br />

<strong>for</strong>mer are explicitly excluded from taxation by law, whereas the <br />

latter have only been excluded by custom. This terminology is still <br />

useful, even though the Deficit Reduction Act of 1984 extended <br />

statutory exemption to certain of the non-statutory fringe benefits. <br />

The most important statutory fringe benefit excluded from the tax<br />

base is premiums on accident <strong>and</strong> health insurance provided by<br />

employers. Other statutorily excluded fringe benefits include groupterm<br />

life insurance, dependent care services, <strong>and</strong> certain living<br />

allowances. Under the Treasury Department proposals, most statutory<br />

fringe benefits will be taxed, with exceptions or limitations when<br />

amounts are small <strong>and</strong> valuation is difficult. Employer contributions<br />

to health plans will be taxed only to the extent that they exceed $70<br />

per month <strong>for</strong> an individual employee <strong>and</strong> $175 per month <strong>for</strong> family<br />

coverage; these floors will be indexed to protect their real value<br />

from inflation. The Bradley-Gephardt proposals <strong>and</strong>, to some extent,<br />

the Kemp-Kasten proposals also include many major statutory fringe<br />

benefits in taxable income. Non-statutory fringe benefits (including<br />

those recently excluded by law) would not be taxed under any of the<br />

proposals.


- 157 -<br />

All three proposals will tax unemployment compensation; the<br />

Treasury Department <strong>and</strong> Kemp-Kasten proposals will generally tax<br />

workers' compensation, because it also serves as a wage replacement<br />

program. All three proposals will tax income received in the <strong>for</strong>m of<br />

scholarships <strong>and</strong> fellowships, but only to the extent that it exceeds<br />

tuition expenses. The increased tax thresholds provided by the higher<br />

personal exemptions <strong>and</strong> ZBA in the Treasury Department proposals will<br />

prevent the taxation of most low-income recipients of any of these<br />

benefits.<br />

2. Preferred uses of income. Major itemized deductions allowed<br />

under current law are <strong>for</strong> state <strong>and</strong> local taxes, charitable<br />

contributions, <strong>and</strong> interest expense. Deductions also are allowed <strong>for</strong><br />

medical expenses in excess of 5 percent of adjusted gross income<br />

(AGI), casualty losses in excess of 10 percent of AGI, <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

miscellaneous other expenditures, including costs of earning income<br />

not deducted elsewhere. The Treasury Department proposal will phase<br />

out completely the deduction <strong>for</strong> all state <strong>and</strong> local taxes.<br />

Charitable contributions will be deductible only to the extent they<br />

exceeded 2 percent of adjusted gross income; the deduction of<br />

charitable contributions by non-itemizers will be eliminated. The<br />

deduction <strong>for</strong> a charitable donation of appreciated property will be<br />

limited to the indexed basis. The existing deduction <strong>for</strong> medical expenses<br />

in excess of 5 percent of AGI <strong>and</strong> casualty losses in excess of<br />

10 percent of AGI will be left intact. The deduction <strong>for</strong> mortgage<br />

interest on the taxpayer's principal residence will be unchanged, but<br />

the deductibility of other personal interest expense will be reduced<br />

<strong>and</strong> limited <strong>for</strong> taxpayers with substantial interest expense in excess<br />

of realized capital income. Miscellaneous expenses of earning income<br />

will be combined with employee business expenses <strong>and</strong> made an "abovethe-line''<br />

adjustment, rather than an itemized deduction; this combined<br />

deduction will be limited to the excess of such expenses over 1<br />

percent of adjusted gross income. Placing this floor under itemized<br />

deductions <strong>for</strong> employee expenses will simplify compliance <strong>for</strong> many<br />

taxpayers <strong>and</strong> allow rates to be lowered further than if all expenses<br />

could be deducted.<br />

The Bradley-Gephardt proposals will retain the deduction <strong>for</strong> state <br />

<strong>and</strong> local taxes on income <strong>and</strong> real property, but eliminate itemized <br />

deductions <strong>for</strong> all other state <strong>and</strong> local taxes. The proposals will <br />

retain the itemized deductions <strong>for</strong> interest on home mortgages, but <br />

will substantially limit deductions <strong>for</strong> other personal interest. The <br />

itemized deductions <strong>for</strong> charitable contributions <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> casualty <strong>and</strong> <br />

theft losses will be retained, but that <strong>for</strong> medical expenses will be <br />

limited to expenditures in excess of 10 percent of adjusted gross<br />

income. <br />

Under the Bradley-Gephardt approach itemized deductions could be<br />

used only in calculating tax under the 14 percent rate; they will not<br />

be deductible against the 12 percent <strong>and</strong> 16 percent surtaxes that<br />

raise marginal rates to 26 percent <strong>and</strong> 30 percent. By allowing<br />

itemized deductions only <strong>for</strong> purposes of computing income taxed at the<br />

14 percent rate, the Bradley-Gephardt plan effectively converts<br />

459-370 0 - 84 - 7


- 158 -<br />

itemized deductions into 14 percent tax credits. This approach limits <br />

the tax value of deductible expenses to the same dollar amount <strong>for</strong> all <br />

taxpayers. If the purpose of the deduction is to provide a subsidy<br />

through the tax system, this approach is satisfactory. However, to <br />

the extent that itemized deductions help define economic income <br />

properly subject to tax, the full deduction should be allowed in <br />

computing income <strong>for</strong> purposes of the surtaxes as well. <br />

Under the Kemp-Kasten approach itemized deductions will be <br />

retained <strong>for</strong> interest on home mortgages <strong>and</strong> on educational loans, but <br />

not on other consumer debt, <strong>for</strong> state <strong>and</strong> local property <strong>and</strong> general<br />

sales taxes, <strong>for</strong> charitable contributions, <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> medical expenses in <br />

excess of 10 percent of adjusted gross income <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> casualty <strong>and</strong> <br />

theft losses. The deduction <strong>for</strong> state <strong>and</strong> local income taxes will be <br />

eliminated. <br />

D. <strong>Tax</strong> Abuses<br />

Some taxpayers improperly take business deductions <strong>for</strong> expenses<br />

that most Americans would view as personal expenses. In addition,<br />

various techniques are used by some taxpayers to shift income from<br />

themselves to their children, who are in lower tax brackets. For<br />

example, parents can transfer income-earning assets to their children<br />

or they can establish trusts that enable income to be subject to tax<br />

rates lower than those of the parents. Provisions in the Treasury<br />

Department proposal will prevent the claiming of business deductions<br />

<strong>for</strong> personal expenses <strong>and</strong> will limit the benefits of income shifting.<br />

Neither the Bradley-Gephardt proposal nor the Kemp-Kasten plan<br />

addresses these issues.<br />

E. Simplification <br />

The increases in the personal exemptions <strong>and</strong> zero-bracket amounts <br />

<strong>and</strong> the limitations on the availability of itemized deductions will <br />

simplify tax compliance <strong>for</strong> many Americans. With lower tax rates <br />

taxpayers will have less incentive to find deductible expenditures <strong>and</strong> <br />

because fewer deductions are available, they will have less need <strong>for</strong> <br />

recordkeeping. <br />

1. The return-free system. Because of its increased capability of<br />

processing withholding <strong>and</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mation returns, the Internal Revenue<br />

Service will soon have improved capability of calculating tax<br />

liabilities <strong>for</strong> many Americans. As a result, the Treasury Department<br />

is proposing that the United States begin to test a "return-free<br />

system," under which many individual taxpayers will be relieved of the<br />

obligation of filing an income tax return. Instead, <strong>for</strong> taxpayers who<br />

certify that they only had certain sources of income <strong>and</strong> deductions,<br />

the Internal Revenue Service will send the taxpayer a report of tax<br />

calculation based on in<strong>for</strong>mation at its disposal. The taxpayer will<br />

then either accept the IRS report or indicate that additional<br />

in<strong>for</strong>mation will require filing of a regular return. Initially,<br />

eligibility <strong>for</strong> the return-free system will be limited to taxpayers<br />

who had only wages subject to withholding <strong>and</strong> interest income subject


- 159 -<br />

to in<strong>for</strong>mation reporting. Thus, an estimated 20 percent of returns to<br />

be filed by non-itemizers in 1988 might rely completely on returns<br />

originally prepared by the Internal Revenue Service. None of the<br />

other proposals <strong>for</strong> tax re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>and</strong> simplification include a returnfree<br />

system.<br />

2. Other simplification. The Bradley-Gephardt <strong>and</strong> Kemp-Kasten<br />

proposals share some of the simplification advantages of the Treasury<br />

proposals, but they leave intact many provisions that involve<br />

complexities <strong>for</strong> taxpayers. The Treasury Department proposals will<br />

repeal the credit <strong>for</strong> political contributions, the Presidential<br />

campaign checkoff, special 10-year averaging <strong>for</strong> lump-sum distributions,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the 3-year rule <strong>for</strong> recovery of retirement contributions.<br />

It will eliminate (or allow to expire) all existing tax credits, other<br />

than the <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit, the credit <strong>for</strong> research <strong>and</strong><br />

experimentation, <strong>and</strong> the earned income tax credit. It will simplify<br />

the tax treatment of pensions, it will unify <strong>and</strong> simplify existing<br />

penalties, <strong>and</strong> it will unify the substantive rules <strong>for</strong> the taxation of<br />

gifts <strong>and</strong> estates. The Bradley-Gephardt <strong>and</strong> Kemp-Kasten proposals<br />

would also eliminate most tax credits <strong>and</strong> the special 10-year<br />

averaging <strong>for</strong> lump-sum distributions. These plans generally do not<br />

address the tax treatment of pensions or the substantive rules <strong>for</strong> the<br />

taxation of gifts <strong>and</strong> estates, or alter tax penalties. The Treasury<br />

Department proposal will retain income averaging, except <strong>for</strong> those who<br />

have been students during the base period. Both the Bradley-Gephardt<br />

<strong>and</strong> Kemp-Kasten plans will repeal income averaging in its entirety.<br />

11. Basic <strong>Tax</strong>ation of Capital <strong>and</strong> Business Income <br />

Under current law capital <strong>and</strong> business income is subject to vastly<br />

different tax treatment, depending on its source. An important<br />

objective of the Treasury Department proposals is to make the tax<br />

treatment of business <strong>and</strong> capital income more uni<strong>for</strong>m. This will<br />

allow business decisions to be based more on economic reality, <strong>and</strong><br />

less on tax implications. Cutting corporate rates will further reduce<br />

the distortion of business decisions caused by the tax system.<br />

A. Corporate <strong>Tax</strong> Rates<br />

Under current law the marginal rate of tax paid on corporate<br />

income increases with the amount of income, reaching a maximum of 46<br />

percent at an income of $100,000. The Treasury Department proposals<br />

will replace this graduated rate structure with a flat rate of 33<br />

percent applied to all corporate income, including real capital gains<br />

of corporations. The Treasury Department proposals will retain the<br />

corporate minimum tax through 1992 <strong>and</strong> then phase it out over a threeyear<br />

period, if most tax preferences are eliminated as proposed. The<br />

Bradley-Gephardt proposals will levy a 30 percent corporate rate <strong>and</strong><br />

eliminate the corporate minimum tax. The Kemp-Kasten proposals will<br />

also subject most corporate income to a rate of 30 percent, but it<br />

will retain the corporate minimum tax, limit the tax rate on the first<br />

$50,000 of corporate income to 15 percent, <strong>and</strong> apply a 20 percent rate<br />

to capital gains of corporations.


- 160 -<br />

B. Investment <strong>Tax</strong> Credit <br />

The Treasury Department, as well as Bradley-Gephardt <strong>and</strong> Kemp-<br />

Kasten, proposes that the investment tax credit (ITC) be eliminated.<br />

The Treasury Department proposes repeal of the ITC because 1) the<br />

proposed system of capital recovery will compensate <strong>for</strong> inflation<br />

directly; 2) the current ITC discriminates against new businesses <strong>and</strong><br />

companies with losses; 3 ) the ITC is a major source of tax shelter<br />

<strong>for</strong>mation; <strong>and</strong> 4) administration of recapture rules with respect to<br />

the ITC i s quite difficult <strong>and</strong> subject to abuse. At current low rates<br />

of inflation, moreover, the investment tax credit distorts resource<br />

allocation <strong>and</strong> it will continue to do so if retained in the proposed<br />

system. Rate reduction provides a uni<strong>for</strong>m incentive <strong>for</strong> all<br />

corporations, <strong>and</strong> is there<strong>for</strong>e preferable to devices such as the<br />

investment tax credit, which is targeted to industries that are heavy<br />

producers or users of only the certain types of capital that benefit<br />

from the credit. Both the Bradley-Gephardt <strong>and</strong> Kemp-Kasten proposals<br />

will eliminate the credit <strong>for</strong> research <strong>and</strong> experimentation. The<br />

Treasury Department proposals will retain this credit, but restructure<br />

it to make it more effective.<br />

C. Income Measurement: Inflation Adjustment <br />

During periods of high inflation the current income tax causes<br />

capital income to be overstated <strong>and</strong> it causes interest deductions to<br />

be exaggerated. The result is misallocation of the nation's capital<br />

<strong>and</strong> undesirable incentives <strong>for</strong> borrowing <strong>and</strong> disincentives <strong>for</strong> saving.<br />

Current law reflects ef<strong>for</strong>ts to avoid these distortions <strong>and</strong> inequities<br />

by allowing recovery of capital more rapidly than it actually<br />

depreciates <strong>and</strong> by excluding part of nominal capital gains. These ad<br />

hoc adjustments are appropriate only <strong>for</strong> given rates of inflation. On<br />

the other h<strong>and</strong>, no adjustment is made <strong>for</strong> the effect of inflation in<br />

the calculation o f costs of goods sold from inventories or <strong>for</strong><br />

overstatement of interest income <strong>and</strong> expense resulting from inflation.<br />

The Treasury Department proposes to ameliorate these problems by<br />

allowing explicit inflation adjustment <strong>for</strong> depreciable assets,<br />

inventories, interest income <strong>and</strong> expense, <strong>and</strong> the calculation of<br />

capital gains. With the measurement of income improved by these<br />

adjustments <strong>for</strong> inflation, the ad hoc adjustments <strong>for</strong> depreciable<br />

assets <strong>and</strong> capital gains will no longer be needed. Thus, depreciation<br />

deductions can be made to correspond more closely to economic<br />

depreciation arid capital gains can be taxed as ordinary income.<br />

Expensing would, however, be allowed <strong>for</strong> the first $5,000 of<br />

depreciable business property. The deduction of capital losses will<br />

continue to be limited. The Treasury Department proposal will exclude<br />

from taxation a portion of interest income <strong>and</strong> disallow deduction of<br />

part of interest expense in excess of that on business indebtedness<br />

<strong>and</strong> mortgages on the taxpayer's principal residence, plus $5,000. The<br />

fraction of interest income <strong>and</strong> expense to be ignored in calculating<br />

taxable income will depend on the rate of inflation.


- 161 -<br />

The Kemp-Kasten proposal also includes indexation of the basis of <br />

capital gains <strong>and</strong> taxation of all capital gains of individuals as <br />

ordinary income, but it does not include inflation adjustment of <br />

depreciable assets. (It will continue the present Accelerated Cost <br />

Recovery System <strong>and</strong> the presently suspended ability of firms to <br />

expense up to $10,000 of assets each year.) The combination of <br />

inflation adjustment <strong>for</strong> capital gains <strong>and</strong> continued ad hoc adjustment<br />

of depreciation allowances could create technical difficulties <strong>and</strong> <br />

un<strong>for</strong>seen misallocation of economic resources. Moreover, the failure <br />

to index the cost of goods taken from inventories will continue the <br />

present tax discrimination against inventory-intensive industries. <br />

The Kemp-Kasten proposal will allow unlimited capital losses. It <br />

attempts to deal with the artificial minimization of taxes that is <br />

possible when losses on some assets may be recognized even though<br />

gains on other assets need not be recognized by treating capital<br />

losses as a preference item to be subject to the alternative minimum <br />

tax. <br />

The Bradley-Gephardt proposal eliminates the distinction between<br />

long-run <strong>and</strong> short-run capital gains by subjecting all nominal gains<br />

to taxation as ordinary income. This approach leaves the effective<br />

rate of taxation of real capital gains dependent upon the rate of<br />

inflation. As during the 1970s, effective rates could far exceed the<br />

statutory rate; they could go above 100 percent, <strong>and</strong> tax could be<br />

collected on real losses. <strong>Tax</strong>ing nominal gains as ordinary income<br />

could create substantial disincentives <strong>for</strong> investment, invention <strong>and</strong><br />

innovation, particularly in periods of high inflation. The<br />

Bradley-Gephardt proposal will apply 250 percent declining balance<br />

depreciation to assets classified under the Asset Depreciation Range<br />

System of depreciation, with no adjustment <strong>for</strong> inflation. As a<br />

result, it will be much too yenerous at low inflation rates, but not<br />

generous enough at high inflation rates. The Bradley-Gephardt<br />

approach will not index inventories or adjust the amount of interest<br />

to be included in income or allowed as an expense.<br />

All three proposals retain the rollover of capital gains on a<br />

principal residence: the Treasury Department <strong>and</strong> Kemp-Kasten<br />

proposals retain the $125,000 one-time exclusion of gains on the<br />

principal residence; the Bradley-Gephardt proposal does so only <strong>for</strong><br />

the purpose of computing income subject to tax at the 14 percent rate.<br />

D. Retirement Savings <br />

All three proposals leave intact the present tax treatment of <br />

individual retirement accounts (IRAs) <strong>and</strong> Keogh plans (retirement <br />

accounts <strong>for</strong> the self-employed). The Treasury Department proposal<br />

will make IRAs of spouses working in the home without pay subject to <br />

the same limits as those of employed taxpayers <strong>and</strong> raise the limit on <br />

tax-free contributions to IRAs. <br />

Al.1 three proposals essentially leave intact the present tax <br />

treatment of qualified pension plans <strong>and</strong> profit-sharing plans. To <br />

achieve administrative simplicity, the Treasury Department proposals


- 162 -<br />

will eliminate the combined limits on amounts contributed to defined <br />

benefit <strong>and</strong> defined contribution plans which are not top-heavy, but <br />

will impose an excise tax on the receipt of extraordinarily large<br />

benefits after retirement. The Bradley-Gephardt proposal, by<br />

comparison, nearly halves the limits under present law. Under the <br />

Kemp-Kasten proposal, the current limits will be retained. The <br />

Treasury Department proposals will unify various other provisions,<br />

including penalties <strong>for</strong> premature withdrawals by employees. <br />

E. Neutrality Toward the Form of Business Organization <br />

Under present law corporations <strong>and</strong> partnerships are subject to<br />

substantially different tax treatment. Partnerships, regardless of<br />

their size or other features, are taxed as pass-through entities; that<br />

is, there is no tax at the partnership level, <strong>and</strong> allvincome or losses<br />

are simply passed on to individual partners <strong>for</strong> inclusion in their tax<br />

returns. As a result, partnerships are used as important vehicles <strong>for</strong><br />

tax shelters, since they allow individuals to take deductions <strong>for</strong><br />

partnership losses against income earned from other sources. In the<br />

case of large partnerships, pass-through treatment can create severe<br />

collection <strong>and</strong> other administrative costs. In the event of a<br />

partnership audit, collection notices must be sent to the hundreds or<br />

thous<strong>and</strong>s of individual taxpayers who were owners of the partnership<br />

at the time the original, erroneous return was filed. Some of these<br />

taxpayers may have moved, some may be in substantially different<br />

circumstances, some may have died, <strong>and</strong> some may have sold their<br />

interests to others. Income earned by corporations, on the other<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, is subject to double taxation; corporate profits are taxed as<br />

earned <strong>and</strong> then dividends paid from after-tax income are taxed again<br />

when received by shareholders. One objective of the Treasury<br />

Department's study has been to make more consistent the treatment of<br />

partnerships <strong>and</strong> corporations which closely resemble one another.<br />

The Treasury Department proposals will provide a more consistent <br />

treatment of similarly situated corporations <strong>and</strong> partnerships through<br />

1) the reclassification of certain partnerships as corporations <strong>for</strong><br />

tax purposes, <strong>and</strong> 2 ) the reduction of the double tax on dividends<br />

paid. The reclassification proposal involves treating as a<br />

corporation any limited partnership that includes 35 or more limited<br />

partners. In addition, corporations will be allowed a deduction <strong>for</strong><br />

part of dividends paid. The dividends paid deduction will eliminate<br />

part of the double taxation of dividends, since the part of dividends<br />

allowed as a deduction to the corporation will be taxed only at the<br />

shareholder level.<br />

Neither the Bradley-Gephardt nor the Kemp-Kasten proposals deal <br />

with the important issue of unification of the tax treatment of <br />

partnerships <strong>and</strong> corporations. The Treasury Department <strong>and</strong> Bradley-<br />

Gephardt proposals will repeal both the personal holding company tax <br />

<strong>and</strong> the rules <strong>for</strong> collapsible corporations. The Bradley-Gephardt<br />

proposal repeals the accumulated earnings tax; the Treasury Department


- 163 -<br />

proposes to retain it. All three proposals will repeal the small<br />

exclusion <strong>for</strong> dividends received by shareholders ($100 <strong>for</strong> single <strong>and</strong><br />

separate returns; $200 <strong>for</strong> joint returns).<br />

111, Industry-Specific Subsidies, <strong>Tax</strong> Shelters, <strong>and</strong> Other <strong>Tax</strong> Issues <br />

A. General Issues of Income Measurement <br />

Because certain provisions of current law do not take adequate<br />

account of the timing of income receipts <strong>and</strong> payments, taxation of<br />

income can be deferred until future years. This tax deferral lowers<br />

the effective tax rate on the tax-preferred activity, distorts the<br />

allocation of investment across industries, <strong>and</strong> causes similarlysituated<br />

taxpayers to be treated differently.<br />

Current tax rules do not match taxable receipts <strong>and</strong> deductions <strong>for</strong><br />

activities that require several years to produce. Matching can be<br />

achieved if the costs of producing assets are capitalized, that is,<br />

includea in the basis of the asset <strong>and</strong> recovered (deducted) when the<br />

asset is sold or when the basis is depreciated. The rules requiring<br />

capitalization of expenses incurred in the construction of capital<br />

assets are incomplete <strong>and</strong> vary by type of activity. This treatment<br />

distorts the choice between purchased <strong>and</strong> self-constructed assets <strong>and</strong><br />

encourages tax shelters in multiperiod production activities.<br />

Under the Treasury Department proposals the capitalization rules <br />

will be reasonably comprehensive of all expenses <strong>and</strong> will be uni<strong>for</strong>m <br />

across activities. The other proposals will extend 10-year<br />

amortization of construction period interest <strong>and</strong> taxes to other <br />

business assets, but are not as comprehensive as the Treasury<br />

proposal. <br />

Under current law the gain on installment sales is not taxed until<br />

payments are received. Under the Treasury Department proposal, a<br />

taxpayer will not be entitled to use the installment sales method if<br />

the installment obligations are converted into cash by means of<br />

pledging or other arrangement, thereby eliminating the taxpayer's<br />

possible liquidity problem. The other two proposals do not change<br />

current law in this area.<br />

IJnder current law, taxpayers can generally elect to use either the <br />

cash or accrual methods of accounting. Although the accrual method of <br />

accounting is considered to be a more accurate measure of annual <br />

economic income, the cash method is administratively simpler <strong>for</strong> <br />

certain taxpayers. The option to use different accounting methods <br />

allows taxpayers to reduce taxes artificially by mismatching<br />

recognition of taxable income <strong>and</strong> deductions. The Treasury Department<br />

proposal will require the use of the accrual method by all large<br />

firms, by all firms using the accrual method <strong>for</strong> financial reporting,<br />

<strong>and</strong> by firms holding inventories. The other two proposals do not <br />

address this issue. The other two proposals will require accrual <br />

accounting <strong>for</strong> farming <strong>and</strong> timber where the taxpayer has gross<br />

receipts greater than $1 million.


- 164 -<br />

The preferential tax treatment of bad debt losses encourages<br />

lenders to make risky loans <strong>and</strong> favors debt over equity financing.<br />

The Treasury Department proposal will remove these distortions by<br />

repealing the deduction <strong>for</strong> additions to reserves <strong>for</strong> bad debt loan <br />

losses <strong>and</strong> limiting the bad debt lass deduction to the amount of the <br />

current loan losses. The Treasury Department proposal will apply to <br />

both financial <strong>and</strong> non-financial institutions. The other two <br />

proposals will change allowances <strong>for</strong> bad debt loan losses only <strong>for</strong> <br />

financial institutions. <br />

With these modifications of tax law, taxable income will resemble <br />

much more closely economic income. Ultimately, the present corporate<br />

minimum tax will be unnecessary <strong>and</strong> evenutally it should be <br />

eliminated. It should be retained, however, over an interim period<br />

during which previously made investments continue to benefit from <br />

preferences allowed under current law. Whereas the Bradley-Gephardt<br />

proposal will also eliminate the corporate minimum tax, the <br />

Kemp-Kasten proposal will retain it. <br />

E. Subsidies <strong>for</strong> Specific Industries <br />

The Treasury Department proposals will repeal numerous preferential<br />

cost recovery provisions designed to favor one <strong>for</strong>m of investment<br />

over another, or one industry over another. These special provisions<br />

operate as subsidies, altering economic decisions. Such subsidies are<br />

justified only if the subsidy corrects appropriately an otherwise<br />

incorrect market evaluation of costs <strong>and</strong> benefits. None of the<br />

subsidies to be repealed can be justified on these grounds. Moreover,<br />

since the subsidy they provide is in the <strong>for</strong>m of exclusion of income<br />

from tax, OK as tax deferral, these provisions unfairly benefit<br />

higher-income investors more than lower-income ones.<br />

1. Energy <strong>and</strong> Natural Resources. Under the Treasury Department<br />

vroposals expensinq of intanqible drilling costs in the oil <strong>and</strong> gas<br />

industry will be replaced by-depreciation-allowances,<strong>and</strong> percentage<br />

depletion will be replaced by cost depreciation. Indexing of the<br />

basis of non-depleted resources will be allowed. The Treasury<br />

Department proposal will also accelerate the phase-out of the windfall<br />

profit tax to 1988. The Bradley-Gephardt <strong>and</strong> Kemp-Kasten proposals<br />

will also eliminate percentage depletion, expensing of exploration <strong>and</strong><br />

development costs, <strong>and</strong> the deduction <strong>for</strong> intangible drilling costs,<br />

replacing them with ordinary depreciation. The Bradley-Gephardt <strong>and</strong><br />

Kemp-Kasten proposals, however, wil retain the windfall profit tax.<br />

I<br />

Under current law additions to reserves <strong>for</strong> strip mining<br />

reclamation can be deducted currently even though no expenditure has <br />

occurred. This tax treatment accelerates deductions <strong>for</strong> future <br />

expenses <strong>and</strong> lowers strip mining operators' effective tax rates <br />

through tax deferral. The Treasury Department proposal will require<br />

reclamation expenses to be deductible when the expenses have been paid <br />

OK economic per<strong>for</strong>mance has occurred. The other two proposals do not <br />

change current law.


- 165 -<br />

2. Financial institutions. Under current law various types of<br />

financial institutions (banks, thrift institutions, life insurance<br />

companies, <strong>and</strong> casualty insurance companies) are accorded a wide<br />

variety of preferential tax treatment. In effect, they are regulated<br />

through tax provisions that discourage competition. Besides<br />

discriminating in favor of investment in these institutions, relative<br />

to other investment alternatives, this patchwork treatment of<br />

preferences prevents the achievement of fair <strong>and</strong> neutral taxation,<br />

even within the financial sector. The Treasury Department proposals<br />

will make uni<strong>for</strong>m the tax treatment of various types of financial<br />

institutions <strong>and</strong> generally subject income earned in the financial<br />

sector to the same tax law applied elsewhere in the economy. The<br />

Treasury Department proposals will repeal special exclusions,<br />

deductions <strong>and</strong> tax rates <strong>for</strong> the different financial institutions,<br />

require discounting of banks' bad debt loss reserves <strong>and</strong> casualty<br />

insurance company reserves, <strong>and</strong> restrict life insurance company<br />

reserves to the increase in policyholders' cash surrender value. The<br />

other two proposals will only change the special bad debt deductions<br />

of commercial banks <strong>and</strong> thrift institutions.<br />

3. Insurance investment income. The exclusion of investment<br />

income ("inside" buildup) on life insurance policies <strong>and</strong> annuities is<br />

one of the major excluded sources of income. Interest income on<br />

savings held with other financial institutions is subject to tax<br />

whether or not the interest is currently distributed to the taxpayer.<br />

The tax-preferred treatment of the inside buildup encourages<br />

individuals to save through life insurance companies <strong>and</strong> perhaps to<br />

purchase life insurance that they would not buy except to gain access<br />

to the favorable tax treatment. All three proposals will tax the<br />

annual investment income earned on life insurance policies <strong>and</strong><br />

annuities.<br />

4. State <strong>and</strong> local debt <strong>and</strong> investments. Interest on debt issued<br />

by state <strong>and</strong> local governments (often called municipal bonds) has long<br />

been exempt from Federal income tax. In recent years the generally<br />

accepted exemption <strong>for</strong> general obligation bonds has been extended by<br />

state <strong>and</strong> local governments to "private purpose" activities --<br />

activities such as home mortgages, educational institutions,<br />

hospitals, <strong>and</strong> industrial development projects -- that might more<br />

appropriately be financed entirely from local funds, or through<br />

private credit markets without Federal exemption <strong>for</strong> interest. In an<br />

attempt to limit these abuses, the Deficit Reduction Act of 1984<br />

includes a limit of $150 per capita on issuance of private purpose<br />

obligations by any state <strong>and</strong> its subdivisions. Even worse, some state<br />

<strong>and</strong> local governments have used proceeds from their securities to<br />

engage in tax arbitrage, by investing them in private or Federal debt<br />

obligations that pay rates of interest in excess of the municipal bond<br />

rate because they are subject to Federal tax. Each state <strong>and</strong> locality<br />

is encouraged to engage in as much of these activities as possible,<br />

since the cost is borne primarily by taxpayers in other states <strong>and</strong><br />

localities. The result is an unproductive increase in Federal tax<br />

rates <strong>and</strong> shift in burdens of taxation between states. Residents of


- 166 --<br />

jurisdictions with cautious or conservative borrowing habits are<br />

e specia11y peria 1ized.<br />

The Treasury Department proposals will repeal the tax exemption of <br />

interest on private purpose bonds issued by state <strong>and</strong> local <br />

governments <strong>and</strong> tighten the restrictions on tax arbitrage <strong>and</strong> advance <br />

refunding related to tax-exempt bonds. Both the Bradley-Gephardt<br />

proposal <strong>and</strong> the Kemp-Kasten proposal will repeal the exemption of <br />

interest on private purpose obligations. <br />

5. Other specific subsidies. Among the subsidies the Treasury<br />

Department proposals <strong>and</strong> both congressional bills will repeal are: <br />

the business energy production <strong>and</strong> alcohol fuel credits; the complex<br />

Capital Construction Fund mechanism to subsidize investment in fishing<br />

vessels <strong>and</strong> inl<strong>and</strong> waterway <strong>and</strong> ocean going ships; expensing of <br />

capital expenditures <strong>for</strong> farml<strong>and</strong> conditioning <strong>and</strong> soil <strong>and</strong> water <br />

conservation; <strong>and</strong> 7-year amortization of capital outlays <strong>for</strong> <br />

<strong>for</strong>estation <strong>and</strong> re<strong>for</strong>estation. <br />

The Treasury Department <strong>and</strong> Bradley-Gephardt proposals, but not <br />

the Kemp-Kasten proposal, will repeal provisions allowing 5-year<br />

amortization of investment in the rehabilitation of low-income housing<br />

<strong>and</strong> certified pollution control facilities installed in pre-I976<br />

plants. <br />

The Treasury proposals, but neither the Bradley-Gephardt nor the <br />

Kemp-Kasten propsoals, will repeal the special favorable rule <strong>for</strong> <br />

deducting costs of future mine reclamation expenditures, the 5-year<br />

amortization of costs of registering trademarks <strong>and</strong> tradenames, <strong>and</strong> <br />

the 50-year amortization of investment in, <strong>and</strong> sunk costs of, railroad <br />

grading <strong>and</strong> tunnel bores. <br />

C. Further Curtailment of <strong>Tax</strong> Shelters<br />

Many taxpayers use tax shelters to reduce their current tax<br />

liability. Even though many tax shelters are perfectly legal, they<br />

distort the allocation of economic resources <strong>and</strong> undermine both the<br />

equity of the tax system <strong>and</strong> the perception of fairness. Many of the<br />

Treasury Department, Bradley-Gephardt, <strong>and</strong> Kemp-Kasten proposals<br />

discussed above will make investing in tax shelters much less<br />

attractive. Important examples include re<strong>for</strong>m of depreciation rules<br />

<strong>and</strong> changes in the tax treatment of capital gains. All three<br />

proposals will limit the deduction <strong>for</strong> interest expense. To further<br />

curtail the attraction of tax shelters, the Treasury Department<br />

proposal will extend the at-risk rules <strong>for</strong> loss deductions to real<br />

estate. Both the Treasury Department proposals <strong>and</strong> the Bradley-.<br />

Gephardt proposal will repeal the alternative minimum tax; the Kemp-<br />

Kasten proposal retains it.<br />

D. International Issues <br />

Income earned abroad by <strong>for</strong>eign subsidiaries of U.S. corporations<br />

is generally not subject to U.S. tax unless repatriated as dividends.


- 167 -<br />

U.S. tax imposed on such dividends <strong>and</strong> on the earnings of <strong>for</strong>eign<br />

branches can be offset by a credit <strong>for</strong> taxes paid to <strong>for</strong>eign<br />

governments. The <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit is limited to the effective rate<br />

of U.S. tax paid on the <strong>for</strong>eign source income in question. Under<br />

current law companies are allowed to pool income <strong>and</strong> credits from all<br />

countries (though not from all sources) in calculating the limit on<br />

the <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit. In order to encourage U.S. exports, U .S.<br />

firms are allowed to establish Foreign Sales Corporations, the income<br />

from which benefits from tax deferral, even if distributed.<br />

The Treasury Department <strong>and</strong> Kemp-Kasten proposals will continue<br />

the deferral of taxation of income from suhsidiaries of domestic<br />

corporations. By comparison, the Bradley-Gephardt proposal will<br />

eliminate deferral. The Treasury Department proposal will require<br />

calculation of the limitation of the <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit on a countryby-country<br />

basis, in order to prevent an artificial incentive <strong>for</strong><br />

American firms operating in high tax countries to invest in low-tax<br />

countries, rather than in the United States. Neither the Bradley-<br />

Gephardt nor Kemp-Kasten proposals address this issue. The Treasury<br />

Department proposal will continue the preferential treament of Foreign<br />

Sales Corporations. The Treasury Department proposal also deals with<br />

certain problems in the measurement <strong>and</strong> determination of source of<br />

income; the Bradley-Gephardt <strong>and</strong> Kemp-Kasten proposals do not do so.<br />

The Treasury Department proposal will modify the possessions tax<br />

credit. The Bradley-Gephardt proposal will repeal the possesions tax<br />

credit, whereas the Kemp-Kasten proposal will retain it in its current<br />

<strong>for</strong>m. The Treasury Department <strong>and</strong> Kemp-Kasten proposals will retain<br />

the exclusion <strong>for</strong> income of Americans working abroad; the Bradley-<br />

Gephardt proposal will repeal this exclusion.<br />

IV.<br />

Other Ta% Issues <br />

A. <strong>Tax</strong>ation of Transfers<br />

Because the bases of the estate <strong>and</strong> gift taxes are calculated <br />

differently, current law favors those who can af<strong>for</strong>d to make lifetime <br />

gifts over those who need or desire to retain their property until <br />

death. The preference given to lifetime gifts has also caused complex<br />

<strong>and</strong> arbitrary rules <strong>for</strong> including in the donor's estate certain <br />

previously transferred property. The Treasury Department proposal<br />

will treat transfers more uni<strong>for</strong>mly by imposing the gift tax on the <br />

same basis as the estate tax. This change will simplify transfer <br />

taxation by eliminating the need <strong>for</strong> the rules that include certain <br />

gifts in an estate. The Treasury Department proposals will also <br />

simplify the rules <strong>for</strong> generation-skipping transfers <strong>and</strong> the rules <br />

that allow the estate tax to be made in installments where the estate <br />

has insufficient liquid assets to pay the tax. The other two <br />

proposals generally do not change the substantive rules <strong>for</strong> the <br />

taxation of transfers.


B. Expiring Provisions <br />

- 160 -<br />

The Treasury Department proposes elimination (or the allowance of <br />

currently planned expiration) of all major tax credits other than the <br />

earned income tax credit, the <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit, the credit <strong>for</strong> the <br />

elderly, blind, <strong>and</strong> disabled, <strong>and</strong> the credit <strong>for</strong> research <strong>and</strong> <br />

experimentation. The Kemp-Kasten proposals will reduce the earned <br />

income credit <strong>and</strong> retain the <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit <strong>and</strong> will repeal the <br />

credit <strong>for</strong> the elderly <strong>and</strong> the disabled, <strong>for</strong> research <strong>and</strong> <br />

experimentation credit, <strong>and</strong> all major tax credits. The Bradley-<br />

Gephardt proposal will retain the <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit <strong>and</strong> the earned <br />

income credit, but will repeal the credit <strong>for</strong> the elderly <strong>and</strong> the <br />

disabled, the credit <strong>for</strong> research <strong>and</strong> experimentation <strong>and</strong> all major <br />

tax credits. <br />

All three proposals will repeal or allow to expire the special<br />

treatment <strong>for</strong> dividend reinvestment in public utility stock. All<br />

three plans will repeal or allow to expire the exclusions <strong>for</strong><br />

employer-provided legal services <strong>and</strong> transportation. The Treasury<br />

Department proposal <strong>and</strong> the Bradley-Gephardt proposals will also<br />

repeal or allow to expire the exclusion of employer-provided legal <strong>and</strong><br />

educational assistance.


- 169 -<br />

0000 <br />

0000<br />

-?--0<br />

.-.. <br />

WWWW<br />

vi<br />

0000 <br />

v)<br />

OZO <br />

m<br />

v)<br />

I<br />

-I<br />

000 <br />

00<br />

99<br />

NN <br />

v)<br />

oomo<br />

om?-0<br />

Y??Y<br />

Nm-N<br />

m<br />

0000<br />

oo*o <br />

F-!n-i.F­<br />

. ..<br />

Nm-N<br />

v)<br />

-... <br />

000 <br />

!n!n<br />

99<br />

*<br />

21<br />

000<br />

000 <br />

000 <br />

NIriNI<br />

v)<br />

0000 <br />

0000 <br />

0000 <br />

GGGO.<br />

v)<br />

\<br />

mi<br />

000 <br />

000 <br />

woo<br />

... <br />

r-.­<br />

v)<br />

.... <br />

0000<br />

0000 <br />

mmmm<br />

wm-m


- 170 -


- 111 -


- 172 -<br />

8 8 8 8<br />

8<br />

.d 0 5 m w


- 173 -


24<br />

mu<br />

C C <br />

aJ<br />

m 4<br />

u4<br />

$8 <br />

- 1,74 -<br />

4 n<br />

3<br />

3<br />

m u<br />

c c<br />

4 w<br />

32<br />

$5<br />

$0<br />

9z <br />

'Qwd<br />

om <br />

mw 8 8 8 <br />

m<br />

'Q m m<br />

0<br />

m 8 8 %<br />

'Q<br />

m <br />

s<br />

a!<br />

u<br />

E


- 176 -<br />

8 8 <br />

8 8 8 5 : 5: 8 8!33 <br />

5: 5: 8 8 <br />

d<br />

u <br />

u<br />

u


- 111 -<br />

F.*<br />

rl<br />

:<br />

4<br />

5<br />

W 0 <br />

P


- 178 -


- 179 -<br />

%.4<br />

w<br />

2<br />

8<br />

w<br />

0 w 0<br />

U a "<br />

N


- 180 -<br />

d<br />

ei


- 181 -<br />

h<br />

4 <br />

N "


- 182 -


- 183 -


- 185 -<br />

Appendix 8-8 <br />

SUMMARY OF TAX REFORM BILLS <br />

INTRODUCED DURING THE 98TH CONGRESS <br />

H.R. 170, the <strong>Tax</strong> Simplification Act, was introduced by Mr.<br />

Hansen. The bill would tax the income of individuals, estates, <strong>and</strong><br />

trusts at the rate of 15 percent. The deduction <strong>for</strong> personal<br />

exemptions would be increased to $3,000. Most deductions <strong>and</strong><br />

exclusions would be repealed, including those <strong>for</strong> medical expenses,<br />

capital gains, <strong>and</strong> IRAs. Itemized deductions would continue to be<br />

allowed <strong>for</strong> expenses attributable to the conduct of a trade or<br />

business <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> the production of income, <strong>for</strong> charitable<br />

contributions to a church or a convention or association of churches,<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> alimony payments. <strong>Tax</strong> credits would continue to be allowed.<br />

The bill would not amend the corporate income tax.<br />

H.R. 542, the Flat Rate <strong>Tax</strong> Act of 1983, was introduced by Mr. <br />

Philip M. Crane, The bill would tax the income of individuals, <br />

estates, <strong>and</strong> trusts in excess of the deduction <strong>for</strong> personal exemptions <br />

at the rate of 10 percent. The allowance <strong>for</strong> personal exemptions<br />

would be increased to $2,000 <strong>and</strong> would be indexed <strong>for</strong> inflation <br />

occuring after 1982. All exclusions, deductions, <strong>and</strong> credits would be <br />

repealed. The bill would not amend the corporate income tax. <br />

H.R. 1664, the Flat Rate <strong>Tax</strong> Act of 1983, was introduced by Mr. <br />

Paul. The bill would tax the income of individuals, estates, <strong>and</strong> <br />

trusts at the rate of 10 percent. The personal exemptions would be <br />

increased to $2,500. The bill would not amend the corporate income <br />

tax. <br />

H.R. L770, the Flat <strong>Tax</strong> Act of 1983, was introduced by Mr. Dreier. <br />

The bill would tax the gross income of individuals, estates, <strong>and</strong> <br />

trusts in excess of the deduction <strong>for</strong> personal exemptions at the rate <br />

of 14 percent. The allowance <strong>for</strong> personal exemptions would be <br />

increased to $2,000. All exclusions, deductions, <strong>and</strong> credits would be <br />

repealed. The bill would not amend the corporate income tax. <br />

H.R. 2137, the Flat Rate <strong>Tax</strong> Act of 1982, was introduced by Mr. <br />

Paul. The bill would tax the gross income of individuals, estates,<br />

<strong>and</strong> trusts in excess of $10,000 at the rate of 10 percent. All <br />

exclusions, deductions, <strong>and</strong> credits <strong>for</strong> individual taxpayers would be <br />

repealed. The bill would not amend the corporate income tax. <br />

H.R. 2520, the Income <strong>Tax</strong> Simplification Act of 1983, was <br />

introduced by Mr. Panetta. The bill would tax the income of <br />

individuals, corporations, estates, <strong>and</strong> trusts at the rate of 18 <br />

percent. For individuals, the bill would replace the st<strong>and</strong>ard <br />

deduction <strong>and</strong> the deductions <strong>for</strong> personal, blind <strong>and</strong> elderly<br />

exemptions with a tax credit. The credit <strong>for</strong> personal exemptions<br />

would be $1,000 <strong>for</strong> a single return <strong>and</strong> $2,000 <strong>for</strong> a joint return.


- 186 -<br />

The credit <strong>for</strong> each dependent, the blind, <strong>and</strong> the elderly would be<br />

$200 each. Most credits (except the <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit), exclusions,<br />

<strong>and</strong> deductions would be repealed, except <strong>for</strong> those that are related to<br />

the conduct of a trade or business or the production of income.<br />

Individuals would continue to be allowed to deduct alimony payments.<br />

The bill would repeal special rules that apply to natural resources<br />

industries, including the deduction <strong>for</strong> depletion <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> intangible<br />

drilling <strong>and</strong> development costs, <strong>and</strong> special rules relating to<br />

insurance companies <strong>and</strong> banking institutions. The bill would also<br />

repeal deductions <strong>for</strong> certain entertainment expenses, <strong>and</strong> employer<br />

contributions to pension, stock bonus, profit-sharing or annuity<br />

plans. The bill would repeal the special tax treatment af<strong>for</strong>ded<br />

Domestic International Sales Corporations <strong>and</strong> the exclusion of income<br />

of Americans working abroad. The special tax treatment of capital<br />

gains would be repealed, including the provisions that allow the<br />

rollover of gain on the sale of a home. Income averaging would be<br />

repealed.<br />

H.R. 3271, the Fair <strong>Tax</strong> Act of 1983, was introduced by<br />

Mr. Gephardt. This bill is the same as S. 1421, introduced by Senator<br />

Bradley. The provisions of these bills are summarized in Appendix 8-A.<br />

H.R. 3516, the Flat Rate <strong>Tax</strong> Act of 1983, was introduced by Mr. <br />

Don Young. The bill would tax gross income over $10,000 at the rate <br />

of 15 percent. All exclusions, credits, <strong>and</strong> deductions would be <br />

repealed, except <strong>for</strong> the deductions <strong>for</strong> charitable contributions, home <br />

mortgage interest, <strong>and</strong> expenses incurred in carrying 011 a trade or <br />

business. The bill would not amend the corporate income tax. The <br />

bill would provide certain taxpayer protection st<strong>and</strong>ards that relate <br />

to the administration of the tax. <br />

H.R. 4776, the Flat Rate <strong>Tax</strong> Act of 1984, was introduced by Mr. <br />

Quillen. The bill would tax the income of individuals, estates, <strong>and</strong> <br />

trusts at the rate of 10 percent. Exclusions would be repealed, <br />

except <strong>for</strong> social security benefits, veterans benefits, <strong>and</strong> interest <br />

on tax-exempt bonds. The allowance <strong>for</strong> personal exemptions would be <br />

increased to $2,000. Other deductions would be repealed, except <strong>for</strong> <br />

charitable contributions, home mortgage interest <strong>and</strong> interest used to <br />

finance investment, state <strong>and</strong> local income <strong>and</strong> property taxes, <strong>and</strong> <br />

trade <strong>and</strong> business expenses. <strong>Tax</strong> credits would be repealed. The bill <br />

would not amend the corporate income tax. <br />

H.R. 4871, introduced by Mr. Dannemeyer, directs the Treasury<br />

Department to propose legislation <strong>and</strong> provides guidelines that would<br />

be used to develop the legislation. All income of businesses <strong>and</strong><br />

individuals would be taxed only once at a 15 percent rate. The<br />

poorest households would not pay income tax. Individual taxpayers<br />

would be allowed a deduction <strong>for</strong> personal <strong>and</strong> dependency exemptions,<br />

charitable contributions, <strong>and</strong> home mortgage interest. Capital gains<br />

would be exempt from tax. For the business tax, the distinction<br />

between corporations, partnerships, farms, <strong>and</strong> professionals would be<br />

removed. Deductions would be allowed <strong>for</strong> capital expenses, <strong>for</strong> the<br />

cost of goods <strong>and</strong> services, <strong>and</strong> charitable contributions.


- 187 -<br />

H.R. 5432, the Ten Percent Flat <strong>Tax</strong> Rate Act, was introduced by<br />

Mr. Silj<strong>and</strong>er. This bill is the same as S. 5432, introduced by<br />

Senator Nickles. The provisions of these bills are summarized in <br />

Appendix 8-A. <br />

H.R. 5484, the Ten Percent <strong>Tax</strong> Rate Act, was introduced by Mr.<br />

Paul. The bill would tax the income of individuals at the rate of 10<br />

percent. The personal exemptions would be increased to $2,000.<br />

Certain exclusions would continue to be allowed, including alimony<br />

payments, scholarship <strong>and</strong> fellowship grants, supplemental security<br />

income, disability payments, government employee retirement benefits,<br />

interest on certain tax-exempt bonds, <strong>and</strong> fringe benefits. Deductions<br />

would continue to be allowed <strong>for</strong> trade <strong>and</strong> business expenses, <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

expenses related to the production of income. Most other deductions<br />

would be repealed, including the deductions <strong>for</strong> medical expenses,<br />

alimony payments, taxes, <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> two-earner married couples. All tax<br />

credits <strong>for</strong> individuals would be repealed. The estate <strong>and</strong> gift tax<br />

provisions would be repealed. The bill would not amend the corporate<br />

income tax.<br />

H.R. 5711, introduced by Mr. Shelby, is the same as S. 551,<br />

introduced by Senator DeConcini. The provisions of these bills are <br />

summarized in Appendix 8-A. <br />

H.R. 5841, the Progressive Consumption <strong>Tax</strong> Act of 1984, was<br />

introduced by Mr. Heftel. The bill would tax consumption of<br />

individuals at graduated rates that range from 10 percent to 50<br />

percent. The consumption of corporations would be taxed at the rate<br />

of 30 percent. To compute taxable consumption, the taxpayer would add<br />

net income, any increase in debt, <strong>and</strong> any decrease in saving. From<br />

that total, the taxpayer would subtract any decrease in debt <strong>and</strong> any<br />

increase in savings. To compute net income the taxpayer would be<br />

allowed deductions <strong>for</strong> trade <strong>and</strong> business expenses, capital losses,<br />

certain expenses related to the production of income, moving expenses<br />

<strong>and</strong> alimony. Individuals could claim a st<strong>and</strong>ard deduction, equal to<br />

$3,400 <strong>for</strong> joint returns <strong>and</strong> $2,300 <strong>for</strong> single returns. A credit of<br />

$200 would be provided <strong>for</strong> each personal exemption. Most credits,<br />

exclusions <strong>and</strong> deductions allowed under current law would be repealed.<br />

The deduction <strong>for</strong> interest would be limited to home mortgage interest,<br />

interest on debt used to purchase investment assets, <strong>and</strong> interest<br />

incurred in the active conduct of a trade or business. The deduction<br />

<strong>for</strong> charitable contributions would be limited to 5 percent of adjusted<br />

gross consumption. The deduction <strong>for</strong> medical expenses would continue<br />

to be allowed. Capital losses would be fully deductible. Casualty<br />

<strong>and</strong> theft losses in excess of $500 would be deductible. The deduction<br />

<strong>for</strong> property taxes would be repealed. The gift tax would be repealed,<br />

but gifts would be includible in the recipient's gross income.<br />

H.R. 6165, the Fair <strong>and</strong> Simple <strong>Tax</strong> Act of 1984, was introduced by<br />

Mr. Kemp. The this bill is the same as S. 2948, introduced by Senator<br />

Kasten. The provisions of these bills are summarized in Appendix 8-A.<br />

H.R. 6165 <strong>and</strong> S. 2948 replace H.R. 5533 <strong>and</strong> S. 2600, respectively.


- 188 -<br />

H.R. 6364, the Broad-Based, Enhanced Savings <strong>Tax</strong> Act of 1984, was <br />

introduced by Mr. Moore. This bill is the same as S. 3042, introduced <br />

by Senator Roth. The provisions of these bills are summarized in <br />

Appendix 8-A. <br />

H.R. 6384, the SELF-<strong>Tax</strong> Plan Act of 1984, was introduced by Mr.<br />

Schulze. This bill is the same as S. 3050, introduced by Senator<br />

Quayle. S. 3050 replaces S. 1040. <strong>Tax</strong>able income in excess of $6,000<br />

<strong>for</strong> single returns <strong>and</strong> head of household returns, <strong>and</strong> $10,000 <strong>for</strong><br />

joint returns would be subject to tax at graduated rates ranging from<br />

15 percent to 30 percent. The personal exemption would not be<br />

increased. All tax credits <strong>for</strong> individuals would be repealed. Many<br />

exclusions <strong>for</strong> individuals would be repealed, including interest 011<br />

certain state <strong>and</strong> local government bonds. The exclusion <strong>for</strong><br />

scholarships <strong>and</strong> fellowships would be limited to tuition expenses.<br />

Many deductions <strong>for</strong> individuals would be repealed, including the<br />

deductions <strong>for</strong> casualty <strong>and</strong> theft losses, two-earner married couples,<br />

intangible drilling <strong>and</strong> development costs, <strong>and</strong> percentage depletion.<br />

Home mortgage interest would be deductible, but other consumer<br />

interest would not be deductible. Unemployment compensation <strong>and</strong><br />

governmental welfare or assistance benefits would be taxable. Capital<br />

gains would be taxed like ordinary income. The bills would not amend<br />

the corporate income tax, but directs the Treasury Department to study<br />

certain corporate <strong>and</strong> individual income tax changes.<br />

6420, the Cash Flow Income <strong>Tax</strong> Act of 1985, was introduced by Mr.<br />

Heftel. The bill would tax the income of individuals at graduated<br />

rates ranging from 10 percent to 30 percent. Income of corporations<br />

would be taxed at the rate of 30 percent. Income of estates <strong>and</strong><br />

trusts in excess of $3,000 would be taxed at the rate of 30 percent.<br />

Individuals would be allowed a st<strong>and</strong>ard deduction of $8,000 <strong>for</strong> joint<br />

returns, $6,000 <strong>for</strong> head of household returns, <strong>and</strong> $4,000 <strong>for</strong> single<br />

returns. A nonrefundable credit equal to $200 <strong>for</strong> each dependent<br />

would be permitted. Most other credits, exclusions, <strong>and</strong> deductions<br />

provided under current law would be repealed. To compute adjusted<br />

gross income, a taxpayer would add net income, any increase in debt,<br />

<strong>and</strong> any decrease in savings. From this total, the taxpayer would<br />

subtract any decrease in debt <strong>and</strong> any increase in savings. The<br />

taxpayer would be permitted to elect an exclusion of up to $20,000 in<br />

debt. To compute net income, the taxpayer would be permitted<br />

deductions <strong>for</strong> trade <strong>and</strong> business expenses, <strong>for</strong>eign taxes, capital<br />

losses, certain expenses related to the production of income <strong>and</strong><br />

alimony payments. Interest expenses <strong>for</strong> the purchase of investment<br />

assests <strong>and</strong> home mortgage interest would continue to be deductible,<br />

but consumer interest would not be deductible. The deduction <strong>for</strong><br />

charitable contributions would be limited to 5 percent of adjusted<br />

gross income. The deduction <strong>for</strong> property taxes would be repealed.<br />

Deductions would be permitted <strong>for</strong> medical expenses in excess of 10<br />

percent of adjusted gross income <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> casualty <strong>and</strong> theft losses in<br />

excess of $500. Capital losses would be fully deductible. Gifts <strong>and</strong><br />

bequests in excess of $5,000 per year would be includable in the<br />

recipient's gross income.


- 189 -<br />

S. 1767, the Personal Income <strong>Tax</strong> <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong> Act of 1983, was<br />

introduced by Senator Mitchell. The income of individuals, estates,<br />

<strong>and</strong> trusts would be subject to a base tax equal to 12 percent <strong>and</strong> a<br />

surtax that ranges from 8 percent to 24 percent. Personal exemptions<br />

would be increased to $1,750 <strong>for</strong> a taxpayer who is the head of<br />

household, <strong>and</strong> $1,500 <strong>for</strong> any other taxpayer. The amount of dependency<br />

exemptions would be $1,000 each. The st<strong>and</strong>ard deduction would be<br />

increased to $4,600 <strong>for</strong> joint returns. For all other returns, the<br />

amount would be $2,300. Most of the exclusions, deductions, <strong>and</strong><br />

credits contained in current law would be repealed. One-third of the<br />

employer's contribution to the employee's medical care plan would be<br />

included in the employee's income. Scholarship <strong>and</strong> fellowship grants<br />

in excess of tuition <strong>and</strong> related expenses would be included in income.<br />

The deductions <strong>for</strong> two-earner married couples <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> adoption<br />

expenses would be repealed. For individual taxpayers, the capital<br />

gains exclusion <strong>and</strong> the distinction between short <strong>and</strong> long term<br />

capital gains are repealed. The deduction <strong>for</strong> interest would be<br />

allowed <strong>for</strong> home mortgage interest, interest on trade or business<br />

debt, <strong>and</strong> other interest subject to limitations. The credit <strong>for</strong><br />

dependent care expenses would be replaced with an itemized deduction.<br />

The exclusion <strong>for</strong> the gain on the sale of a principal residence <strong>for</strong> a<br />

taxpayer who is 55 years old or older would be replaced with an<br />

itemized deduction. Individual retirement accounts, <strong>and</strong> qualified<br />

pension, profit-sharing, <strong>and</strong> stock bonus plans would be taxed at the<br />

rate of 12 percent. Income averaging would be repealed. The bill<br />

would not amend the taxatjon of corporations.<br />

s. 2158, the Simpli<strong>for</strong>m <strong>Tax</strong> Act, was introduced by Senator<br />

Hatfield. The bill would tax the income of individuals at graduated<br />

rates ranging from 6 percent to 30 percent. Joint returns would be<br />

eliminated. The st<strong>and</strong>ard deduction would be repealed <strong>and</strong> the personal<br />

<strong>and</strong> dependency exemptions would be replaced by credits equal to $250<br />

each. Most credits, deductions, <strong>and</strong> exclusions provided under current<br />

law would be repealed. Deductions would continue to be allowed <strong>for</strong><br />

expenses related to the production of income, <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> alimony<br />

payments. Certain deductions allowed under current law would be<br />

replaced by tax credits. A credit would be provided <strong>for</strong> 20 percent of<br />

qualified medical expenses in excess of 10 percent of adjusted gross<br />

income (AGI). A credit would be provided <strong>for</strong> home mortgage interest<br />

equal to 15 percent of the interest paid in excess of one percent of<br />

AGI, up to a maximum credit of $1,000. A credit would also be<br />

provided <strong>for</strong> 20 percent of charitable contributions in excess of one<br />

percent of AGI, <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> 15 percent of state <strong>and</strong> local taxes in excess<br />

of one percent of AGI, up to a maximum credit of $1,000. The bill<br />

would repeal the partial exclusion of capital gains <strong>and</strong> would index<br />

the basis of assets <strong>for</strong> determining capital gains <strong>and</strong> losses. The<br />

bill would not amend the corporate income tax, but directs the<br />

Treasury Department to conduct a study of amendments to the corporate<br />

income tax that would lower the rate of tax, eliminate tax<br />

preferences, <strong>and</strong> structure the corporate tax in a way that is similar<br />

to the individual income tax provided in the bill.<br />

459-3'70 0 - 84 - 8


- 191 -<br />

Chapter 9 <br />

CONSUMED INCOME TAX <br />

A tax on consumed income, one of the four options considered by<br />

the Treasury Department in its study of fundamental tax re<strong>for</strong>m, is a <br />

frequently mentioned alternative to the income tax. The base of a <br />

comprehensive personal tax on consumption, or consumed income, differs <br />

from that of a comprehensive income tax only in that a deduction is <br />

allowed <strong>for</strong> net saving. This effectively excludes capital income from <br />

the tax base because deferring the tax on saving until withdrawal is, <br />

on average <strong>and</strong> in present value terms, equivalent to exempting the <br />

return to saving from taxation. <br />

Apart from the deduction <strong>for</strong> net saving, the bases of the two<br />

types of taxes are identical. They are both direct personal taxes<br />

which can be structured to reflect the individual circumstances of<br />

taxpayers. Thus, like the income tax, a consumed income tax can<br />

contain personal exemptions, a zero-bracket amount, itemized deductions,<br />

<strong>and</strong> flat or graduated rates. Personalization of this type is<br />

not possible under a transaction-based sales tax on consumption, such<br />

as a value-added tax or a national retail sales tax (discussed in<br />

chapter 10).<br />

A comprehensive consumed income tax <strong>and</strong> a comprehensive income tax<br />

also share the advantages obtained from moving from the current,<br />

narrow base to a broad, uni<strong>for</strong>m tax base. (These advantages are<br />

discussed in chapter 5.) Many of the issues covered in the discussion<br />

of the base of a modified income tax would also arise under a tax on<br />

consumed income. For example, except <strong>for</strong> contributions to retirement<br />

plans, most fringe benefits provided by employers represent a <strong>for</strong>m of<br />

consumption; there<strong>for</strong>e, they should be subject to a tax on consumed<br />

income as well as on all income. Similarly, expenditures such as <strong>for</strong><br />

moving expenses <strong>and</strong> medical care might not be viewed as taxable<br />

consumption, just as they may be viewed as reducing ability to pay<br />

income taxes. Other expenditures that qualify as itemized deductions<br />

under the current income tax, such as state <strong>and</strong> local taxes <strong>and</strong> charitable<br />

contributions, could either be granted or denied preferential<br />

treatment under the consumed income tax. Because these issues are,<br />

<strong>for</strong> the most part, no different under a consumed income tax <strong>and</strong> an<br />

income tax, they are not discussed further in this chapter.<br />

This chapter describes the main features of a consumed income tax,<br />

<strong>and</strong> then discusses its advantages <strong>and</strong> disadvantages. It is important<br />

to specify clearly whether a consumed income tax is being compared to<br />

the current income tax or to a broad-base income tax. Since a consumed<br />

income tax <strong>and</strong> a comprehensive income tax share many of the same<br />

advantages over current law, the more important comparision <strong>for</strong><br />

judging the desirability of a consumed income tax is with a broad-base<br />

income tax.


- 192 -<br />

I. Consumed Income <strong>Tax</strong> Base, Rates, <strong>and</strong> Administration <br />

A tax on consumed income would not be administered by asking a<br />

taxpayer to add together all consumption expenditures during the year;<br />

that would clearly be an impossible task. Rather, the taxpayer would<br />

report total income <strong>and</strong> be allowed a deduction <strong>for</strong> net saving. Conversely,<br />

dissaving would be subject to tax. All saving <strong>and</strong> dissaving<br />

would have to occur through "qualified accounts" held with financial<br />

institutions so that annual saving <strong>and</strong> dissaving could be reliably<br />

reported <strong>and</strong> measured.<br />

A. The <strong>Tax</strong> Base. <br />

The principle of taxing consumption determines the treatment of<br />

loans under a consumed income tax. Since repayment of debt is equivalent<br />

to saving, a deduction would be granted <strong>for</strong> such repayment <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>for</strong> payments of interest; similarly, the proceeds of borrowing would<br />

be included in taxable consumption. If net loan proceeds were not<br />

included in the tax base, taxpayers could "game" the tax system simply<br />

by borrowing funds, depositing them in a qualified account, <strong>and</strong> taking<br />

a deduction <strong>for</strong> the increase in their "saving". Purchasing assets<br />

with borrowed funds does not add to net saving, <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e would<br />

not qualify <strong>for</strong> a deduction under a consumed income tax. Although the<br />

present value of the taxes might not be affected, since the taxpayer<br />

could not deduct the repayments <strong>and</strong> interest on the loan, omitting<br />

borrowing from the base would enable the taxpayer to postpone the<br />

liability. This would disrupt the timing of government receipts <strong>and</strong><br />

would seem unfair. More extreme tax avoidance would occur if borrowing<br />

were not in the base but deductions were allowed <strong>for</strong> loan<br />

repayments, or even just <strong>for</strong> interest payments. Under these circumstances<br />

taxpayers could actually reduce their future as well as<br />

present tax liability by borrowing.<br />

An exception to the rule on borrowing could be made to exclude the<br />

proceeds of home mortgages from the base of a consumed income tax,<br />

provided that no deductions were allowed <strong>for</strong> subsequent repayment of<br />

principal <strong>and</strong> interest. This treatment would avoid a huge consumption<br />

tax liability at the time of home purchase <strong>and</strong> would effectively<br />

spread out tax payments over the life of the loan (since deductions<br />

<strong>for</strong> loan repayment <strong>and</strong> interest are denied), without the complexity of<br />

actual averaging. Similarly, tax on withdrawels from a qualified<br />

account used <strong>for</strong> a down payment on a home could be spread out, too.<br />

Special treatment <strong>for</strong> owner-occupied housing might be acceptable<br />

because, under certain circumstances, it would not alter the present<br />

value of taxes, <strong>and</strong> because the possibilities <strong>for</strong> "gaming" would be<br />

limited.<br />

The tax treatment of business assets would also be based on the<br />

principle of taxing consumption. Accordingly, the purchase of<br />

business assets would be deducted immediately; that is, investment is<br />

expensed under a consumed income tax. The returns to the asset <strong>and</strong><br />

the amount received upon sale would be included in the tax base,


- 193 -<br />

unless reinvested. Similarly, the purchase of corporate stock or<br />

other financial assets is deductible; dividends <strong>and</strong> interest received,<br />

as well as the receipts from selling the stock or bond, are included<br />

in the tax base unless they are saved.<br />

Under a consumed income tax, there is even less theoretical<br />

justification <strong>for</strong> a corporate income tax than under a comprehensive<br />

income tax. The rationale <strong>for</strong> eliminating the corporate income tax is<br />

easily seen by considering the uses to which net corporate income can<br />

be put. Earnings that are retained should not be taxed because they<br />

are a <strong>for</strong>m of saving, <strong>and</strong> the consumed income tax explicitly excludes<br />

saving from the tax base. Corporations would not pay tax on income<br />

distributed to shareholders, because dividends would be taxable to<br />

shareholders, unless they saved them. At most, a corporate income tax<br />

might be retained <strong>for</strong> three reasons: (1) to prevent <strong>for</strong>eign investors<br />

in the United States from automatically benefitting from the elimination<br />

of the corporate income tax, ( 2) to assess an additional tax on<br />

extraordinary returns to investment in the corporate sector, or (3) to<br />

tax indirectly corporate expenditures which represent consumption on<br />

the part of employees by denying corporations deductions <strong>for</strong> such<br />

expenditures.<br />

There is general agreement that gifts <strong>and</strong> inheritances should be<br />

included in the taxable consumption of the recipient, unless saved.<br />

Some advocates of a tax on consumed income believe that gifts <strong>and</strong><br />

bequests also represent consumption of the donor, <strong>and</strong> thus should be<br />

included in the tax base of the donor, as well as in the base of the<br />

recipient. This would make the base of the consumed income tax lifetime<br />

income. However, other advocates of a consumed income tax point<br />

out that this would amount to double taxation of the gift or bequest,<br />

<strong>and</strong> believe quite strongly that gifts <strong>and</strong> bequests should be taxed<br />

only to the recipient <strong>and</strong> not to the donor. The distributional<br />

implications of this issue are enormous. If bequests <strong>and</strong> gifts were<br />

excluded from the consumed income tax base of the donor, higher rates<br />

would be required to approximate the existing distribution of tax<br />

burdens by income class. Moreover, the "wealthy miser" would almost<br />

completely escape tax under such a tax on consumed income, <strong>and</strong> large<br />

<strong>for</strong>tunes could be passed on between generations tax-free.<br />

Thus, under a comprehensive consumed income tax, the tax base<br />

would include all <strong>for</strong>ms of current monetary <strong>and</strong> in-kind income, the<br />

current consumption value of all fringe benefits supplied by<br />

employers, the proceeds of sales of capital assets <strong>and</strong> the returns to<br />

direct investment that are not reinvested, withdrawals in excess of<br />

deposits in saving accounts, the proceeds of all borrowing in excess<br />

of loan repayments, <strong>and</strong> gifts <strong>and</strong> inheritances received. Accrued<br />

interest, earnings from ownership of corporate shares, increases in<br />

the value of pension <strong>and</strong> life insurance reserves, <strong>and</strong> other increases<br />

in the value of asset holdings would not be subject to tax until paid<br />

out, borrowed, or otherwise withdrawn <strong>for</strong> consumption.<br />

This tax on consumed income then amounts to a tax on the sum of<br />

gifts, inheritances, <strong>and</strong> labor income received. For the economy as a


- 194 -<br />

whole <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> most taxpayers, who receive only an insignificant amount<br />

of gifts <strong>and</strong> inheritances, a consumed income tax would, in fact, be<br />

virtually equivalent to a tax only on wages. Capital income would in<br />

effect be exempt. Although individuals would have to pay tax on<br />

capital income when it was used <strong>for</strong> consumption, the deduction of<br />

saving (out of wages) <strong>and</strong> the tax exemption of interest income results<br />

in a present value of the tax liability which, under certain circumstances,<br />

is the same as if the individual had been taxed only on total<br />

wages when paid.<br />

8. <strong>Tax</strong> Rates<br />

Because the household sector is a net lender in the economy, the <br />

base of a consumed income tax would be smaller than the base of an <br />

income tax with identical treatment of items other than capital<br />

income. Thus, to raise an equal amount of revenue as an income tax, a <br />

consumed income tax would have to have higher rates. The tax <br />

exemption of capital income must be weighed against higher marginal<br />

tax rates on labor income. The percentage difference in marginal tax <br />

rates between a consumed income tax <strong>and</strong> a broad-based income tax would <br />

depend on the difference in the tax base. The tax rates under a <br />

consumed income tax might still be lower than the rates on the narrow <br />

base of the current income tax. <br />

C. Administration <br />

In order to administer a consumed income tax <strong>and</strong> to minimize<br />

noncompliance, almost all financial transactions would have to be<br />

conducted through one or more IRA-type qualified accounts held through<br />

banks, brokerages, or other financial institutions to insure reliable<br />

in<strong>for</strong>mation reporting. A useful way to think of qualified accounts<br />

under a tax on consumed income is to imagine extension of the present<br />

rules <strong>for</strong> individual retirement accounts (IRAs) <strong>and</strong> Keogh plans to<br />

cover all <strong>for</strong>ms <strong>and</strong> amounts of saving <strong>and</strong> dissaving (including loans).<br />

Any amounts put into such accounts (including loan repayments of<br />

principal <strong>and</strong> interest) would be deductible. Investment income earned<br />

on the accounts would be currently tax exempt unless withdrawn, but<br />

any withdrawal from the accounts (including the proceeds of loans)<br />

would be taxable.<br />

Requiring virtually all financial transactions to be recorded<br />

through a qualified account is necessary to prevent abuses of the tax<br />

system. In some cases, the present value of the tax liability of<br />

transactions conducted outside of qualified accounts might be the same<br />

as transactions through qualified accounts, but the taxpayer would be<br />

able to time the tax payments to his or her advantage. Excluding the<br />

proceeds of borrowing from the tax base (which is equivalent to<br />

borrowing outside of qualified accounts) provides an example of this.<br />

In other instances, avoiding qualified accounts could actually reduce<br />

the present value of the tax liability. This could occur if the<br />

taxpayer expects unusually high returns on an investment. By not<br />

making an investment through a qualified account, <strong>and</strong> not getting a<br />

deduction <strong>for</strong> it, the taxpayer "prepays" the tax. But the value of


- 195 -<br />

the tax on the actual consumption from the high returns would have<br />

been greater than the prepayment amount. Allowing taxpayers to choose<br />

whether to use qualified accounts would provide only ex ante equity in<br />

taxation, whereas requiring qualified account treatment <strong>for</strong> all<br />

transactions provides ex post equity.<br />

The unit of taxation under a consumed income tax would probably be <br />

the family, rather than the present tax unit. The problems under an <br />

income tax caused by transfers of income to family members with low <br />

marginal rates would be magnified under a consumed income tax. Con­<br />

sumption cannot be as clearly attributed to individual family members <br />

as income can. Distinctions between a "gift" <strong>and</strong> "shared consumption"<br />

would be meaningless within most families. Furthermore, the family is <br />

the more appropriate unit <strong>for</strong> taxing consumption, since in general a11 <br />

family members (at least within the same household) share in a common <br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard of living. <br />

11. Advantages of a Consumed Income <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

One of the major advantages that a comprehensive consumed income<br />

tax would have over the present income tax would be a uni<strong>for</strong>m tax<br />

base, which would eliminate many of the economic distortions <strong>and</strong><br />

inequities of the present system. Of course, a comprehensive income<br />

tax would share this advantage over current law. Relative to a broadbase<br />

income tax, a comprehensive consumed income tax would still have<br />

several advantages i n terms of administration, economic effects, <strong>and</strong><br />

equity.<br />

A. Administrative Advantages <br />

The main administrative advantages of e tax on consumed income are<br />

that it avoids most problems of measuring income from business <strong>and</strong><br />

capital, it does not require complicated indexing adjustments to make<br />

it inflation-proof, <strong>and</strong> it provides a simple solution to the current<br />

problems of tax shelters <strong>and</strong> tax arbitrage.<br />

1. Income measurement issues. The measurement of income from<br />

business <strong>and</strong> capital is inherently difficult. Many of the most<br />

complicated provisions of the current income tax can be traced to<br />

problems of income measurement. A major advantage of a tax on<br />

consumed income would be that it avoids most of these problems.<br />

Business income measurement. A number of the complexities in<br />

measuring business income stem from issues of timing. For example,<br />

under current law taxpayers are allowed to choose whether to employ<br />

cash or accrual accounting. Under either accounting convention, there<br />

are important questions of interpretation. When, <strong>for</strong> example, shou1.d<br />

a cash-basis taxpayer record expenses incurred during one year <strong>for</strong> the<br />

purpose of earning income in a later year? When should an accrual<br />

basis taxpayer reflect income from projects that extend beyond one<br />

year? <strong>Tax</strong>payers employing different accounting methods -- including<br />

affiliated or commonly owned taxpayers -- can engage in transactions<br />

that produce recognition of expenses (by the accrual basis taxpayer)


- 196 -<br />

but postponement of recognition of receipt (by the cash basis tax-<br />

payer), thereby reducing their aggregate tax liability. under most <br />

proposals, a consumed income tax would be based on cash flow; the <br />

taxpayer has or has not paid or received cash or its equivalent. None <br />

of the problems described above would exist under a consumed income <br />

tax of this type. <br />

Problems of depreciation accounting, depletion allowances,<br />

amortization, <strong>and</strong> accounting <strong>for</strong> inventories <strong>for</strong> tax purposes also <br />

would not arise under a consumed income tax. The cost of depreciable<br />

assets would simply be currently deducted (expensed) in the year of <br />

acquisition under the cash flow tax. Similarly, expenditures on goods<br />

placed in inventory would be automatically expensed. Various other <br />

types of cash expenditures are expensed, rather than capitalized <strong>and</strong> <br />

amortized over their useful life. In the case of natural resources, <br />

all costs of acquisition, exploration, <strong>and</strong> development would be <br />

expensed, rather than recognized over the lifetime of the resulting<br />

asset through cost depletion; the possibility of percentage depletion<br />

should never arise. By comparison, under the income tax it is <br />

necessary to determine the useful life of assets <strong>and</strong> the pattern of <br />

depreciation to employ <strong>for</strong> tax purposes. special <strong>and</strong> arbitrary rules <br />

are required under current law <strong>for</strong> property such as motion pictures,<br />

sound recordings, <strong>and</strong> trademarks. <br />

For certain purposes the characterization of an income flow can<br />

affect tax treatment under the income tax; <strong>for</strong> example, the distinction<br />

between dividends <strong>and</strong> interest is often important. Under an<br />

ideal tax on consumed income all such distinctions would be irrelevant.<br />

Perhaps more important, the distinction between income <strong>and</strong><br />

return of capital would also be meaningless under a tax on consumed<br />

income since cash received would be taxable unless reinvested.<br />

Similarly, payment of cash would always produce deductions, whether<br />

the payments were <strong>for</strong> expenses or <strong>for</strong> repayment of capital.<br />

Capital gains would not be subject to tax under an ideal tax on <br />

consumed income. Rather, the taxpayer would be allowed a deduction <br />

<strong>for</strong> the full value of expenditures on capital assets. The entire <br />

proceeds of asset sales would be included in taxable consumption,<br />

unless reinvested. This treatment would have several administrative <br />

advantages. First, there would be no need to know the original basis <br />

(usually the cost) of capital assets, since basis would be irrelevant <br />

in calculating the consumed income tax; this would greatly simplify<br />

both taxpayer compliance <strong>and</strong> tax administration. Second, since <br />

capital gains would receive no special treatment, there would be no <br />

incentives to characterize income as capital gain. This would <br />

eliminate the complex distinctions between capital gains <strong>and</strong> ordinary<br />

income in current law, as well as the associated tax shelters. <br />

Averaginq. Current law includes some fairly complicated<br />

provisions <strong>for</strong> income averaging. Such provisions are necessary under<br />

a progressive income tax so that an individual with fluctuating income<br />

does not bear a heavier tax burden than an individual with the same


- 197 -<br />

average income received at a steady rate. Since annual consumption<br />

does not fluctuate as much as annual income, there would be less need <br />

<strong>for</strong> complex averaging provisions under a consumed income tax. <br />

Pensions. A primary administrative advantage of a tax on consumed<br />

income in the area of measurement of individual income lies in the<br />

simplification of the tax treatment of pensions. At present, contributions<br />

to certain qualified pension accounts are accorded consumption<br />

tax treatment; that is, contributions are fully deductible but receipt<br />

of both principal <strong>and</strong> interest is subject to tax. Contributions are,<br />

however, subject to limitations, <strong>and</strong> pre-retirement withdrawals are<br />

penalized. However, many pension plans <strong>and</strong> other vehicles <strong>for</strong> retirement<br />

saving are not covered by these rules. Under a tax on consumed<br />

income all saving <strong>for</strong> retirement -- indeed, all saving -- is accorded<br />

uni<strong>for</strong>m treatment: deduction upon contribution <strong>and</strong> taxation of both<br />

the original contribution <strong>and</strong> subsequent earnings at the time of<br />

withdrawal.<br />

2. Inflation-proof tax base. During inflationary periods, the<br />

current income tax generally mismeasures income from capital <strong>and</strong> from<br />

business; real income is understated in some instances <strong>and</strong> overstated<br />

in others. This occurs <strong>for</strong> a number of reasons: depreciation is based<br />

on historical costs; tax is collected on nominal capital gains, rather<br />

than real (inflation-adjusted) gains; the deduction <strong>for</strong> the cost of<br />

goods sold from inventory is often based on the value of the oldest<br />

goods in stock at the beginning of the year; <strong>and</strong> interest income <strong>and</strong><br />

expense are calculated without recognizing that nominal interest rates<br />

include an inflation premium that should neither be taxed nor<br />

deducted. During the 1970s the mismeasurement of business <strong>and</strong> capital<br />

income resulted in substantial overtaxation of these <strong>for</strong>ms of income,<br />

which in addition to being inequitable, had a serious depressing<br />

effect on capital investment. Adjusting depreciation allowances, the<br />

cost of goods sold from inventories, capital gains, <strong>and</strong> interest<br />

income <strong>and</strong> expense <strong>for</strong> inflation is inevitably complicated. Because<br />

the tax on consumed income is based on cash flow, it requires no<br />

inflation adjustment to make it inflation-proof. Cash flow is<br />

inherently measured in dollars of the current period, so there is no<br />

occasion to combine current income <strong>and</strong> expenses with historical ones.<br />

3. <strong>Tax</strong> shelters <strong>and</strong> tax arbitrage. <strong>Tax</strong> shelters <strong>and</strong> tax arbitrage<br />

are a major source of inequity <strong>and</strong> distortion under the current income<br />

tax system. Any attempts-at >e<strong>for</strong>ming the tax system must address<br />

their underlying causes; these include -- usually in combination --<br />

acceleration of deductions <strong>for</strong> expenses, preferential treatment of<br />

capital gains or the return to saving (often through vehicles typical<br />

of a consumed income tax, such as pensions, IRAs, <strong>and</strong> life insurance<br />

policies with large saving components), <strong>and</strong> borrowing in order to<br />

realize deductions <strong>for</strong> interest expense. The relative advantage of<br />

the consumed income tax with respect to tax shelters is the simplicity<br />

of the solution. By addressing the underlying causes of tax avoidance,<br />

a well-structured income tax would certainly reduce the use of<br />

tax shelters. But it would require extensive <strong>and</strong> complex provisions,<br />

including "at risk rules" intended to prevent taxpayers from taking


- 198 -<br />

deductions in excess of their actual investment in the asset, limitations<br />

on the deduction of inflation-adjusted interest expenses, real<br />

economic depreciation with more complete cost capitalization rules,<br />

<strong>and</strong> full taxation of real capital gains.<br />

In contrast to the complex rules necessary to prevent tax shelters<br />

under an income tax, existing tax shelters would simply disappear with<br />

the tax exemption of capital income. The relative advantage of<br />

current tax shelters would be eliminated if all purchases of capital<br />

goods were expensed, if capital gains <strong>and</strong> the returns to saving were<br />

taxed only when consumed, <strong>and</strong> if borrowing were subject to tax unless<br />

offset by additional investment.<br />

Some caution must be exercised, however, in extolling the relative<br />

advantage of a consumed income tax with regard to tax shelters. Unless<br />

the family was the tax unit, <strong>and</strong> to some extent even if it were,<br />

attribution of consumption to related individuals subject to low<br />

marginal tax rates would be a new tax reduction technique under a<br />

graduated consumed income tax. This is just one example of how any<br />

tax preference or possible tax loophole would likely be exploited<br />

under a consumed income tax. The difficult measurement issues which<br />

gave rise to loopholes in the present income tax are fairly well known<br />

after 70 years of experience. Similar measurement difficulties in an<br />

actual consumed income tax would probably give rise to many new <strong>and</strong><br />

different "tax shelters".<br />

8. Economic Advantages<br />

Advocates of a consumed income tax argue that it would have two<br />

important advantages over an income tax. First, it would not distort<br />

the consumer choice between present <strong>and</strong> future consumption. Second,<br />

it would probably increase saving, which in turn would increase<br />

investment, productivity <strong>and</strong> growth. Implementation of a consumed<br />

income tax would also affect individual behavior regarding gifts <strong>and</strong><br />

bequests.<br />

1. Economic neutrality. An individual can consume income now or<br />

save it in order to consume it later. The cost or "price" of future<br />

consumption is inversely related to the net rate of return to saving<br />

obtained by the individual; a higher rate of return implies a lower<br />

price, since more future consumption can be purchased <strong>for</strong> any amount<br />

saved. A consumed income tax does not change the price of future<br />

consumption since it does not change the rate of return to saving. In<br />

contrast, by taxing the return to saving, the income tax raises the<br />

price of future consumption, thus distorting the choice between<br />

consuming now or saving <strong>for</strong> future consumption. In this sense, unlike<br />

the income tax, the consumed income t.ax does not discriminate against<br />

saving.<br />

However, eliminating the income tax discrimination against saving<br />

by enacting a consumed income tax would have some adverse effects as <br />

well. Although only the income tax discriminates against saving, both <br />

the income <strong>and</strong> consumed income taxes distort the individual decision


- 199 -<br />

to work more or take more leisure (broadly defined to include nonmarket<br />

production in the home). However, tax rates must be higher<br />

under a consumed income tax, as the base is smaller. As a result, the<br />

consumed income tax distorts the work-leisure choice more than the<br />

broad-based income tax does. Thus, in terms of overall economic<br />

neutrality, the relative merits of the two taxes are unclear on<br />

theoretical grounds. (The theoretical argument is unlikely to be<br />

resolved in the near future; <strong>for</strong> example, there is little empirical<br />

evidence <strong>and</strong> no consensus about the val.ue of an esoteric but critical<br />

parameter in the analysis -- the labor supply response to changes in<br />

the return to saving.) Under many assumptions about individual<br />

behavior, the consumed income tax results in a smaller total distortion<br />

of the two choices <strong>and</strong> thus is preferable in terms of economic<br />

neutrality. However, under other assumptions, the income tax can be<br />

shown to result in a smaller overall distortion.<br />

2. Effect on saving. The effect on saving of implementing a <br />

consumed income tax is also controversial. As described above, saving<br />

would be encouraged under the consumed income tax because the income <br />

tax discrimination against saving would be eliminated. However,<br />

because the net return to saving would be higher, any particular goal<br />

<strong>for</strong> future consumption could be attained with less current saving;<br />

this would reduce the need to save. The net effect of taxation on <br />

saving is a topic of much debate. Most economists believe that,<br />

relative to an income tax, a consumed income tax would result in more <br />

saving, <strong>and</strong> thus more investment, faster growth <strong>and</strong> eventually higher<br />

wages; some contend the effects would be very significant. However, <br />

many economists argue that little change in saving would result. <br />

Also, if the marginal tax rate at the time of dissaving were lower<br />

than the tax rate at the time the deductions were taken, the effective<br />

tax rate on the return to saving would be negative -- not only would<br />

the government collect no tax on the saving, it would actually pay<br />

people to save. Although this would further encourage saving, it<br />

would reduce total tax collections <strong>and</strong> require higher marginal tax<br />

rates on the remaining tax base.<br />

3. Effects on gifts <strong>and</strong> bequests. The tax treatment of gifts <strong>and</strong><br />

bequests under the consumed income tax would affect individual<br />

decisions to give <strong>and</strong> to leave inheritances. Gifts <strong>and</strong> bequests would<br />

probably be stimulated if they were taxed only to the recipient.<br />

However, the opposite effect would occur if they were taxed to both<br />

the donor <strong>and</strong> recipient. Saving would also be stimulated in the<br />

<strong>for</strong>mer case but discouraged in the latter.<br />

C. Equity Advantages <br />

Many advocates of taxes on consumed income believe that<br />

consumption provides a better measure of ability to pay than does<br />

income. One argument <strong>for</strong> a tax on consumed income is that annual<br />

income, which is subject to considerable fluctuation, is a less


- 200 -<br />

satisfactory indicator of ability to pay than is permanent income, <strong>and</strong> <br />

that consumption is a better proxy <strong>for</strong> permanent income than is annual <br />

income. <br />

At another level of sophistication, some advocates of a particular<br />

<strong>for</strong>m of consumed income tax argue that ability to pay should be<br />

measured in terms of lifetime income, rather than annual income.<br />

Lifetime income can, in turn, be measured in present value terms in<br />

either of two ways: as the sum of gifts <strong>and</strong> bequests received plus<br />

labor income, or as the sum of consumption plus amounts given or<br />

bequeathed to others. Under this rationale, the tax base of the tax<br />

on consumed income is appropriate because it is exactly a measure of<br />

lifetime income, but only if gifts <strong>and</strong> bequests are included in the<br />

tax base of the donor as well as the recipient.<br />

The consumed income tax can be viewed as more equitable than an<br />

income tax from the perspective of the lifetime. Under certain<br />

circumstances, including a constant tax rate over the lifetime of the<br />

taxpayer, the value of taxes paid under a consumed income tax does not<br />

depend on when a person consumes or receives earnings. By comparison,<br />

an income tax levies higher taxes on individuals who earn income at a<br />

relatively early age or spend it at a relatively older age.<br />

Finally, some advocates of a tax on consumed income believe it is <br />

more equitable because individuals should be taxed on "what they take <br />

out of the pot" (consumption) rather than "what they put into it" <br />

(income). Since this position basically involves philosophical<br />

judgments, it is inherently inconclusive. <br />

111. Disadvantages of a Consumed Income <strong>Tax</strong><br />

Although the advantages of a tax on consumed income are numerous,<br />

the Treasury Department believes they are outweighed by a number of <br />

serious administrative, economic, <strong>and</strong> equity disadvantages. These <br />

include increased complexity <strong>for</strong> individual taxpayers, higher marginal <br />

tax rates, serious compliance problems, perceived unfairness, <strong>and</strong> a <br />

lengthy transition period with complicated treatment of existing<br />

wealth. Again, the relative advantages <strong>and</strong> disadvantages of a compre­<br />

hensive consumed income tax must be compared to those of a broad-base <br />

income tax, not just to the current income tax system. <br />

A. Administrative Disadvantages <br />

A consumed income tax would be simpler <strong>for</strong> business <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

taxpayers with much capital income. However, it would probably be<br />

more complicated <strong>for</strong> the average individual taxpayer. The elements of<br />

a consumed income tax required to separate saving from consumption<br />

would be unfamiliar <strong>and</strong> complex. In addition, increased compliance<br />

difficulties, troublesome international issues, <strong>and</strong> potential constitutional<br />

challenges are unique to a consumed income tax.<br />

1. Complexity <strong>for</strong> average taxpayers. under a consumed income tax,<br />

problems of measuring the tax base <strong>for</strong> individuals would be different,


- 201 -<br />

rather than eliminated. For the family of a typical wage earner, the <br />

problems of measuring capital income that a consumption tax avoids are <br />

of little concern. Such a family's tax picture would be complicated<br />

by the addition to the tax base of borrowing <strong>and</strong> savings account <br />

withdrawals. Also, taxpayers would confront a more elaborate tax <br />

administration system, with "qualified accounts" <strong>for</strong> all financial <br />

transactions, <strong>and</strong> the possibility of withholding on borrowing, on <br />

withdrawals of savings, as well as negative withholding on deposits in <br />

qualified accounts. <br />

Borrowing. Most families would have to keep track of their net<br />

borrowing under a consumed income tax. In addition to reporting their<br />

wage income, they would have to report any new borrowing <strong>and</strong> any<br />

repayments of prior borrowing. <strong>Tax</strong>payers would find it hard to<br />

underst<strong>and</strong> why all borrowing -- including consumer loans, credit card<br />

debt, <strong>and</strong> business loans -- would be part of the tax base, Unlike the<br />

present income tax, with its deduction of gross additions to Ims, a<br />

consumed income tax would allow a deduction only <strong>for</strong> net saving, that<br />

is, increases in saving in excess of increases in debt. Conversely,<br />

any increases in debt in excess of the increase in saving would be<br />

included in the tax base.<br />

Qualified financial accounts. The requirement that almost all <br />

financial transactions be conducted throuqh qualified accounts would <br />

reduce a taxpayer's financial flexibility-<strong>and</strong> ability to maintain the <br />

privacy of his or her financial affairs. <strong>Tax</strong>payers would have to <br />

learn to think of amounts accumulated in a qualified account as pre-<br />

tax funds. The amount of consumption a given amount of saving could <br />

buy would be less than the amount accumulated, since taxes would have <br />

to be paid on any net withdrawal from an account. The same is true of <br />

existing state sales taxes, but not of the current income tax. <br />

Treatment of personal-use assets. The tax treatment of housing, <br />

autos, other consumer durables, <strong>and</strong> "collectibles" like art <strong>and</strong> <br />

antiques is an important <strong>and</strong> difficult issue under a consumed income <br />

tax. These items have both consumption <strong>and</strong> investment characteristics <br />

since they provide consumption services over a number of years.<br />

Treating them like ordinary consumer goods by including the full <br />

purchase price in the tax base overstates the taxpayer's consumption<br />

that year. However, there are no annual monetary payments, like lease <br />

payments paid by a renter, associated with these goods to indicate the <br />

amount of annual consumption services. <br />

Treating personal assets like ordinary investments, on the other <br />

h<strong>and</strong>, understates the taxpayer's consumption. Owner-occupied housing<br />

<strong>and</strong> pieces of art provide good examples of this. Suppose an indi­<br />

vidual buys a house or painting <strong>for</strong> $100,000 <strong>and</strong> sells it <strong>for</strong> the same <br />

price three years later. If the purchase is treated as an investment, <br />

an individual would be able to deduct the purchase price of $100,000<br />

<strong>and</strong> then include the resale price of $100,000 in taxable income. In <br />

this example the taxpayer has no net tax liability (indeed he <br />

postpones tax <strong>for</strong> three years). Yet the house or art has provided<br />

consumption benefits while used by the taxpayer. If the purchase


- 202 -<br />

price were deductible, the ownership <strong>and</strong> use of a car that was bought<br />

<strong>for</strong> $10,000 <strong>and</strong> sold three years later <strong>for</strong> $4,000 would actually<br />

reduce tax liability, thus subsidizing the consumption services <br />

provided by the personal asset. <br />

One compromise way to treat personal use assets would require<br />

consumers to include the full purchase price of certain major consumer<br />

assets in the tax base but allow them to spread out the tax payments<br />

over a number of years. But averaging is notoriously complicated<br />

anytime there is a change in the taxpaying unit, such as through<br />

marriage, death, or divorce. Alternatively, purchases of a limited<br />

group of consumer durables, perhaps only housing, could be made out of<br />

non-qualified accounts; the proceeds of loans from such accounts would<br />

not be included in the tax base, <strong>and</strong> deposits <strong>and</strong> repayment of loan<br />

principal <strong>and</strong> interest would not be deductible. Under certain circumstances,<br />

this treatment would be equivalent to the qualified account<br />

approach in ternis of present value of tax liability. However, the<br />

simultaneous use of qualified accounts <strong>for</strong> certain transactions <strong>and</strong><br />

non-qualified accounts <strong>for</strong> others increases complexity <strong>and</strong> the<br />

potential <strong>for</strong> tax avoidance. In addition, this treatment raises<br />

questions about the proper treatment of extraordinary gains realized<br />

upon disposition of the asset.<br />

Extended withholdinq. Under the present system of withholding, <br />

most taxpayers experience little net tax liability at the end of the <br />

year. Relatively few taxpayers are required to file statements of <br />

estimated tax <strong>and</strong> make quarterly payments of tax. Even with itemized <br />

deductions, most taxpayers can adjust withholding to achieve a satis­<br />

factory degree of similarity between total amounts withheld <strong>and</strong> <br />

ultimate tax liability. Those who file estimated returns generally<br />

have substantial non-labor income that is not subject to withholding<br />

<strong>and</strong> are more able to cope with the complexities of filing an estimated <br />

return. <br />

The situation is potentially quite different under a tax on<br />

consumed income. Withholding applied only to income would frequently<br />

produce a poor approximation of ultimate tax liability if the tax base<br />

were consumption, rather than income. With withholding on consumed<br />

income, most taxpayers would have to become more actively <strong>and</strong><br />

frequently involved in determining their withholding, guessing <strong>and</strong><br />

revising their expected consumption several times a year. In the<br />

absence of a system of withholding on loans <strong>and</strong> withdrawals, any major<br />

purchase, such as that of a vacation or an automobile, could result in<br />

a substantial underpayment of tax. Consumer loans or withdrawals<br />

taken out near the end of a year might be particularly troublesome,<br />

since they could not easily be reflected in withholding, unless<br />

anticipated earlier. For example, loans taken out to finance<br />

Christmas presents might unexpectedly increase tax liability <strong>for</strong> many<br />

taxpayers. Year-end contributions to savings accounts may also not be<br />

reflected in withholding during the year. But these are likely to be<br />

welcome, because they result in reduced tax liability or even a<br />

refund, rather than increased tax.


- 203 -<br />

Both taxpayer convenience <strong>and</strong> protection of revenues might dictate<br />

that a system of universal withholding be applied to all loans,<br />

withdrawals, deposits, <strong>and</strong> repayments. This prospect raises several<br />

problems. Under a graduated tax schedule, the lender would not know<br />

the correct rate at which to withhold, so that withholding would have<br />

to be at a flat rate. With a simplified rate structure, this might<br />

not appear to be problematic, since most taxpayers would be subject to<br />

tax at the same marginal rate. However, it would overwithhold low<br />

consumption taxpayers <strong>and</strong> underwithhold large consumers. In addition,<br />

withholding on loans <strong>and</strong> repayments would logically be coupled with<br />

negative withholding on saving: <strong>for</strong> a $5,000 deposit, the bank would<br />

credit $6,000 (at a 20 percent withholding rate). At a minimum, this<br />

would be complex <strong>and</strong> confusing to taxpayers.<br />

2. Compliance. With consumption defined as income minus net<br />

saving, a tax on consumed income would entail many of the compliance<br />

problems of an income tax -- plus additional difficulties of monitoring<br />

saving <strong>and</strong> dissaving. While taxpayers would have an incentive<br />

to report all the deductions <strong>for</strong> saving <strong>and</strong> investment to which they<br />

are entitled, they would have an incentive <strong>for</strong> riot reporting withdrawals<br />

or borrowing. Consequently, qualified accounts could only be<br />

established in institutions that could provide reliable <strong>and</strong> accurate<br />

reporting.<br />

<strong>Tax</strong> evasion would be more rewarding <strong>and</strong> consequently more tempting<br />

with a tax on consumed income. In this case, evasion would involve<br />

not reporting or erroneously deducting the full principal plus<br />

earnings on capital transactions, rather than just the earnings. The<br />

IRS estimates that 40 percent of capital gain transactions are not<br />

reported. This is serious enough under current law, where only the<br />

gains are taxed, <strong>and</strong> at preferential rates. It would be much more<br />

serious under a tax on consumed income, where the entire proceeds of a<br />

sale, not just the gain, would be taxable (unless reinvested) <strong>and</strong> at<br />

ordinary rates. Compliance with a consumed income tax would there<strong>for</strong>e<br />

require a more extensive system of in<strong>for</strong>mation reporting <strong>and</strong> monitoring<br />

than does an income tax.<br />

To prevent legal "gaming of the system" <strong>and</strong> illegal tax evasion, a <br />

number of comprehensive, <strong>and</strong> possibly complex en<strong>for</strong>cement procedures<br />

would be necessary. These would go beyond third-party in<strong>for</strong>mation <br />

reporting that would be useful under an income tax. They might<br />

include a comprehensive inventory of all existing wealth upon enact­<br />

ment of the tax, registration of private borrowing, <strong>and</strong> a far-reaching <br />

system of exchange controls to facilitate policing of <strong>for</strong>eign<br />

transactions. <br />

3. Constitutionality. The Sixteenth Amendment of the U.S.<br />

Constitution empowers the Federal Government ' I . . . to lay <strong>and</strong> collect<br />

taxes on incomes, from whatever source derived . . . . ' I Experience<br />

suggests that the Sixteenth Amendment would not prevent taxation from<br />

being limited to income that is consumed. After all, many <strong>for</strong>ms of<br />

saving now effectively result in tax exemption. Nor does there appear<br />

to be any problem in taxing dissaving of amounts that have previously


- 204 -<br />

benefitted from tax exemption or deferral, such as qualified pension<br />

accounts, individual retirement accounts, or Keogh plans; this is also<br />

a feature of current law. But the tax on consumed income goes beyond<br />

the deduction <strong>for</strong> saving, deferral of tax on interest, <strong>and</strong> inclusion<br />

of dissaving in the tax base. It includes borrowing in the tax base,<br />

even <strong>for</strong> taxpayers who have no income. Although a consumed income tax<br />

is not likely to be found unconstitutional, there is little doubt that<br />

the constitutionality of a tax on consumed income would be challenged<br />

on the ground that the Sixteenth Amendment does not allow imposition<br />

of a direct tax on amourits borrowed. Such a challenge might impair<br />

administration of the tax pending resolution of the dispute in the<br />

courts.<br />

4. International issues. A shift by the U.S. to a consumed income<br />

tax would at best be disruptive of international relatipns, would<br />

increase the opportunities to use <strong>for</strong>eign transactions to avoid or<br />

evade U.S. taxes, <strong>and</strong> would provide tax incentives <strong>for</strong> immigration <strong>and</strong><br />

emigration.<br />

The U.S. tax in the world economy, Under current law, U.S. citizens,<br />

residents, <strong>and</strong> corporations are taxed on their worldwide income,<br />

with credit <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>eign income taxes paid. Nonresident aliens <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>for</strong>eign corporations are generally taxed on their U.S. source income.<br />

It would be impossible to require all international savings transactions<br />

to flow through U.S. qualified accounts. There<strong>for</strong>e, a shift<br />

to a consumed income tax would apply only to U.S. residents; <strong>for</strong> them<br />

the tax base would be worldwide consumption. A deduction <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>eign<br />

income taxes paid could be allowed; however, it would be difficult to<br />

devise a workable <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit. For nonresidents (citizens <strong>and</strong><br />

noncitizens alike), the tax base would continue to be income -- income<br />

from U.S. sources (which would be a change <strong>for</strong> nonresident citizens).<br />

The corporate income tax could be eliminated <strong>for</strong> both domestic <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>for</strong>eign corporations, though retaining it during a transition period<br />

would help phase out the <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit. In order to tax the<br />

corporate income of nonresident investors, "withholding-at-source"<br />

taxes on their dividends <strong>and</strong> interest could be raised; taxing their<br />

share of earnings retained by U.S. corporations would be more<br />

problematical.<br />

Eliminating the corporate income tax <strong>and</strong> replacing the <strong>for</strong>eign tax<br />

credit with a deduction would increase the attraction of U.S. investment,<br />

relative to investments elsewhere, <strong>for</strong> domestic <strong>and</strong> some <strong>for</strong>eign<br />

businesses. Other nations might object to the resulting capital<br />

outflow. In addition, after the many years that the U.S. has had a<br />

<strong>for</strong>eign tax credit <strong>and</strong> advocated it as a mechanism <strong>for</strong> relieving<br />

double taxation <strong>and</strong> achieving "capital export neutrality," other<br />

nations might protest the replacement of the credit with a deduction<br />

as a breach of a longst<strong>and</strong>ing commitment. In many cases, such a<br />

change would require overriding an existing U.S. tax treaty with the<br />

other country.<br />

Compliance. Detecting <strong>for</strong>eign borrowing <strong>and</strong> receipts from <strong>for</strong>eign<br />

corporations raises compliance problems <strong>for</strong> a consumed income tax that


- 205 -<br />

are more serious than under an income tax. U.S. residents could<br />

borrow abroad <strong>and</strong> then "save" the unreported <strong>for</strong>eign borrowing in a<br />

domestic qualified account, thereby lowering current year taxes by<br />

taking a deduction <strong>for</strong> the "saving". This would not necessarily<br />

reduce the present value of their tax liability, since they would not<br />

be able to deduct future repayments on the loan. (If such repayments<br />

were deductible at lower rates, taxes would be reduced.) It may,<br />

however, be viewed as inequitable to allow those taxpayers with access<br />

to <strong>for</strong>eign lenders to juggle the timing, if not the present value, of<br />

their tax liability. Futhermore, the proper timing of <strong>for</strong>eign loans<br />

<strong>and</strong> U.S. deposits would enable the taxpayer to reduce somewhat the<br />

present value of the tax liability, as long as there were no withholding<br />

on the loan. Allowing deductions <strong>for</strong> investments in <strong>for</strong>eign<br />

business that the U.S. could not monitor would enable taxpayers to<br />

consume the return <strong>and</strong> repayment of those investments tax free.<br />

Solutions could be devised to stop this type of abuse. They would<br />

require, however, a great deal of added complexity, either by tracing<br />

funds flowing into <strong>and</strong> out of the U.S., or disallowing deductions <strong>for</strong><br />

investments in countries with which the U.S. does not have effective<br />

exchange of in<strong>for</strong>mation arrangements.<br />

Emisration <strong>and</strong> immigration. A pioneering shift by the U.S. to a<br />

consumed income tax would also encourage individuals to emigrate to<br />

avoid 1J.S taxes in times of high consumption, such as retirement.<br />

Exit taxes <strong>and</strong> an expansive definition of residence could moderate<br />

this tendency, although again at the cost of increased complexity.<br />

Immigrants would also be required to include in their receipts assets<br />

brought into the country to prevent them from sheltering 1J.S. consumption.<br />

These twin issues of immigration <strong>and</strong> emigration have not<br />

weighed heavily in U.S. debates on the consumed income tax, but<br />

several European nations have considered them major obstacles.<br />

8. Economic Disadvantages<br />

All tax systems distort some <strong>for</strong>m of economic behavior -- consumption<br />

choices, the work-leisure tradeoff, the consumption-saving tradeoff,<br />

financing decisions, production decisions, <strong>and</strong> the decision to<br />

comply with or evade taxes. The types of decisions affected depend on<br />

the transactions included in the tax base. Both a comprehensive<br />

consumed income tax <strong>and</strong> a broad-base income tax would reduce many of<br />

the economic distortions in current law by lowering marginal tax rates<br />

<strong>and</strong> treating all sources <strong>and</strong> uses of income more consistently.<br />

One of the advantages of a consumed income tax, under certain <br />

circumstances, is neutrality with respect to the consumption-saving<br />

tradeoff. However, in order to achieve this neutrality while <br />

financing a given level of Federal Government services, the exclusion <br />

of net savings from the tax base requires higher marginal tax rates on <br />

the remaining taxable items. Higher marginal tax rates increase the <br />

efficiency losses from the remaining distortions in the tax system. <br />

1. Higher marginal tax rates on wages. As noted above, marginal <br />

tax rates on wage income would be higher under a consumed income tax


- 206 -<br />

since capital income would effectively be excluded from the tax base,<br />

As a result, the consumed income tax would discourage work ef<strong>for</strong>t more<br />

than would a broad-base income tax applied to both capital <strong>and</strong> labor<br />

income. The work disincentive would fall hardest on second workers.<br />

The higher marginal tax rate might encourage more non-market activity<br />

or underground economy activity that is not subject to tax, further<br />

narrowing the base <strong>for</strong> a consumed income tax.<br />

2. <strong>Tax</strong> preferences under a consumed income tax. Much of the discussion<br />

of consumed income taxes has implicitly been overly optimistic<br />

about the possibilities of the repeal of all tax preferences <strong>and</strong> the<br />

complete neutrality toward saving that consumption tax treatment would<br />

imply.<br />

Under a consumed income tax, the effective tax rate applied to <br />

income from capital would be zero only if no <strong>for</strong>m of capital income <br />

benefitted from preferential tax treatment. But historical experience<br />

in the united States suggests that zero would only be an upper bound <br />

on the taxation of capital income under a consumption tax. <br />

Under an ideal consumed income tax all interest income would be<br />

exempt until consumed. In such a system state <strong>and</strong> local securities<br />

would lose their tax advantage over other investments. If political<br />

<strong>for</strong>ces succeeded in maintaining the existing differential between the<br />

treatment of interest from state <strong>and</strong> local bonds <strong>and</strong> other <strong>for</strong>ms of<br />

investment income, it would be necessary to pay a Federal subsidy on<br />

interest from such bonds. Similarly, if it were desired to continue<br />

preferential tax treatment <strong>for</strong> housing, energy or other natural<br />

resources, research <strong>and</strong> developmenc, or any of the many other <strong>for</strong>ms of<br />

investment that now benefit from preferential treatment, it would be<br />

necessary to extend to those activities a negative effective tax rate.<br />

To provide any preferential treatment of particular investments<br />

through the tax Code, legal tax shelters would have to be permitted,<br />

with the resulting economic distortions <strong>and</strong> perception of unfairness.<br />

Negative effective tax rates would perpetuate the type of distorting<br />

effect that the present tax system has on the allocation of resources.<br />

As under current law, the investment projects that were the most<br />

productive <strong>for</strong> the economy would not necessarily provide the most<br />

attractive after-tax yield. This differential would lead resources to<br />

flow to less productive uses, preventing the economy from reaching its<br />

maximum level of output <strong>and</strong> growth.<br />

Even if preferential tax treatment is not accorded to particular<br />

investments, a consumed income tax with graduated rates <strong>and</strong> a tax<br />

threshold may reduce the effective tax rate on some saving below zero.<br />

This is inherent in the typical pattern of lifetime saving <strong>and</strong> consumption.<br />

(See Figure 9-1.) Most saving occurs during middle age<br />

(during working <strong>and</strong> child-raising years) at the same time when family<br />

consumption is highest <strong>and</strong> thus marginal tax rates are highest.<br />

Dissaving <strong>and</strong> borrowing occur during periods when consumption is lower<br />

<strong>and</strong> thus when marginal tax rates are lower. There<strong>for</strong>e, the present<br />

value of the tax deduction of savings (<strong>and</strong> repayment of debt) would<br />

possibly be greater than the present value of the tax liability on


- 207 -<br />

Q<br />

-<br />

(d<br />

.....<br />

U­<br />

Y­<br />

.... O<br />

(d<br />

a,<br />

>-<br />

v<br />

-0<br />

(d<br />

a,<br />

I <br />

.--<br />

x E<br />

a,<br />

2 <br />

a, <br />

e,<br />

m<br />

L. <br />

a,<br />

><br />

a<br />

W


- 208 -<br />

borrowing <strong>and</strong> dissaving <strong>for</strong> some taxpayers. The tax system would <br />

actually subsidize saving, paying people to save at the cost of higher<br />

taxes <strong>and</strong> tax rates on labor income. This problem might be reduced in <br />

a system with relatively wide tax brackets. <br />

3. Corporate taxes under a consumed income tax. One of the<br />

advantases of a consumed income tax is that reveal of the corvorate<br />

income fax would obviate the need <strong>for</strong> a complicated scheme ofintegrating<br />

the corporate <strong>and</strong> individual income tax systems. Because<br />

investment income would not be subject to tax until consumed, there is<br />

no theoretical justification <strong>for</strong> a corporate income tax under a<br />

consumed income tax. As discussed above, there are other reasons,<br />

however, why the corporate income tax might be retained with a<br />

consumed income tax. If the corporate income tax were retained, the<br />

mechanism by which capital income is exempted from tax would pose<br />

significant problems.<br />

Under a consumed income tax, all purchases of capital investments <br />

are deducted immediately (expensed). The large upfront deductions of <br />

investment would offset income earned, <strong>and</strong> in many cases would be <br />

larger than needed to simply offset all tax liability. Any business <br />

that grows fast enough or is less profitable than average would owe no <br />

Federal income tax liability. Only firms that grow relatively slowly <br />

or have above average profitability would pay corporate tax. This <br />

result would cause the fairness of the tax to be questioned. <br />

The tax system is not likely to allow <strong>for</strong> full benefit of tax<br />

deductions via refunds of excess deductions, due to serious perception<br />

problems. In order <strong>for</strong> firms to utilize excess deductions, there<br />

would need to be generous carryover rules with payment of interest by<br />

the Federal Government on such "losses". Otherwise -- <strong>and</strong> perhaps<br />

even then -- companies would find it attractive to merge with, or<br />

acquire other firms to create a new <strong>for</strong>m of tax shelter. This tax<br />

incentive can be expected to distort managerial decisions on firm<br />

size, ownership, <strong>and</strong> product mix, as well as increase industrial<br />

concentration <strong>and</strong> reduce competition.<br />

4. Government as business partner. The deduction <strong>for</strong> saving <strong>and</strong><br />

investment has the effect of making the government a "silent partner"<br />

in the investment. With a 20 percent tax rate, a person or corporation<br />

would only have to save $4,000 to invest $5,000; the government<br />

provides the other $1,000 through lower taxes. Only if the investment<br />

is successful will the government get its money back when the investor<br />

decides to use the profits to finance consumption. If the investment<br />

fails, the government would lose its investment. Having the government<br />

as a partner may influence investors' choices of risk. They may<br />

be less cautious in risking losses since some of the money at stake is<br />

not their own, but they may also be less adventuresome in seeking high<br />

returns since they have to share the proceeds with the government.


- 209 -<br />

Any tax system which is based on voluntary compliance must be <br />

perceived as fair <strong>and</strong> equitable. Although theoretical arguments can <br />

be made about the fairness of a consumed income tax over the lifetime <br />

of taxpayers (always subject to various assumptions), the public<br />

perception of fairness is likely to be judged annually at the time of <br />

payment of tax, rather than over the individual's entire lifetime. <br />

1. Perception of lifetime fairness. Many taxpayers borrow when <br />

they are young <strong>and</strong> establishing families <strong>and</strong> most draw down accumula­<br />

ted-savings (dissave) during retirement. During middle age, peop1.e <br />

save to retire previous indebtedness <strong>and</strong> accumulate wealth with which <br />

to finance retirement. Under the current tax on annual income, most <br />

families pay relatively little tax when they are young <strong>and</strong> have low <br />

incomes <strong>and</strong> again when they are old <strong>and</strong> retired <strong>and</strong> drawing down <br />

accumulated wealth; by comparison, they pay relatively mor'e tax during<br />

middle age. Under the consumed income tax there would be a shift in <br />

tax liability toward periods of borrowing <strong>and</strong> dissaving <strong>and</strong> away from <br />

periods of saving <strong>and</strong> repayment of debt. Thus, although similar in <br />

present value terms, taxes would be higher during early adulthood <strong>and</strong> <br />

retirement than under the income tax; similarly, during middle age <br />

taxes would be lower than under the annual income tax. Though an <br />

economic argument can be made that this pattern of tax payments is <br />

more neutral <strong>and</strong> more equitable than that under the income tax, it <br />

seems unlikely that this would be the public perception. <br />

2. Perception of fairness between rich <strong>and</strong> poor. There is a <br />

general presumption that all taxes on consumption must be regressive,<br />

because consumption falls as a percentage of income as income rises. <br />

While this presumption is generally accurate <strong>for</strong> consumption taxes <br />

based on transactions, such as a value-added tax or retail sales tax,<br />

it need not be accurate <strong>for</strong> a personal tax on consumed income. A tax <br />

on consumed income can be made progressive by allowing personal<br />

exemptions, a zero-bracket amount, <strong>and</strong> graduated rates. <br />

The ultimate judgement on the fairness of the income tax relative<br />

to a tax on consumed income comes down to a subjective choice between<br />

income <strong>and</strong> consumption as the more appropriate st<strong>and</strong>ard <strong>for</strong> measuring<br />

both economic equals <strong>and</strong> economic inequality <strong>for</strong> tax purposes. If the<br />

accumulation of wealth has value beyond the consumption that it can<br />

buy -- if it confers power, prestige, or peace of mind -- then annual<br />

consumption does not measure equals. In that case, a consumed income<br />

tax would unavoidably be unfair even if it assessed the same tax on<br />

all individuals with the same lifetime income.<br />

A distinction is sometimes made between wealth that individuals <br />

accumulate during their lifetimes as a result of their own energies,<br />

<strong>and</strong> wealth that is inherited from previous generations. The treatment <br />

of gifts <strong>and</strong> bequests under a consumed income tax then becomes an <br />

important factor in judging the overall fairness of the system.


- 210 -<br />

Indeed some supporters of a consumed income tax consider such a tax <br />

equitable only if gifts <strong>and</strong> bequests are taxed to both the donor <strong>and</strong> <br />

the beneficiary. <br />

D. Transition Problems <br />

One of the most serious obstacles to adoption of a consumed income <br />

tax is the treatment of existing wealth. Movement to a tax on <br />

consumed income raises special transition issues beyond those that <br />

result from any broad-based tax re<strong>for</strong>m. The unique issues involve how <br />

consumption out of wealth accumulated under the current income tax <br />

("old wealth") should be treated, <strong>and</strong> how repayment of debt incurred <br />

under the current system ("old debt") should be treated. <br />

There are three possible approaches to these issues, each of which <br />

has significant drawbacks. <br />

<strong>Tax</strong>ing old wealth. First, all old wealth could be subject to tax <br />

when consumed. With no special transitior. rules, old wealth would be <br />

treated the same as newly accumulated wealth. <strong>Tax</strong>ing old wealth (<strong>and</strong><br />

deducting repayment of old loans) would broaden the tax base immedi­<br />

ately, <strong>and</strong> thus permit low tax rates, but it would be an inequitable<br />

approach to transition <strong>and</strong> fraught with compliance problems. <br />

All wealth existing on the effective date of the new tax would<br />

have to be registered <strong>and</strong> considered to be in qualified accounts.<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>payers would have a clear incentive to understate assets. This<br />

could be done most easily by converting them to cash or balances held<br />

abroad. Such assets could then be fed back into the system as saving<br />

or used <strong>for</strong> tax-free consumption. Though this problem would be<br />

temporary, until all hidden assets had been revealed, the revenue loss<br />

<strong>and</strong> inequities it would produce would be enormous. To prevent<br />

hoarding of cash, it might be necessary to introduce a new system of<br />

money on the effective date of the consumed income tax. To prevent<br />

hoarding in <strong>for</strong>eign accounts, even more far-ranging steps, possibly<br />

including <strong>for</strong>eign exchange controls, would be necessary.<br />

Individuals consuming out of old wealth would generally be taxed<br />

twice: Once when they had saved under the income tax out of after-tax<br />

dollars, <strong>and</strong> then again when they consume under the new tax on<br />

consumed income. This would be particularly difficult <strong>for</strong> the elderly<br />

because many would have saved without counting on a second tax on<br />

their consumed income. Conversely, issuers of old debt would receive<br />

a windfall gain. They would deduct interest <strong>and</strong> repayments o f<br />

principal, even though the loan was never included in their tax base.<br />

Special relief could be provided to older taxpayers, but only by<br />

complicating the system considerably. The practical difficulties of<br />

wealth inventory at the beginning of the new tax system <strong>and</strong> the<br />

extreme inequities of taxing old wealth <strong>and</strong> subsidizing old debt make<br />

this approach infeasible.<br />

Exempting old wealth. Second, all old wealth could be exempt from <br />

the new tax. If all wealth owned on the day the consumed income tax


- 211 -<br />

became effective were considered to be in nonqualifed accounts, then <br />

these savings would not be subject to tax when used <strong>for</strong> consumption,<br />

<strong>and</strong> double taxation would not be a problem. This approach, however,<br />

would allow wealthy holders of old wealth to eliminate all tax lia­<br />

bility <strong>for</strong> years into the future (perhaps generations) simply by<br />

shifting assets from nonqualified accounts to deductible qualified <br />

accounts, thereby reducing their tax liability. Separate accounting<br />

<strong>for</strong> old <strong>and</strong> new wealth would greatly complicate comp1,iance <strong>and</strong> admini­<br />

stration. The reduction in the tax base would necessitate such high<br />

marginal tax rates on the remaining tax base that any efficiency gains<br />

from a consumed income tax would be postponed <strong>for</strong> decades. <br />

Partial exclusion of old wealth. A middle ground solution would<br />

be essential, in which taxpayers were allowed some minimal amount of<br />

tax-free consumption from accumulated wealth. One possible approach<br />

to reduce windfall gains <strong>and</strong> losses would be to allow a limited amount<br />

of old wealth accumulated out of after-tax income to buy tax-free<br />

consumption, but to allow a deduction only <strong>for</strong> new saving (not <strong>for</strong><br />

repayment of debt). Windfall gains <strong>and</strong> double taxation of existing<br />

wealth would be reduced, but not eliminated. Distinguishing between<br />

old <strong>and</strong> new saving would be difficult <strong>and</strong> would require complex rules,<br />

such as those required to determine what portion of the trillions of<br />

dollars worth of existing l<strong>and</strong>, housing, stocks, <strong>and</strong> other <strong>for</strong>ms of<br />

wealth was purchased out of after-tax income. MOreOVer, 1,imitations<br />

on tax-exempt consumption would be difficult to monitor <strong>and</strong> to<br />

administer when the taxpaying unit changes. At the very least, such a<br />

partial exclusion of consumption would complicate tax compliance <strong>and</strong><br />

administration <strong>for</strong> nearly a generation.<br />

Iv.<br />

Conclusions <br />

The tax on consumed income has considerable attraction. Partic­<br />

ularly important is the fact that under the consumed income tax the <br />

most vexing problems in the measurement of income from business <strong>and</strong> <br />

capital that plague the current income tax simply do not exist. By<br />

comparison, the oft-repeated economic advantages of neutrality toward <br />

saving <strong>and</strong> of equity from a lifetime perspective appear to be <br />

secondary. <br />

The disadvantages of a consumed income tax appear to outweigh<br />

these advantages. First, the advantages are purchased at the cost of <br />

excluding all capital income from tax, a policy that is questionable <br />

on equity grounds. Moreover, exempting capital income from tax as a <br />

matter of course implies that certain activities can be accorded <br />

preferential treatment only by taxing them at negative effective tax <br />

rates. The implications of negative tax rates <strong>for</strong> the misallocation <br />

of the nation's capital stock are striking, indeed. <br />

Second, the first nation to implement a tax on consumed income <br />

will find itself totally out of step with the international <br />

conventions <strong>for</strong> the taxation of multinational business.


-- 212 -<br />

Third, while a consumed income tax would be simpler <strong>for</strong> business,<br />

it would probably not be simpler <strong>for</strong> most individuals. Withholding<br />

would probably be Less accurate <strong>and</strong> more taxpayers would be required <br />

to file estimated taxes, <br />

Fourth, the transition to a tax on consumed income raises<br />

especially troublesome problems. It would not be satisfactory either<br />

to tax all consumption out of previously accumulated wealth or to<br />

exempt all such consumption. But any system of partial exemption<br />

would cause considerable complexity <strong>for</strong> a generation of taxpayers. A<br />

different type of transition problem involves the possibility of preeffective<br />

date hoarding to avoid paying tax on consumption.<br />

Fifth, advocates of a tax on consumed income do not agree on the<br />

proper tax treatment of gifts or bequests. Some would support a<br />

consumed income tax only if gifts <strong>and</strong> bequests were treated as taxable<br />

consumption of the donor; others would strenuously oppose taxing these<br />

transfers to the transferror. The implications <strong>for</strong> the pattern of tax<br />

burdens on wealthy individuals are quite profound.<br />

All things considered, the Treasury Department has decided against<br />

proposing a tax on consumed income <strong>and</strong> in favor of a modified flat tax<br />

on income.


I. Introduction <br />

- 213 -<br />

Chapter 10 <br />

VALUE-ADDED TAX AND RETAIL SALES TAX <br />

In addition to the income tax re<strong>for</strong>ms described above, the<br />

Treasury Department also considered a different option, the imposition<br />

of a national sales tax. This chapter describes the types of sales<br />

taxes considered <strong>and</strong> their advantages <strong>and</strong> disadvantages, with emphasis<br />

on their economic effects. Volume I11 of the <strong>Tax</strong> <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong> Report discusses<br />

these issues in much greater detail, focusing on the valueadded<br />

tax. This is the <strong>for</strong>m of sales tax that would be most appropriate<br />

<strong>for</strong> use at the Federal level, if a decision was ever made in favor<br />

of a national sales tax.<br />

11. Alternative Forms of Sales <strong>Tax</strong>ation <br />

Sales taxes may be single stage in nature, applying to only one<br />

stage in the production or distribution process, such as a retail or<br />

manufacturers tax, or to all stages, such as a value-added tax. only<br />

two types of general sales tax deserve serious consideration <strong>for</strong> adoption<br />

by the Federal Government, a retail sales tax <strong>and</strong> a value-added<br />

tax extending through the retail. level. Sales taxes that do not<br />

include the retail level, such as a manufacturers or wholesale tax or<br />

a value-added tax that stopped at the wholesale level, are inferior<br />

alternatives <strong>and</strong> should not be considered <strong>for</strong> the United States.<br />

A. Retail Sales <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

Forty-five of the states, the District of Columbia, <strong>and</strong> many local <br />

governments have a retail sales tax, a single-stage tax that applies <br />

to all sales to final consumers, not just those made by retailers. A <br />

retail sales tax is levied on all final or retail sales of goods <strong>and</strong> <br />

services except those that are exempt from tax. More than one half of <br />

the states, <strong>for</strong> example, exempt food consumed at home <strong>for</strong> distribu­<br />

tional reasons. Most services are not taxed, except in a few states,<br />

partly to achieve social objectives <strong>and</strong> partly <strong>for</strong> administrative <br />

reasons. Many, but not all, sales to business firms are exempt. This <br />

exemption is achieved by allowing firms to make tax-free purchases of <br />

various categories of goods, such as those purchased <strong>for</strong> resale, or by<br />

exempting certain items commonly bought only by businesses, such as <br />

equipment <strong>and</strong> machinery. The exemption of business purchases is <br />

necessary to prevent a product, or inputs into its production, from <br />

being taxed more than once as it moves through the production-distri­<br />

bution process. Exports (other than those made directly by <strong>for</strong>eign<br />

tourists in the united States) are not taxed under a retail sales tax,<br />

but imported goods are taxed when sold at retail in a state with a <br />

sales tax. <br />

459-370 0 - 84 - 9


- 214 -<br />

The operation of a 5 percent retail sales tax is illustrated in<br />

the simple two-stage example in Table 1. It is assumed that a winery<br />

grows its own grapes, makes no purchases of produced goods from other<br />

firms, <strong>and</strong> makes no retail sales, but sells $200 worth of wine to a<br />

grocery store. The grocer sells the wines purchased from the winery<br />

to households <strong>for</strong> $300. With a retail sales tax, no tax would apply<br />

on the sales by the winery to the grocer because these are not retail<br />

sales; since the wine purchased is <strong>for</strong> resale, the grocer is registered<br />

to make tax-free purchases. But the grocer would collect $15 on<br />

his retail sales of $300. (See line d.)<br />

Compared to a tax with numerous exceptions <strong>and</strong> exclusions, a<br />

broad-based retail sales tax would be less likely to interfere with<br />

decisions by individuals <strong>and</strong> business firms on what to consume <strong>and</strong><br />

what to produce <strong>and</strong> would be easier to administer. Ideally, a comprehensive<br />

retail sales tax would apply to all consumpti’on expenditures.<br />

For 1988, the projected level of total personal consumption<br />

expenditures is about $3,100 billion <strong>and</strong> each percentage point of a<br />

tax levied on this total would there<strong>for</strong>e yield about $31 billion. In<br />

fact, any realistic sales tax base would probably be well below this,<br />

because of the difficulty or inadvisability of taxing certain types of<br />

consumer expenditures. As explained below, a more realistic, but<br />

comprehensive base would base be about $2,400 billion.<br />

8. Value-Added <strong>Tax</strong><br />

Though the value-added tax is unfamiliar to most Americans, it is<br />

imposed throughout much of the rest of the world. A value-added tax<br />

that extends through the retail level is levied on each firm in the<br />

production <strong>and</strong> distribution chain, from the extraction of raw materials<br />

through the manufacturing <strong>and</strong> distribution processes, to the<br />

last sale to final customers. Thus, under a comprehensive value-added<br />

tax, all businesses, not just those that sell at retail, would pay tax<br />

on their sales. An important characteristic of a value-added tax is<br />

that tax is applied only to the value added by the firm, that is, to<br />

the excess of its sales over its purchases of goods from other business<br />

firms. A value-added tax is usually collected by the tax credit<br />

method; each firm applies the tax rate t o its taxable sales, but is<br />

allowed a credit <strong>for</strong> value-added tax paid on its purchases of goods<br />

<strong>and</strong> services <strong>for</strong> business use, including the tax paid on purchases of<br />

capital equipment under a consumption-type value-added tax. As a<br />

result, the only tax <strong>for</strong> which no credit would be allowed would be<br />

that collected on sales made to households, rather than to businesses.<br />

Since the sum of the values added at all stages in the production <strong>and</strong><br />

distribution of a good are equal to the retail selling price of the<br />

good, the revenue base of a retail sales tax <strong>and</strong> a value-added tax<br />

with the same coverage are theoretically identical, <strong>and</strong> a given tax<br />

rate will yield the same amount of tax revenue under either approach.<br />

Thus, despite its multistage character, a value-added tax is very much<br />

like a retail sales tax in that it is a tax on expenditures by consumers.


- 215 -<br />

Table 10-1<br />

ILLUSTRATION OF A RETAIL SALES TAX<br />

AND A VALUE-ADDED TAX<br />

(<strong>Tax</strong> Rate is 5 Percent)<br />

Assumed Facts Winery<br />

Grocery<br />

Store Total <br />

a. Sales 200 300 **<br />

b. Purchases 0 200 **<br />

c. Value added (a-b) 200 100 **<br />

Calculation of Retail Sales <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

d. <strong>Tax</strong> (5% of a, <strong>for</strong> grocer only) * 15 15<br />

Calculation of Value-Added <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

e. <strong>Tax</strong> on sales (5% of a) 10 15 **<br />

f. Credit <strong>for</strong> tax on purchases<br />

(5% of b)<br />

0 10 **<br />

g. Net tax (e-f) 10 5 15 <br />

* Retail sales tax is collected only on retail sales by grocer; it<br />

is not levied on sales by the winery.<br />

** Not relevant <strong>for</strong> illustration.


- 216 -<br />

The value-added tax can also be illustrated using the simple<br />

example in Table 1. Both the winery <strong>and</strong> the grocery store would collect<br />

the 5 percent tax on their sales ($10 <strong>and</strong> $15, respectively, on<br />

sales of $200 <strong>and</strong> $300), <strong>and</strong> both would be allowed a credit <strong>for</strong> tax<br />

paid on business purchases. In this example, the winery has no purchases<br />

from other firms <strong>and</strong> thus no credit <strong>for</strong> tax paid, but the<br />

grocer is allowed a credit <strong>for</strong> the $10 in tax collected by the winery<br />

on sales to the grocer. Since the tax is on final consumers, no<br />

credit is allowed <strong>for</strong> the $15 of tax collected on the grocer's sales<br />

to households. As with a retail sales tax, value-added tax would not<br />

be charged on export sales, but it would apply to imports.<br />

This illustration reveals a key characteristic of the value-added<br />

tax: it is simply an alternative means of collecting a tax that has<br />

ultimate effects quite similar to those of a retail sales tax. This<br />

point is further illustrated in the example of Table 1 by noting that<br />

the total amount of tax collected from the winery <strong>and</strong> the grocer under<br />

the value-added tax, $15 (see the "total" column in line g), is the<br />

same as that collected from the grocer alone under a retail sales tax<br />

(see line d). Consideration of more detailed examples involving imports,<br />

exports, capital goods, intermediate goods, <strong>and</strong> more complex<br />

processes of production <strong>and</strong> distribution does not seriously alter this<br />

fundamental conceptual equivalence between an ideal retail sales tax<br />

<strong>and</strong> a value-added tax of the type most likely to be imposed in the<br />

United States.<br />

This similarity between the two taxes greatly simplifies the task <br />

of Americans trying to underst<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> assess the advantages <strong>and</strong> disad­<br />

vantages of the unfamiliar value-added tax. For most purposes, one <br />

can simply consider the pros <strong>and</strong> cons of a "sales tax," without asking<br />

whether the tax is to be implemented as a retail tax or as a value-<br />

added tax. Only if it is decided that a Federal sales tax may be <br />

desirable must attention turn to more detailed consideration of the <br />

differences in the way the two taxes are administered <strong>and</strong> to the eco­<br />

nomic effects created by those administrative differences. These dif­<br />

ferences are considered briefly below <strong>and</strong> in greater detail in Volume <br />

111. <br />

C. Advantages of uni<strong>for</strong>m Rates<br />

To avoid unintended distortions in consumer behavior, a sales tax<br />

should constitute a uni<strong>for</strong>m percentage of all consumption expenditures.<br />

This objective can be best achieved with a broad-based retail<br />

sales or value-added tax imposed at a single rate. Still, the experience<br />

of the states with the retail sales tax <strong>and</strong> of European countries<br />

with the value-added tax shows that it may be necessary to exclude<br />

some goods or services from the tax base <strong>for</strong> distributional reasons or<br />

to help achieve social objectives. For example, exclusion of food or<br />

medical care may be deemed necessary to avoid imposing an undue burden<br />

on those below the poverty level, <strong>and</strong> education <strong>and</strong> religious activities<br />

may be excluded from taxation as a way of encouraging these<br />

activities. Any exclusions from the tax base, however, should be kept


- 217 -<br />

to a minimum <strong>and</strong> should be solidly justified on the basis of distribu­<br />

tional, social, or administrative necessity. Apart from the exclu­<br />

sions that are necessary to achieve these goals, there should be only <br />

one rate of tax, <strong>and</strong> it should be applied to a comprehensive tax base. <br />

There are both administrative <strong>and</strong> economic reasons <strong>for</strong> this judgment.<br />

First, differences in rates impose on business firms <strong>and</strong> their<br />

employees the necessity to know which rate to apply to any given item<br />

<strong>and</strong> the obligation to make the proper distinction as sales are made.<br />

If orange juice, <strong>for</strong> example, is tax free, but juice substitutes are<br />

taxed at the st<strong>and</strong>ard rate, <strong>and</strong> orange soda is taxed at a higher<br />

luxury rate, then each grocery store clerk must know which rate to<br />

apply to these different products. Distinctions of this type also<br />

greatly complicate tax administration, since it is necessary <strong>for</strong><br />

auditors to verify the rates reported on various sales.<br />

The use of multiple or differential rates also interferes with tax <br />

neutrality by distorting consumer choices away from highly taxed items <br />

<strong>and</strong> toward lightly taxed ones. The end result is reduced consumer <br />

satisfaction <strong>and</strong> a less efficient use of the economy's resources. <br />

This is why it would be preferable not to exclude food from the tax <br />

base, if there is an acceptable <strong>and</strong> effective alternative <strong>for</strong> reducing<br />

the sales tax burden on the poor. For the same reasons, services, as <br />

well as goods, should be subject to tax. The failure to tax expendi­<br />

tures on services favors those persons with relatively strong pref­<br />

erences <strong>for</strong> services <strong>and</strong> distorts consumption away from commodities <br />

<strong>and</strong> toward services. Moreover, if services are not taxed, the tax <br />

rates on taxable sales or on income must be higher than otherwise in <br />

order to raise a given amount of revenue, thereby creating further <br />

distortions <strong>and</strong> disincentives. <br />

Nor should higher rates be applied to "luxuries" or to goods<br />

deemed not to be necessities in an ef<strong>for</strong>t to increase the progressivity<br />

of the tax system. Doing so distorts consumption decisions <strong>and</strong><br />

creates difficulties in complying with the tax <strong>and</strong> in administering<br />

it. Moreover, it is unnecessary. Given the existence of a progressive<br />

individual income tax, it is far easier to increase progressivity,<br />

if that is the goal, by adjusting the structure of income tax<br />

rates.<br />

D. Sales <strong>Tax</strong>es Unworthy of Consideration<br />

The retail sales tax <strong>and</strong> a value-added tax extending through the <br />

retail level are the only types of sales tax that should be considered <br />

<strong>for</strong> adoption by the United States. Thus, even if a Federal sales tax <br />

is thought useful, the United States should categori,callyreject: a <br />

single-stage tax levied be<strong>for</strong>e the retail level, such as a manufactur­<br />

ers or wholesale tax; a value-added tax that does not include the re-<br />

tail stage; <strong>and</strong> a multiple-stage "turnover" or cascade tax that allows <br />

businesses no credit <strong>for</strong> tax paid on purchases <strong>for</strong> business use.


- 218 -<br />

Developing countries view nonretail taxes as attractive since the<br />

number of taxpayers needs to be kept to a manageable size <strong>for</strong> administrative<br />

<strong>and</strong> en<strong>for</strong>cement purposes. Moreover, recordkeeping is often<br />

not adequate to apply a sales tax to the numerous small firms at the<br />

retail level in developing countries. Instead, these countries may<br />

simply collect tax at the manufacturing (or import) stage or on wholesale<br />

sales to retailers. In the United States, in contrast, there is<br />

no administrative or compliance argument against including the retail<br />

level in a sales tax; state experience with the retail sales tax amply<br />

<strong>and</strong> persuasively demonstrates this.<br />

There are many economic <strong>and</strong> administrative disadvantages to <br />

excluding the retail stage from a sales tax. These can be discussed <br />

<strong>for</strong> a single-stage tax that excludes the retail level, though the same <br />

arguments would apply to a value-added tax that is "truncated" to <br />

exclude retailing. Such a tax would be equivalent to a single-stage <br />

tax imposed at the wholesale level. <br />

Suppose that a major oil company is economically integrated from<br />

the oil field to the service station, owning oil fields, refineries, a<br />

wholesale distribution system, <strong>and</strong> even retail outlets. It would<br />

clearly be unfair <strong>and</strong> distortionary to exclude all of the company's<br />

retail sales from taxation, just because the company sells its own<br />

products directly to consumers. Rather, to be fair <strong>and</strong> neutral it<br />

would be necessary to impute a value to the products at the wholesale<br />

level in order to achieve parity with those retailers not associated<br />

with a comparable integrated company. But to assign a value, <strong>for</strong> tax<br />

purposes, to "sales" between affiliated enterprises would be administratively<br />

burdensome, possibly open to abuse, <strong>and</strong> it would be especially<br />

difficult in those industries in which products are not<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ardized <strong>and</strong> in which there are few sales occurring at market<br />

prices between unrelated parties.<br />

Even in the absence of any manipulation of imputed prices <strong>and</strong> the <br />

administrative ef<strong>for</strong>t that would be required to prevent it, omitting<br />

the retail level from the tax base would create economic distortions <br />

that would waste resources <strong>and</strong> favor or penalize both consumers <strong>and</strong><br />

firms in a capricious <strong>and</strong> haphazard manner that was totally unrelated<br />

to any policy objective. A retail sales tax or value-added tax that<br />

extended through the retail level <strong>and</strong> applied to most goods <strong>and</strong> services<br />

would be neutral between types of consumption. By comparison, a<br />

tax that excluded the retail level would favor products of industries<br />

with a high percentage of value added at the retail level. That is,<br />

it would favor products with high retail margins. Services would<br />

probably be excluded from a nonretail tax because they are inherently<br />

a retail activity. A nonretail tax would create an incentive to restructure<br />

business operations to minimize tax liability, basically by<br />

transferring functions <strong>and</strong> costs <strong>for</strong>ward beyond the point of impact of<br />

the tax. In the case of a manufacturers tax, <strong>for</strong> example, activities<br />

that might ordinarily be undertaken by a manufacturer <strong>and</strong> reflected in<br />

the manufacturer's price, such as advertising <strong>and</strong> transportation,<br />

would be spun off to separate subsidiaries beyond the manufacturing<br />

sector or purchased from unrelated firms in order to keep them out of


- 219<br />

the tax base. The manufacturing level tax employed by Canada is <br />

notorious <strong>for</strong> these types of difficulties <strong>and</strong> a value-added tax is <br />

currently under consideration as a replacement. <br />

A multiple-stage turnover tax is even worse than a single-stage<br />

tax levied be<strong>for</strong>e the retail level. Under such a tax, goods are subject<br />

to tax each time they are sold. Thus the amount of tax ultimately<br />

imposed on a given product depends on how many times it has turned<br />

over (been sold) during the production-distribution process. This<br />

distorts economic decisions <strong>and</strong> produces undesirab1,e incentives <strong>for</strong><br />

tax-motivated vertical integration, something a value-added tax avoids<br />

by allowing a credit <strong>for</strong> tax paid on all purchases <strong>for</strong> business use.<br />

In addition, a turnover tax discriminates against products in which<br />

value added occurs early in the production-distribution process, much<br />

as a manufacturers or wholesale tax does. Finally, it is impossible<br />

to remove a turnover tax from exports precisely, since the amount of<br />

tax that has been paid on a given product depends on the degree of<br />

vertical integration <strong>and</strong> whether value is added early or late in the<br />

production <strong>and</strong> distribution chain. For the same reason, it is impossible<br />

to levy a tax on imports to compensate exactly <strong>for</strong> taxes paid on<br />

comparable goods produced domestically. Merely applying the tax to<br />

the tariff-inclusive value of imports is not sufficient because the<br />

imported value will not necessarily be the same as the value at which<br />

the manufacturers or wholesale tax would apply to a domestic good. It<br />

is <strong>for</strong> reasons such as these that turnover taxes have long been<br />

considered unacceptable <strong>and</strong> that the European countries ab<strong>and</strong>oned the<br />

turnover tax in favor of the value-added tax when the Common Market<br />

was established.<br />

111. Pros <strong>and</strong> Cons of a National Sales <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

A Federal retail sales or value-added tax that included the retail<br />

level would have both advantages <strong>and</strong> disadvantages. Since little<br />

needs to be said in describing the advantages, they are simply listed<br />

here. The disadvantages are described in greater detail, since they<br />

are more specific to this particular <strong>for</strong>m of taxation.<br />

A. Advantages of a Sales <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

A national sales tax would have several major advantages that are<br />

discussed in detail in Volume 111. If it were used to replace part of<br />

the income tax, a Federal sales tax would allow even lower income tax<br />

rates. By taking pressure off the definition <strong>and</strong> measurement of taxable<br />

income, a sales tax would help reduce income tax avoidance <strong>and</strong><br />

evasion as well as lessen the incentive to shelter income from the<br />

income tax. Based on consumption, rather than income, a national<br />

sales tax would not discriminate against saving the way the income tax<br />

does. Accordingly, it may increase the level of private saving <strong>and</strong><br />

generate a corresponding increase in capital <strong>for</strong>mation <strong>and</strong> economic<br />

growth. A broad-based sales tax would almost certainly distort<br />

economic choices less than the income tax does. In contrast to the<br />

income tax, it would not discourage capital-intensive methods of<br />

production or risk taking <strong>and</strong> it would be neutral with regard to<br />

--


- 220 -<br />

consumption behavior, neither encouraging nor discouraging consumption<br />

of particular goods or services.<br />

One claim commonly made <strong>for</strong> a value-added tax, that it would<br />

improve the competitive position of U.S. products in world markets, is<br />

generally incorrect. Under international rules, exports may be sold<br />

free of any sales tax <strong>and</strong> imports pay the same sales tax as<br />

domestically-produced goods. Thus, a value-added tax could be rebated<br />

on goods that are exported; similarly, value-added tax could be<br />

collected on imported goods, either at the time of importation or at<br />

the first domestic sale. The refund of taxes on exports <strong>and</strong><br />

collection of tax on imports, known as border tax adjustments, are<br />

sometimes likened to an export subsidy <strong>and</strong> import tariff, which, at<br />

fixed exchange rates, would stimulate exports <strong>and</strong> discourage imports.<br />

But these border tax adjustments simply allow U.S. exports to<br />

occur free of value-added tax; they do not reduce the price at which<br />

U.S. exports were sold be<strong>for</strong>e the tax was imposed, Imposing the tax<br />

on imports merely places imports on an equal tax footing with domestic<br />

goods. Thus, by itself, a value-added tax is no more likely than a<br />

retail sales tax to have favorable effects on international trade. A<br />

retail sales tax would not apply to exports either, <strong>and</strong> it would apply<br />

to retail sales of imported goods. Only if a sales tax replaced part<br />

of a tax that could not be rebated on exports or collected on imports,<br />

such as the corporation income tax, would there be reason to expect<br />

that U.S. products would be more competitive. This would only happen,<br />

however, if the substitution of a sales tax <strong>for</strong> the corporate income<br />

tax did not cause the domestic price level to increase <strong>and</strong> if exchange<br />

rates are fixed.<br />

B. Disadvantages of a Sales <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

1. <strong>Growth</strong> of government. The United States st<strong>and</strong>s almost alone<br />

among the developed countries of the free world in not levying a national<br />

sales tax. Virtually all of the members of the European<br />

Economic Community (EEC) employ a national value-added tax. (Greece,<br />

which recently joined the Community, is scheduled to adopt a valueadded<br />

tax on January 1, 1986).<br />

Of the twenty-three members of the<br />

Organization <strong>for</strong> Economic Cooperation <strong>and</strong> Development (OECD), only two<br />

countries -- Japan <strong>and</strong> Turkey -- use neither a value-added tax nor a<br />

general sales tax.<br />

The lack of a national sales tax in the United States is reflected<br />

closely in the percentage of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) devoted to<br />

public use in the United States <strong>and</strong> in other countries. In 1982 total<br />

tax revenues at all levels of government averaged 30.5 percent of GDP<br />

in the United States. The comparable figure <strong>for</strong> the EEC countries was<br />

40.1 percent <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> the countries of the OECD, exclusive of the<br />

United States, it was 37.1 percent. In the United States, sales taxes<br />

(state <strong>and</strong> local) took approximately 6 percentage points less of GDP<br />

than in the EEC <strong>and</strong> in the OECD (exclusive of the United States). It<br />

is not only sales taxes that are lower in the United States; corporate<br />

income <strong>and</strong> social security taxes also are substantially lower in the


- 221 -<br />

United States than in many other developed countries. Still, these <br />

figures suggest that even if a sales tax were initially imposed as a <br />

partial replacement <strong>for</strong> the income tax in a revenue-neutral change,<br />

public spending in the United States would eventually be greater with <br />

a national sales tax than without one. <br />

2. Regressivity. A general sales tax is often criticized as unfair<br />

to lower income individuals <strong>and</strong> families. There are two aspects<br />

to this equity argument: the absolute burden of the tax on the lowest<br />

income groups, <strong>and</strong> the regressi,vityof the tax or the relatively higher<br />

burden of the tax at the lower income levels thap at the higher.<br />

As explained below, there are four alternatives <strong>for</strong> lessening the<br />

burden of the tax on the poor. For those individuals <strong>and</strong> families<br />

that are above the poverty level of income <strong>and</strong> thus subject to the<br />

income tax, the regressivity of a sales tax can be offset through the<br />

adjustment of income tax rates or through non-refundable credits<br />

against the income tax.<br />

3. Effect on prices. Assuming an accommodating monetary policy, a<br />

sales tax would almost certainly increase the price level by roughly<br />

the percentage it represents of consumption spending. That is, a 4<br />

percent sales tax that applied to 75 percent of consumption expenditures<br />

wouldiincrease the general price level by about 3 percent.<br />

Although this would be a one-time occurrence, not an annual increase,<br />

it might cause "ripples" of wage increases, because of cost-of-living<br />

adjustments! <strong>and</strong> these could be reflected in further price increases.<br />

To the extent the sales tax replaced part of the income tax, there<br />

would be little offsetting reduction in prices or wages.<br />

4. Administrative costs. Administration of a Federal value-added<br />

tax would require substantial additional resources. The Internal<br />

Revenue Service estimates that once the administrative program was<br />

fully phased in, the annual administrative costs would run about $700<br />

million (at 1984 prices), or about 0.4 percent of revenues from a 10<br />

percent broad-based value-added tax. To administer a value-added tax,<br />

the IRS would require approximately 20,000 additional personnel.<br />

5. Federal pre-emption. States, <strong>and</strong> more recently local governments,<br />

consider the sales tax base their exclusive fiscal domain.<br />

Federal imposition of a sales tax might reduce somewhat the ability of<br />

state <strong>and</strong> local governments to tax that base <strong>and</strong> would there<strong>for</strong>e be<br />

seen by those governments as an unwelcome intrusion. This concern<br />

could be reduced if Federal adoption of a retail sales tax led to<br />

increased cooperation between the various levels of governments in tax<br />

administration <strong>and</strong> collection. This cooperation would be much easier<br />

to achieve if the Federal Government adopted a retail sales tax than<br />

if it adopted a value-added tax. If the state <strong>and</strong> Federal tax bases<br />

were identical, state taxes could be collected by the Federal<br />

Government as it collected its own tax. Of course, a Federal sales<br />

tax could not simply be collected by the states, because of the<br />

current differences in state tax bases.


- 222 -<br />

IV. Relevance of the European Experience <br />

Though the reasons that motivated the European countries to switch <br />

to the value-added tax during the late 1960s <strong>and</strong> the 1970s are largely<br />

irrelevant <strong>for</strong> the present debate in the United States, European ex­<br />

perience does contain important lessons <strong>for</strong> the United States. Be<strong>for</strong>e <br />

adopting the value-added tax, most of the members of the EEC had mul­<br />

tiple-stage turnover taxes of the type described <strong>and</strong> analyzed above. <br />

As a result, the switch to the value-added tax represented a rational-. <br />

ization <strong>and</strong> clear improvement of the European tax systems, rather than <br />

the creation of a new source of revenue. The United States, by com­<br />

parison, does not have an inefficient sales tax that needs to be over-<br />

hauled. <br />

The European switch to the value-added tax involved a relatively<br />

minor change in tax administration. There<strong>for</strong>e, few additional admin­<br />

istrative resources were required. By comparison, since the United <br />

States has no Federal sales tax, a substantial increase in IRS admin­<br />

istrative resources would be required to implement a value-added tax. <br />

Because the European value-added taxes replaced existing sales <br />

taxes, there was little effect on consumer prices or on the distribu­<br />

tion of tax burdens across income classes. By comparison, an American <br />

value-added tax would raise prices in the year it was introduced <strong>and</strong> <br />

would add a regressive element to the Federal tax system, unless steps <br />

were taken to reduce the regressivity. <br />

European experience also indicates that a consumption-type valueadded<br />

tax, collected by the tax credit method, would be the most<br />

appropriate type <strong>for</strong> the United States <strong>and</strong> that serious administrative,<br />

compliance, <strong>and</strong> efficiency problems are involved in the use of<br />

the tax to achieve non-revenue objectives. That is, multiple rates of<br />

tax <strong>and</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>ts to favor certain types of consumption by exclusions or<br />

lower rates involve significant costs <strong>and</strong> complexities, as well as<br />

revenue losses.<br />

V. <strong>Tax</strong> Ease <strong>and</strong> Revenue Potential <br />

Total personal consumption expenditures are estimated to be about<br />

$3,100 billion in 1988; each percentage point of a value-added tax<br />

levied on this total would yield $31 billion. In fact, the tax base<br />

is likely to fall well below total consumption, <strong>for</strong> a number of reasons.<br />

Since certain items would be excluded either <strong>for</strong> distributional<br />

or administrative reasons, a more realistic, but broad, base would be<br />

about $2,400 billion in 1988 levels of expenditure. If food consumed<br />

at home also is excluded, the tax base would fall to $2,000 billion.<br />

The most important items of personal consumption that are excluded<br />

from the tax base in arriving at these figures are described briefly<br />

below <strong>and</strong> discussed more fully in Volume 111.<br />

Owner-occupied housing is difficult to tax under any sales tax. <br />

Ideally, housing services would be taxed over the life of a house, but <br />

this is clearly impossible because of the difficulty of valuing the


- 223 -<br />

housing consumed by owner occupants, the value of the so-called "imputed<br />

rent" or what the house would rent <strong>for</strong> on the open market.<br />

Since the "rent" on owner-occupied housing cannot be taxed, it would<br />

be unfair <strong>and</strong> distortionary to tax the rents on tenant-occupied residential<br />

housing. One alternative would be to tax newly-constructed<br />

housing while excluding the rental value of residential housing from<br />

the tax base (both tenant- <strong>and</strong> owner-occupied). This alternaive would<br />

reduce the base by about $290 billion in 1988. If this approach<br />

imposes an unacceptable tax burden on housing, another alternative,<br />

following the practice with state retail sales taxes, would be to tax<br />

the cost of materials entering into new housing construction, repair,<br />

an6 alterations.<br />

A number of other personal consumption items would also probably<br />

not be included even in the most comprehensive value-added tax base<br />

<strong>for</strong> a variety of reasons. Medical care, educational expenses, <strong>and</strong><br />

religious <strong>and</strong> welfare expenses would probably not be taxed <strong>for</strong> social<br />

<strong>and</strong> distributional reasons. Because of the problems of defining value<br />

added, it would be difficult to tax certain banking services <strong>and</strong><br />

insurance, <strong>and</strong> tax could not be collected on the consumption expenditures<br />

of Americans travelling abroad, but <strong>for</strong>eigners travelling in<br />

the United States would pay tax on some items. There also would be<br />

pressure to exclude urban transit service, which is heavily subsidized.<br />

Combined with the proposed treatment of housing, exclusion<br />

of all of these items from the tax base would result in a comprehensive<br />

value-added tax base of about $2,400 billion, or 77 percent of<br />

total personal consumption expenditures of $3,100 billion.<br />

VI.<br />

Reducing Regressivity <br />

The most frequent objection to any <strong>for</strong>m of general sales tax is<br />

its regressivity, <strong>and</strong> especially the burden it places on families with<br />

incomes below the poverty level. Regressivity within the portion of<br />

the population subject to the income tax -- roughly those above the<br />

poverty level in the present proposals <strong>for</strong> income tax re<strong>for</strong>m -- can be<br />

offset by changes in income tax rates or by tax credits; but no adjustment<br />

of tax rates or non-refundable credits can eliminate the<br />

sales tax burden on those below the income tax threshold.<br />

There are four possible approaches to removing the burden of a<br />

sales tax on low-income households below the income tax threshold.<br />

First, food <strong>for</strong> home consumption can be excluded from the tax base.<br />

This approach is followed in 27 of the state sales taxes. (One state<br />

uses a lower rate <strong>for</strong> food.) There are, however, problems with this<br />

approach. Even though expenditures on food consumed at home are regressive<br />

(a larger percentage of income being spent on food at low<br />

income levels than at middle <strong>and</strong> upper income levels), about 80<br />

percent of the revenue loss from excluding food from the tax base<br />

would be from expenditures by those wih incomes above the poverty<br />

level. Given the administrative <strong>and</strong> economic advantages of applying<br />

uni<strong>for</strong>m rates to a comprehensive base, exclusion of food is not a<br />

desirable way to reduce regressivity.


- 224 -<br />

A second approach would be to establish a system of refundable<br />

credits under the income tax to offset the burden of the sales tax on<br />

the consumption expenditures necessary <strong>for</strong> a minimum st<strong>and</strong>ard of<br />

living. Though this approach could, in principle, effectively<br />

eliminate the burden of a sales tax on an essential level of consumption,<br />

it also suffers from a number of drawbacks. First, if the<br />

credit is available to all taxpayers, rather than just low income<br />

individuals <strong>and</strong> families, it is expensive. If the credit were available<br />

to everyone, it would absorb about one-third of the revenue from<br />

the sales tax. While it would reduce the burden of the sales tax <strong>for</strong><br />

families below the poverty line, 90 percent of the credit would go to<br />

those above the poverty level. This demonstrates that the credit<br />

should be phased-out <strong>for</strong> incomes above the poverty level; a credit<br />

that is phased-out between the poverty level of income <strong>and</strong> 150 percent<br />

of that level would absorb about a tenth of the revenue from a sales<br />

tax. A phased-out credit, however, would be more complex <strong>and</strong>, in<br />

effect, would generate higher marginal income tax rates'over the<br />

phase-out range. A credit of either type may also be viewed as establishing,<br />

in embryonic <strong>for</strong>m, the administrative machinery <strong>for</strong> a new<br />

social program such as a family assistance plan. It can be argued<br />

that the desirability of such a program should be debated explicitly<br />

in the context of welfare re<strong>for</strong>m, rather than being introduced as a<br />

by-product of adopting a sales tax. Several of the states, however,<br />

have used this approach <strong>for</strong> lessening the burden of the sales tax<br />

without kindling a debate over welfare re<strong>for</strong>m.<br />

The third approach is indexed transfer payments. If all families<br />

below the poverty income line received government transfers, <strong>and</strong> no<br />

one else did, it would be relatively easy to overcome the low-income<br />

burden of a sales tax; transfers could simply be increased to offset<br />

the sales tax paid by low income families. But not all low income<br />

individuals <strong>and</strong> families receive transfers, <strong>and</strong> many above the poverty<br />

level do receive them. Even so, adjustment of transfers offers a<br />

third potential means of reducing sales tax burdens on the poor.<br />

A personal exemption type of value-added tax would be a fourth<br />

method of eliminating the sales tax burden on low-income families.<br />

Under this approach, which would differ substantially from a conventional<br />

value-added tax, workers would be considered to be "sellers" of<br />

labor services <strong>and</strong> would be subject to a value-added tax, but they<br />

could not take credits <strong>for</strong> value-added tax on their purchases of<br />

consumption goods. Employers would be allowed a credit <strong>for</strong> the taxes<br />

"charged" by employees on their wages. Treating employees as sellers<br />

of labor, rather than employees, changes the value-added tax in one<br />

crucial way: it would allow the introduction of personal exemptions<br />

in the calculation of the value-added tax liability of workers. That<br />

is, workers could be allowed an exemption from value-added tax <strong>for</strong> a<br />

specified amount of the income earned from "selling" their labor to<br />

the employer. This approach could alleviate the burden of the tax on<br />

low-income individuals receiving labor income, but it would not help<br />

those not receiving labor income, such as retirees without pensions or<br />

the unemployed. The approach also raises some questions about whether


- 225 -<br />

the tax would be shifted to consumers to the same extent that a <br />

tradi,tionalvalue-added tax would be shifted. <br />

VII. Value-Added <strong>Tax</strong> versus Retail Sales <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

The value-added tax <strong>and</strong> the retail sales tax are collected in dif­<br />

ferent ways; thus they have somewhat different administrative impli­<br />

cations <strong>and</strong> economic effects, despite their basic similarity. On <br />

balance the administrative advantages of the value-added tax appear to <br />

outweigh the primary administrative advantage of the retail sales tax <br />

in the American context, its much greater familiarity. <br />

Purchases <strong>for</strong> business use should not be taxed under a sales tax;<br />

otherwise production techniques will be distorted, the value of a<br />

product will be taxed more than once, <strong>and</strong> exports will be penalized.<br />

IJnder a value-added tax any tax collected on capital goods, intermediate<br />

products, or other inputs to the production-distribution process<br />

is allowed as a credit against the tax imposed on the sales made by<br />

the purchasing firm. This means that goods <strong>and</strong> services purchased <strong>for</strong><br />

business use are automatically freed from tax; by <strong>and</strong> large, only<br />

goods <strong>and</strong> services sold to households are ultimately taxed under the<br />

value-added tax. <strong>Tax</strong> auditors need only to check the purchasing firm<br />

to ensure that purchases <strong>for</strong> which a credit is claimed were used <strong>for</strong><br />

business purposes. By comparison, it is more difficult under a retail<br />

sales tax to completely exempt all business purchases. Firms must<br />

provide exemption certificates to their suppliers to buy tax free, <strong>and</strong><br />

auditors must check both the supplier <strong>and</strong> purchaser in cases of doubt.<br />

At the state level, this system of exemption certificates applies only<br />

to goods purchased <strong>for</strong> resale or goods that become component parts or<br />

physical ingredients of produced goods; other purchases, such as<br />

machinery <strong>and</strong> equipment, are only exempt if specifically provided in<br />

the state statute. The end result is that not all business purchases<br />

are free of retail sales tax; about 20 percent of sales tax revenue is<br />

from taxing business purchases.<br />

Another important advantage of the value-added <strong>for</strong>m of sales tax<br />

is the fact that tax is collected as products move from stage to stage<br />

in the production-distribution process. Thus by the time a product<br />

reaches the retail stage, much of its total value has already been<br />

taxed. (In the example of Table 1, two-thirds of the tax was<br />

collected from the winery, <strong>and</strong> only one-third from the grocer.) This<br />

means that tax evasion at the retail level is less of a problem under<br />

a value-added tax than under a retail sales tax; under the latter tax,<br />

evasion at the retail level means that no tax is collected. (Of<br />

course, all previously collected revenue from the value-added tax<br />

could be lost if the retailer understates sales but claims a credit<br />

<strong>for</strong> all value-added tax paid on purchases.) The possibility of<br />

collecting tax be<strong>for</strong>e the retail level can be particularly important<br />

in the case of sales by street vendors <strong>and</strong> purveyors of certain<br />

services in the legal underground economy. A Federal sales tax of as<br />

little as 4 percent, together with state <strong>and</strong> local taxes, could<br />

produce a combined rate of tax of 10 percent or more in many states,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the combined rate could easily exceed 15 percent if the value-


- 226 -<br />

added tax approached European rates. Rates this high could increase <br />

the incentives <strong>for</strong> evasion. <br />

Related to this advantage is the audit trail provided by the chain<br />

of taxes <strong>and</strong> credits with the value-added tax. In the example of<br />

Table 1, the grocer can only claim credit <strong>for</strong> tax paid on purchases<br />

from the winery if the grocer can produce an invoice documenting that<br />

he was charged tax by the winery. Auditors can then trace the invoice<br />

back to see that the winery remitted to the government the tax claimed<br />

as a credit by the grocer. There is no such paper trail under a<br />

retail sales tax.<br />

VIII.<br />

Implementation <br />

A value-added tax could not be imposed quickly by employing the <br />

existing personnel <strong>and</strong> practices of the Internal Revenue Service. <br />

Rather, it would be necessary to employ <strong>and</strong> train additional IRS <br />

agents, acquire additional computer capability, establish new adminis­<br />

trative procedures, <strong>and</strong> engage in a major ef<strong>for</strong>t in taxpayer educa­<br />

tion. These requirements are described more fully in Volume 111. The <br />

Internal Revenue Service estimates that it would need 18 months after <br />

enactment be<strong>for</strong>e it could begin to administer a value-added tax. <br />

Thus, if legislation imposing a value-added tax were enacted in late <br />

1985, the tax could be made effective July 1, 1987. <br />

The one-time start-up costs <strong>for</strong> recruiting <strong>and</strong> training IRS<br />

agents, acquiring enhanced computer capabilities, <strong>and</strong> educating the<br />

public about the value-added tax are substantial. These start-up<br />

costs indicate clearly that the value-added tax should not be considered<br />

as a temporary source of revenue. Moreover, given the magnitude<br />

of both the start-up costs <strong>and</strong> the on-going annual costs of administration<br />

<strong>and</strong> compliance, it would be unwise to introduce a value-added<br />

tax at less than at a rate of 5 or 6 percent. (Some experts believe<br />

that imposition at a rate below 10 percent would not be sensible.)<br />

Ix.<br />

Conclusions <br />

Because of its inherent regressivity, a Federal value-added tax or<br />

other <strong>for</strong>m of general sales tax should not be adopted as a total replacement<br />

<strong>for</strong> the income tax. Implementing a Federal sales tax would<br />

be costly <strong>and</strong> it would take time. There<strong>for</strong>e, it does not seem desirable<br />

to introduce a Federal sales tax solely as a replacement <strong>for</strong> part<br />

of the present income tax, even though doing so would take pressure<br />

off the latter. <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m</strong> of the income tax, along the lines proposed in<br />

Chapters 5 through 7 is a more appropriate avenue of fundamental tax<br />

re<strong>for</strong>m in a revenue neutral context.<br />

For economic <strong>and</strong> administrative reasons any Federal sales tax that <br />

is adopted should extend through the retail level <strong>and</strong> should be <br />

applied as widely as possible at a uni<strong>for</strong>m rate of tax. The value <br />

added technique appears to be somewhat preferable to the retail sales <br />

technique as a means of implementing a sales tax.


- 227 -<br />

A Federal sales tax would have considerable advantages <strong>and</strong> serious <br />

disadvantages. These must be weighed carefully in deciding whether a <br />

sales tax should be imposed. The advantages include neutrality toward <br />

saving, capital <strong>for</strong>mation, production techniques, <strong>and</strong> consumption de­<br />

cisions. The disadvantages are reqressivity, a one-time increase in <br />

prices, Federal intrusion into the sales tax area, the administration <br />

<strong>and</strong> compliance costs of a new Federal sales tax, <strong>and</strong> the likelihood of <br />

greater public expenditures. Any proposal <strong>for</strong> introducing a sales tax <br />

should include steps to relieve the tax burden on low-income indivi­<br />

duals <strong>and</strong> families.


- 229 -<br />

APPENDIX A <br />

EFFECTIVE DATES AND TRANSITION RULES <br />

Implementing the Treasury Department's re<strong>for</strong>m proposal will<br />

involve a fundamental tradeoff. On the one h<strong>and</strong>, immediate<br />

implementation of the proposals would be desirable in order to capture<br />

as soon as possible the gains in equity, economic neutrality <strong>and</strong><br />

simplicity described at length in this report; immediate implementation<br />

would also be the simplest policy, as it would avoid<br />

inevitably complex transition rules. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, immediate<br />

implementation of the proposals would be unfair <strong>and</strong> disruptive;<br />

taxpayers who made commitments based on the current tax structure<br />

would suffer unanticipated gains <strong>and</strong> losses when the tax law was<br />

changed suddenly. Such re<strong>for</strong>m-induced windfall gains <strong>and</strong> losses<br />

amount to essentially arbitrary redistributions of income <strong>and</strong> are<br />

there<strong>for</strong>e an undesirable, if inevitable, consequence of re<strong>for</strong>m. The<br />

magnitude of the gains <strong>and</strong> losses induced by implementation of the<br />

Treasury Department's proposal could be reduced by delaying or<br />

phasing-in implementation or by using "gr<strong>and</strong>fathering" provisions<br />

which guarantee current tax treatment to taxpayers who made commitments<br />

based on current law.<br />

The Treasury Department's proposal provides <strong>for</strong> a fair <strong>and</strong> orderly<br />

transition by striking a balance between the conflicting objectives of<br />

maximizing the equity, economic neutrality <strong>and</strong> simplicity gains of<br />

rapid implementation <strong>and</strong> minimizing the arbitrary redistributions of<br />

income induced by unexpected tax re<strong>for</strong>m. All four of the implemetation<br />

options described above -- immediate coupled with<br />

gr<strong>and</strong>fathering provisions, delayed, phased-in, <strong>and</strong> immediate -- are<br />

utilized toward this end. The proposed effective dates <strong>and</strong> transition<br />

rules <strong>for</strong> each element of the Treasury Department's proposal are<br />

summarized in Table A-1; the listing of proposed changes corresponds<br />

to those in Appendixes 5-A, 6-A, <strong>and</strong> 7-A. The proposed effective<br />

dates <strong>and</strong> transition rules assume that legislation is introduced in<br />

early 1985, <strong>and</strong> that the re<strong>for</strong>m package is enacted on July 1, 1985<br />

with a general effective date of January 1, 1986.<br />

The proposed transition rules can be divided into four general<br />

categories. Detailed descriptions of the transition rules are <br />

provided in Volume 11. The four general categories are summarized as <br />

follows. <br />

(1) Immediate implementation with gr<strong>and</strong>fatherinq. Where feasible,<br />

gr<strong>and</strong>fathering provisions are effective in avoiding re<strong>for</strong>m-induced<br />

windfall gains <strong>and</strong> losses. They have the effect of applying the new<br />

tax laws to new commitments but avoiding a change in the tax treatment<br />

of commitments made on the basis of current law. Elements of the<br />

proposal which provide <strong>for</strong> permanent gr<strong>and</strong>fathering of existing


- 230 -<br />

commitments include the new real economic depreciation rules, the<br />

elimination of the investment tax credit, the extension of the at risk<br />

rules, the elimination of a variety of special expensing <strong>and</strong><br />

amortization rules <strong>and</strong> other subsidies, the taxation of certain life<br />

insurance <strong>and</strong> annuity income, the new treatment of insurance company<br />

loss reserves, changes in the treatment of irrevocable non-grantor<br />

trusts, <strong>and</strong> the unification of the estate <strong>and</strong> gift tax laws. Note<br />

that whenever gr<strong>and</strong>fathering occurs, it will generally benefit<br />

taxpayers to qualify <strong>for</strong> such treatment. In order to prevent a flood<br />

of tax-motivated commitments made prior to the general enactment date,<br />

gr<strong>and</strong>fathering frequently will be granted only to commitments made<br />

prior to the date legislation is introduced; note that such treatment<br />

is more generous than granting gr<strong>and</strong>fathering only to commitments made<br />

prior to the announcement date of a proposal, as has sometimes<br />

occurred in the past.<br />

Gr<strong>and</strong>fathering can also be provided on a temporary basis, where<br />

the goal is to reduce the windfalls caused by re<strong>for</strong>m, but to subject<br />

all commitments to the same tax treatment by some fixed point in time.<br />

This is the approach taken <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m in the area of fringe benefits,<br />

where the new rules will apply as contracts expire or, at the latest,<br />

by January 1, 1989; also, application of the new rules will be delayed<br />

<strong>for</strong> one year in the cases of the two largest fringe benefits,<br />

employer-provided health care <strong>and</strong> life insurance, in order to allow<br />

time <strong>for</strong> employers <strong>and</strong> insurance companies to adjust to the new tax<br />

law. Similarly, partnerships existing prior to the date legislation<br />

is introduced will not be subject to the new corporate-type taxation<br />

until January 1, 1990.<br />

Treatment similar in spirit to temporary gr<strong>and</strong>fathering is <br />

proposed in several areas where the proposal will eliminate unfair <br />

preferential tax treatment, but immediate implementation would result <br />

in a large one-time increase in income as previously tax-advantaged<br />

income is brought into the tax base. In these cases, the adverse <br />

effects of the one-time increase in income will be tempered by<br />

allowing the increase in income to be spread evenly over a fixed <br />

number of years <strong>for</strong> tax reporting purposes. This treatment is <br />

proposed <strong>for</strong> the elimination of special bad debt deductions <strong>and</strong> the <br />

deduction <strong>for</strong> additions to "protection against loss" accounts by<br />

property <strong>and</strong> casualty insurance companies, the restriction of the use <br />

of cash accounting, <strong>and</strong> the new rules <strong>for</strong> insurance policyholder<br />

loans. <br />

(2) Delayed implementation. Delayed implementation of some of the<br />

Treasury Department's proposals is recommended <strong>for</strong> four reasons.<br />

First, delay reduces the magnitude of re<strong>for</strong>m-induced redistri­<br />

butions by postponing the change in tax liability <strong>and</strong> by allowing time <br />

<strong>for</strong> existing commitments to expire. For these reasons, interest <br />

indexing will be postponed until January 1, 1988, <strong>and</strong> capital gains<br />

indexing (on non-depreciable assets) will be postponed until January<br />

1, 1989.


- 23:l -<br />

Second, delay allows time <strong>for</strong> rebudgeting in cases where the <br />

elimination of preferential tax treatment should be offset by<br />

appropriate increases in Federal, state or local expenditures. For <br />

this reason, the changes in the taxation of military compensation <strong>and</strong> <br />

of unemployment <strong>and</strong> workers' compensation will be delayed until <br />

January 1, 1987. <br />

Third, delay allows time <strong>for</strong> adjustment to new rules. Many of the <br />

changes in the taxation of estates will be delayed <strong>for</strong> one year in <br />

order to allow estate planners time to adjust to the new rules. <br />

Similarly, the replacement of the possessions tax credit with a wage<br />

credit will be delayed <strong>for</strong> one year to allow businesses time to adjust <br />

to the new tax structure. <br />

Fourth, repeal of the individual <strong>and</strong> corporate minimum taxes --<br />

subject to full implementation of the re<strong>for</strong>m proposal -- will be<br />

delayed until January 1, 1990 in order to subject to taxation existing<br />

preferences which are gr<strong>and</strong>fathered.<br />

(3) Phased-in implementation. Phasing-in implementation is<br />

recommended <strong>for</strong> several elements of the Treasury Department re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

package. Since phasing-in involves a modified <strong>for</strong>m of delayed<br />

enactment, it not only has the advantage of reducing the magnitude of<br />

re<strong>for</strong>m-induced redistributions, but also the further advantage of<br />

capturing some of the equity <strong>and</strong> economic neutrality gains from re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

immediately. Phasing-in is recommended <strong>for</strong> the dividend relief<br />

proposal, the elimination of the itemized deduction <strong>for</strong> state <strong>and</strong><br />

local taxes, the new limit on charitable contributions, the<br />

elimination of graduafed corporate tax rates, the extension of the<br />

limit on interest deductions, <strong>and</strong> the denial of business deductions<br />

<strong>for</strong> entertainment expenses <strong>and</strong> meal costs in excess of a limit.<br />

(4) Immediate implementation. In many cases, the Treasury<br />

Department's re<strong>for</strong>m proposals can be implemented immediately with<br />

little effect on existing commitments. The changes in the zero<br />

bracket amount, personal exemptions, <strong>and</strong> a variety of credits <strong>and</strong><br />

deductions fall into this category; the changes in individual <strong>and</strong><br />

corporate rates will be delayed <strong>for</strong> six months solely to achieve the<br />

goal of revenue neutrality in the initial year after enactment.<br />

Similarly, the extension of Individual Retirement Accounts <strong>and</strong> the new<br />

rules on pension distributions will be implemented immediately.<br />

Another class of proposals where re<strong>for</strong>m should be implemented<br />

immediately are those involving provisions that are particularly<br />

objectionable in terms of violating equity principles. These include<br />

some changes in trust rules, limits on deductions <strong>for</strong> business<br />

expenses away from home, <strong>and</strong> highly preferential special rules <strong>for</strong><br />

life <strong>and</strong> property <strong>and</strong> casualty insurance companies. Similarly, in<br />

view of the strong equity <strong>and</strong> neutrality arguments <strong>for</strong> elimination of<br />

the special preferences <strong>for</strong> the energy <strong>and</strong> natural resource<br />

industries, the Treasury Department proposes that these preferences be<br />

repealed immediately; to reduce the impact of immediate implementation


- 232 -<br />

or1 the energy industry, the repeal of the windfall profits tax will be<br />

accelerated by three years, with the scheduled three-year phase-out<br />

beginning on January 1, 1988 instead of JatlUaKy 1, 1991.


m<br />

W<br />

rl<br />

a <br />

c<br />

0<br />

- 233 -<br />

m m m m<br />

R U W U W<br />

U u r t u r l<br />

-3 a<br />

rl 4 4 m e<br />

2<br />

U<br />

5<br />

W<br />

c<br />

.".I<br />

W<br />

U ><br />

.I W<br />

m .4<br />

c<br />

l: U<br />

2 m<br />

El<br />

a <br />

m<br />

m<br />

W<br />

U<br />

m<br />

a <br />

W<br />

><br />

.,3<br />

U<br />

0<br />

W<br />

w<br />

W u) u) u) u) u) u) r - a, m m m m m a m<br />

I I 1<br />

..- ..- ..--<br />

Ị<br />

I<br />

I<br />

c ..- - I I ..-- 1<br />

a <br />

0 <br />

"3 . R m<br />

m 4 m<br />

2 W<br />

W 4 W rl<br />

c) m u 0 a w<br />

EE2 U 0 W<br />

4 11 3<br />

x om N 00 1<br />

mw<br />

a<br />

U O W<br />

m U "3<br />

male 4<br />

.-+I4 (R 4<br />

m<br />

*l.m<br />

e a<br />

a<br />

W xrl 4<br />

0<br />

m m o W +I 4<br />

EU4. e .I 01<br />

W 4 a<br />

a- m m W U W O w<br />

-a 4 ee3 0<br />

m o Y 51 W O U<br />

mal: 0 au<br />

n, c X c cw<br />

m mw 3 m W "4"3<br />

l o El a<br />

r l m 4 W 0 4 m 0 0 a m o<br />

u ma w om<br />

Rid a4 ­<br />

a m w U c m-3<br />

c a4. C m ­<br />

mx H E<br />

m a a 0 I,<br />

m u c a rl 45<br />

~m W .rl w rl<br />

U W e l: 4<br />

mrl m 4 0 c4.<br />

cnh W m ou<br />

CW . W W "3<br />

W '4 R m a rl V U W<br />

u m m W O m X muc N<br />

a 40 W W 450<br />

a 4 x u . a 'D<br />

wom C N 0 C Ri w<br />

aw4.J H(R a H a a -4<br />

.- N<br />

m -r * (D<br />

c;l k m U


~~ ~ ~ ~~ ~<br />

10 m 10<br />

U U 0<br />

u 0<br />

m m m<br />

4 4 4<br />

u u u<br />

fflc m C m c<br />

4 0 4 0 4 0<br />

om o m u m<br />

C i c 3 c ,3<br />

0 4 0 4 0 4<br />

4 oc 3 oc .* oc<br />

aJ wo u wo u wo<br />

m r l m .A m .3<br />

rl -u rl -u d -u<br />

m m u m m ~m m u m ID<br />

aJ 3 aJ-4 3 w r l ,rf wrl m<br />

d m rtvl .?Im m ,..I m I<br />

a aJ 34 m 4.4 a, 1.3 -<br />

e: 4 4m cl 4m rl 4m<br />

-I<br />

maJ ma maJ<br />

C aJ aJd aJ aJd aJ aJrl<br />

0 u u U 4<br />

3 m ww m w a ~ m w a ~ w<br />

U w 3u w .3u w .3u il<br />

-m<br />

- m - m w<br />

1 3<br />

Lo<br />

C<br />

4 w<br />

a J a J<br />

4<br />

m<br />

u<br />

W<br />

co m co m<br />

C<br />

0,.4 u 04 01<br />

m<br />

..34 U.."44<br />

u aw m w u aw a~<br />

ffl<br />

m o h m m ~ J E<br />

aJ<br />

4 muu u 4 mu o<br />

u<br />

,3 c 5 c 5,.4c 5 u<br />

m a,.- w 0 w w c<br />

n<br />

xuouoxuo4<br />

aJm4 4aJffl4<br />

aJ ,.3u 4 u .4 u 4<br />

3 4xc0c4xc0<br />

4 0 aJ ,.Aw ,,40 aJ ,3w<br />

u 0<br />

aJ 10 m u) % I D<br />

w m m m m m m<br />

41 I 1<br />

- -<br />

w 4 w m<br />

0) a J a J<br />

uo u uo w<br />

m u uo<br />

4 w m u w m u w m u m<br />

E4 m a m W m w C<br />

Ị- .<br />

4 4 4<br />

Ị<br />

W -I<br />

...... - I I Ị<br />

I I 1 Ị r<br />

-I<br />

.<br />

I<br />

- 234 -<br />

10<br />

W aJ<br />

aJ<br />

r(<br />

u C 5<br />

C "3 4<br />

2 W<br />

aJ<br />

mal m<br />

0 C C<br />

0 5 m<br />

cw c 0<br />

aJ 00 0<br />

u<br />

u<br />

..I4<br />

m aJu m u<br />

w ac C C<br />

03 .4<br />

4 8<br />

aJ 4ffl<br />

u<br />

u u<br />

03 a, 111<br />

w .-+I m 5<br />

m w c n<br />

a~mo w W<br />

WUC.4 0 m<br />

aJ a.3u<br />

uwum 4 4<br />

COaJd 0 0<br />

m 4c LO w W<br />

4uu4<br />

m c m m<br />

al<br />

"4w a, 2<br />

a0 w 04 0<br />

0 30 4 5 rl<br />

uc 0 rlu rl<br />

dmoo m .A m<br />

clrlc<br />

W<br />

m w m 4 >rC x<br />

.3 E 0 ma, m<br />

4014.3 da d<br />

OaJaJ4 QJX aJ<br />

w d a a WaJ W<br />

ID<br />

-<br />

IDi. i.<br />

m mm m<br />

I I<br />

7-<br />

--<br />

ti<br />

ffl mrl .3 5<br />

c m c u il<br />

odma~<br />

4 4u fflffl ffl<br />

u c m m 3aJ 3<br />

I 1<br />

.<br />

I I 1<br />

- I<br />

-<br />

C<br />

0 <br />

..I<br />

c um In<br />

.rl 3 i.<br />

m o w m 2<br />

aJ cclc I m<br />

I<br />

m a ~ d m .<br />

C - I z - - r l<br />

m m- 4 - 4<br />

I: ox* 4 4 m a<br />

u u m m (uo 0 m 1 w<br />

rlu .YO w x - m - 0 0 4<br />

I<br />

c m a 04 m ..<br />

.-<br />

,"4 4 c<br />

4<br />

3,z<br />

m<br />

0 aJ m 4 "<br />

44 W 0 .4 x<br />

$ ? E m oa >I W<br />

m O I a J w a J ­<br />

w 3-13 m 4 Ci. u<br />

w I c maJ .- a o m m 4<br />

o u - m c.,d ID0 4 l W 0<br />

c ,.34 mw u- w<br />

4 $ou.-45 I U'C<br />

o v u m wn -0 a o u<br />

w x maJcc w .3 -3 P<br />

ffl m 4 c 4 u,,4 .<br />

lil mxu 57<br />

ma, 0',45m a woa m<br />

E 4 m.4 u 4 45 4 4-<br />

3 5 u 4 u .3 w 0 010 wrl3 I<br />

uu c aaJw cw u m-<br />

40 m c m w c 1 ZZ!? :­<br />

m w E m u 01 4 c m 3- x<br />

3 c xalw am0 41 I aam J 1 0<br />

o a~ m .3 o x ,.i mal- I 4 W I<br />

-!$a;4aJuu a J u <br />

cm 25 0 curl c c <br />

m wd'nod a~ ffl m m u 3U5 HaJ<br />

r l c w m c c 3w I WW I E <br />

ha^ m,.3 4 ma, m w 4 W d a l aJu<br />

d m 4 4 E W 4 E m ~ ma u <br />

u 0 0.3 aJ QJ 0<br />

w mwwuw au w 044 corn c c<br />

ma au-<br />

aaJ<br />

-<br />

P P u) ID ID<br />

m m<br />

m m m<br />

I 1<br />

I I Ị<br />

.- 7 -<br />

1 1<br />

I<br />

au aJaJEa c o m a s m u <br />

.. Ị. . I r<br />

m<br />

- 4<br />

aJoc<br />

W m aJw0 aJ<br />

aJ 3 >I "4 ><br />

m 4 omu "4<br />

,,rl aJ al d u m<br />

> 4 u a m m %<br />

0 m aJ E a C aJ<br />

4 0 w aJ4aJ 0<br />

m<br />

fL u 0 2<br />

4 c 4 W O<br />

aJ a, w mcu<br />

x w . 0 u m<br />

0 cu c ux<br />

rl aJc U a m cuu<br />

a 0. (u C rl c al.3 c<br />

W E 0 0 E d OJ<br />

$<br />

8 3.3 x-4 E<br />

w: u u onu<br />

w w c m w a i m<br />

0 05 aJ 0.4 a m aJ<br />

Q 4 U E.3 4<br />

C C E u c o m w u<br />

0 . 04 olnc<br />

3 U l 3 a J d .A m a mrt<br />

mu<br />

.<br />

m 4<br />

c a m<br />

5 .3 a<br />

21 1Jmcla.4 c<br />

rlw rl4 0 E x m r l U 0<br />

UaJ 00 QJ m 4 u m.3<br />

xc X a x m C.Y ao<br />

aJaJ aJm m aJ.3 a, u ma<br />

aJ<br />

U E m<br />

rl Q d o rl. d.3 @.id 0<br />

m e m d m m m w d n mr<br />

aJu aJ> aJc w m a aJu<br />

a m a4 ac aw a0<br />

WaJ m w $2 aJaJ5caJu<br />

e:W a m e:a a n m m a m<br />

.. 0<br />

m v Ln ID P mm .<br />

4<br />

0<br />

W<br />

C<br />

u <br />

C<br />

0<br />

0 <br />

m m 4 <br />

W 0 ma!<br />

C N aJ 4 rla<br />

m -4 U o n<br />

L, m w m N<br />

mc a I, u<br />

m c ,"3w<br />

2.5 W 0 40<br />

cu C 4 m<br />

a J m 3 m 0 u .C m<br />

E 4 5 w 0 om<br />

o m u m a Q<br />

04 c w 4 u<br />

c ow 2 0 aJ o x<br />

HCO m '.A w w aJ<br />

U<br />

w m m z<br />

o m<br />

waJ w<br />

mou 0<br />

a J x<br />

UCaJ C<br />

40 0<br />

a3c<br />

0 m.3<br />

In5 r l m<br />

qua<br />

w x.3<br />

'0 0s<br />

a m<br />

clrl 3<br />

u m o<br />

x mrl<br />

W a3<br />

aJaJ<br />

haw<br />

aJ <br />

c<br />

u.<br />

0-<br />

or<br />

L,. . .<br />

U am n u<br />

N


w<br />

0 <br />

m h<br />

w a<br />

U <br />

X u<br />

wc<br />

a,<br />

C E <br />

.4u <br />

-0<br />

m<br />

cc<br />

ow<br />

"4<br />

url<br />

U 4 <br />

55 <br />

TJW<br />

wa ..,<br />

* m 4<br />

o w<br />

lnx<br />

3-<br />

0 <br />

4 4<br />

40 <br />

mw<br />

I-<br />

Iu<br />

"4 <br />

C E<br />

H .*<br />

I rlP<br />

w m<br />

mrl:<br />

m m<br />

c w 1<br />

I24 E­<br />

w w w W<br />

m m m m<br />

I l l<br />

.-..-..- .<br />

I l l<br />

.-....?- .- I<br />

- 235 -<br />

w<br />

W<br />

m m<br />

Ị I<br />

.-.<br />

I<br />

Ị. ?-<br />

W W W<br />

m m m<br />

1 1 1<br />

.-.-..-.<br />

I l l<br />

.-.....-.<br />

W<br />

m Ị<br />

.<br />

Ị<br />

W<br />

u<br />

U C m<br />

"4.J .<br />

I<br />

u ^nm<br />

rl w m n w ?­<br />

rl w r l a am<br />

mua m 4<br />

mmo m aJ<br />

aa uu w- u<br />

c 0 a4 w<br />

m 4 3 4 o m<br />

wwoau<br />

m u 4.'4rl m 0<br />

uw44aw C<br />

m ao 4 .4<br />

a 3u h<br />

4 a ..,a a<br />

u w a w a 4<br />

u w u w w m<br />

4mumuu<br />

owawaw C<br />

u4a4am<br />

aJ<br />

cuouo a<br />

m 4 40 w<br />

4 m u m u 4 U<br />

mu cu ca<br />

w<br />

m .,r( 10 m a<br />

aJa a u<br />

4 4 m 4 m.i 'u<br />

,n u -4u "44 0<br />

m a<br />

uwc4ca<br />

orlooom<br />

3 .a "4+I.4<br />

w m u c u m<br />

4ummmw<br />

4 0 4 444<br />

.,rl 3 m mm a<br />

w I .4 4<br />

4 4 mc 0,<br />

04aJOaJO<br />

4.,3rlcrlu<br />

u) W W<br />

m m m<br />

I I<br />

. .-. .-.<br />

I I I<br />

.- .-. .-<br />

m 4<br />

C m 0 x 4 aJ<br />

x c 22 r l w<br />

0 C w m w m C W 4 0<br />

uc rlc<br />

"4 . 0 01<br />

0 0 a .,.I<br />

w o<br />

+Im "4 c mc<br />

5.44 u . .4 . $2 Fg<br />

mu<br />

a x u c u<br />

0 C u0-1 . m u<br />

a m<br />

w<br />

n m m a- u m m a x u<br />

m C"40 m<br />

.&ma a m m a u4 rlu~um 2 2 crlwu u ccmm C<br />

u m cw uwm o o m 04<br />

m c m o m u 4s 0<br />

4aa .4w wrlc 0 4 "40 m 5.4 4 m w n ww o c u u.4 w PI 0.4<br />

4.J 40 m u w a 3 W m u5amu<br />

m uoua "3 4 m 4.J VI ..E a<br />

ca> um<br />

au<br />

c c > w a a a u m w ac m 0 m m E c z;g5$ c e a<br />

0 0.4 cu W"4 ale w o cma 4 w w a E O C<br />

uxa 0 a m a 4 r l w 4 aJmE rl ~ 4 u m<br />

wc uc x m u.4 OJ u<br />

w a -* "3 w w .,4c u *a c : w a0 4<br />

Zw3 ua.4mc<br />

a E . <br />

,4J w m <br />

wu c w u aJ .,4 c c x u a 54rl"* o m e wwu<br />

m"4 x a sa w w w m <br />

4 c w m In4 4.4 c w w Erlu.4 4 ric 04<br />

a-lc uu<br />

m n w 4u 3 <br />

rl CI) 3 E 4 m a>.+m<br />

w VI w 4 u u m .u3.4mu a x 4 4<br />

m o m 4 m w aw.4 m<br />

m d 4 m m 3 4 > w m<br />

uo 4 w c aa*cl no4 warm<br />

.* u m 0 11 o x 8<br />

2 m m c w w 4uu 04- rl a~ mu<br />

m w m o<br />

rlou -a4<br />

.4u4u m c<br />

c 4u3c<br />

w 3 a wad 00 m c w ow<br />

m w 04<br />

2h2 tc<br />

m~ x w a ~u "r( uoo4 rl o 4 4 E m.rlu w uc m 0<br />

4 um. 4 a! curr444 a m . z~rluw.4 am u4<br />

Cu E 0.4 wu wu,w Ew w.4 m 4 44m3c 4 uua w 4 w wc<br />

u 4.4 u I24CmEc a ocuww4 0 10 00 a0 oc c aJ c x4 0 0 0<br />

w 4 u<br />

a0<br />

w u .4 4 c c o w w c ."4 u u m-~w m 4 CJ<br />

4 E w $ @* g.2<br />

m<br />

u ..4<br />

om=wu.rla 4 .o w u m a . r m u aJ--mu<br />

0 CX m u wm C rlE c 0 c a.,4rla a wo cri w ( C 4 m .E m<br />

w 4 0 4 w.4 u w aJ C<br />

m .,4c m 0<br />

C am url w . O W 1 w 0 w o.'4uaw 4 ~ 4 mu owa w 0 ma x<br />

WOE O+J+ ,4 , 4 m<br />

-4<br />

m u<br />

m~<br />

u uoc m m.,du 4<br />

u.4 C X W C e<br />

u our( m<br />

+J<br />

uum-L.+Jwu<br />

O m 5 .E* c4 m m 0 w .* .4 u m'o u z :"t:: <br />

m c m.4u<br />

4c c4 w e 4 ...I 4 e<br />

4 w c m .'.Iln 0 aJa a m rl 4 a c.3 c o.awom 0.4 m,40 x 4 a uw<br />

uu m crl cn w m uc m w 4 m a - 4 m a m a > 4<br />

om o c<br />

a<br />

ucm c u.3 Ir<br />

.4* .4 dp .*<br />

x0.n u<br />

u wmumu w -45- E<br />

w a w . 4 m m m mcw.,4u mu m .+Im w m w o<br />

uw 4-4 8<br />

w m 4 w a u.,daa c u cmo4ww .dma c cue u<br />

auouom a m o m a w an OC u cac 4 m w . 4 "44<br />

w wln 3rlu ad ww a<br />

a4 n UJ w d z ) n<br />

mmw .rl<br />

u,".Ia, w c 0 4 4 C.'4 l4<br />

ad<br />

IrQJ4m<br />

.4 4 4 n mau . aorlo wE a<br />

~mmorl.4 '4C m .4<br />

mumam- c xoa m -4 0) c h U 4 m a umm.4 m44-w "4 4 cu c<br />

u TZ2<br />

3~ "4 w4.4 0 DO 0 m u m c ma w<br />

u am 4 m a4 m u 4 lnaw m 10 444 cmuwucucmm E a a m<br />

.rlm vu w u m h a w m .4"4.4 E w cri m w I: h U h.4 xw woe w .'rlw w m "4 m I .A w "3<br />

E aca3 mc3uw m m E O 5 m ~ T mc J<br />

cs c c u ~ u >..* c w 4 0) 4ua a x w u 3<br />

"4w w 0 (UP 0 w 4 xrl a m.4 4 w e om c w w a w L. w.4 mu.4 w mc w 4 a 4 ow c o m.c x w<br />

cloa u.%- mtcn u w o D a il w G. u u w.4 hnwnunr(303 E& m a on uwm a uwu ma<br />

a-4 0<br />

. . . .<br />

nm m a U a w w u a<br />

N


- 236 -<br />

m <br />

W<br />

a, U C<br />

U C ..3<br />

m a,<br />

W 4 a,<br />

a, m<br />

w<br />

C<br />

a,<br />

c<br />

0<br />

m<br />

3 4<br />

-H 4<br />

U a CI 0<br />

m<br />

U U L m<br />

C C W<br />

ffl a, W .4<br />

W C U<br />

rl 8<br />

: 4 s U<br />

s rl a W<br />

a a u m<br />

w<br />

C 5 .-<br />

, w<br />

0 mw 0<br />

-4 U (u<br />

U W 4 L<br />

4 3 OW 0<br />

m "3 u C w <br />

C U U <br />

m 0 ~m <br />

4 W Ew a, 2 <br />

4 .I'D rl ..3<br />

w U C a c,<br />

W W m 4<br />

C m 4<br />

m C 3m C<br />

0 0 0<br />

In "3 rl W .3<br />

a, U rl4 c,<br />

U m m m .d<br />

m rl m<br />

n<br />

m xc<br />

C<br />

3 c mu<br />

m<br />

W mu rtd 4<br />

3<br />

"4<br />

U<br />

U<br />

a, <br />

w W <br />

W a<br />

40<br />

LUC<br />

a3<br />

U<br />

I<br />

U<br />

mw<br />

cw 0<br />

0 X<br />

+ow m w<br />

UUrl U a,<br />

m m c U<br />

4 4C.3 a, m<br />

vlOI E a<br />

.A ,.3 w a, m w<br />

m4cum m<br />

4<br />

4a ,ao2m ma<br />

w c c U<br />

WO.3 QJ-3 w (u<br />

PEIUU orl<br />

m 4 w m m a<br />

WOm4w rlE<br />

wmo mo<br />

4 saw W U<br />

W m a 4 c a<br />

U C 00 Wm<br />

w 0 - u.3 4 .3<br />

m ,.A w +J<br />

UWEm wW<br />

'omus4 04<br />

W4sEO 3<br />

E o w . 3 ~ ~ cU<br />

Laox4 ,.Flu<br />

0 4 4 m 0 la<br />

zm<br />

wOUEU w 4<br />

uc W U<br />

vl .A04<br />

c4 Url<br />

oom m c sa,<br />

.3 w .A at m<br />

U W C l a%<br />

m - c m g - 4 4<br />

L w 0 0.d I ,.I<br />

Oa,.'d 43- U a,<br />

C U<br />

au* u<br />

~ a m c - ham<br />

owrl.3wn 4<br />

uovl m h0<br />

b d t w~ m a<br />

~ U ~ U - rl4 U<br />

ocomtm wo<br />

w.344r.4 woo<br />

w u )<br />

m m<br />

c<br />

m<br />

1 1 I<br />

7 - r<br />

1 1 I<br />

cr. v-<br />

m<br />

vl<br />

c r:<br />

"3<br />

m 0<br />

m<br />

a,<br />

C<br />

"3<br />

rl<br />

m<br />

W<br />

U<br />

C<br />

,"?I w a,<br />

a U W<br />

m .I 0 "4<br />

0 W X 3<br />

W u .A<br />

w<br />

0 4 W<br />

W<br />

u r:<br />

u 4<br />

C<br />

0<br />

0 c c - w<br />

3 m o m .<br />

4J 3 .3 w E C<br />

s m clam mm 0<br />

n a@ 4 cc .3<br />

.3 2 o c m .3 .4 m<br />

4 m w o mL a<br />

U u m r l 4 ma 4<br />

C m a 4w U<br />

rl 0 4 w 3 a, X<br />

m 0 m O U W 3 m a,<br />

.3 "3 a,& mc,<br />

U rt U c 0<br />

c m C 5 2: W W 0<br />

a, 0 a, -3 -3 EV N<br />

4 ,..I W USV 03 v).<br />

a, U "3 UU C 011<br />

w "4 m a4aJ cm 2<br />

W rl W "4 0<br />

L, a a 0 4 z32 a QJ c<br />

W E W<br />

g 5<br />

v).<br />

W<br />

rt rl rl 44U rlU 4<br />

m " m mw u r l t m<br />

a, a, W a,& a, ad W<br />

a a a a.3 L, mrl<br />

a, a, W a, 4.3 3 s 3<br />

a ffi a a ow OM a<br />

C <br />

0 <br />

,.A <br />

U<br />

0<br />

3 <br />

224<br />

OWL,<br />

mco<br />

03 <br />

w u<br />

o w<br />

-0<br />

c 0-rl h<br />

W a a C<br />

a wm<br />

m<br />

x a,4L<br />

w w ~ m 2<br />

X-4 m mug 0<br />

m c c o m<br />

E 43<br />

43: 3<br />

m<br />

C<br />

0 .3<br />

w 2 230 W<br />

(u - I C 4<br />

a c m m 0<br />

0 ala, c<br />

m 403<br />

s LO ocm rl<br />

0 5 wWs m<br />

W a C<br />

C QJXO 0<br />

m 5 der: m<br />

r l r l a 3 4<br />

rl a,<br />

W W g- a<br />

0 ffl r l 3 m<br />

m m m U 4 rl<br />

.3 a, 3 2 0 m<br />

Z 4 UEY W<br />

U QJE4<br />

4 c a00 3<br />

W H mu3 a<br />

c <br />

+I<br />

0 . . <br />

- N<br />

x<br />

m<br />

U


- 237 -<br />

rl m<br />

rl C<br />

3 .A<br />

uo<br />

c u<br />

a<br />

w<br />

c4<br />

m<br />

mo<br />

EA<br />

rl<br />

44 m a<br />

w a *<br />

C<br />

a .3 m<br />

...w a<br />

a<br />

m<br />

wffl<br />

mm<br />

re -u <br />

I 4<br />

-9 a <br />

4<br />

wul<br />

*+J<br />

ww<br />

m m<br />

ffl <br />

a m<br />

w<br />

L o 4 <br />

G O <br />

22%<br />

U<br />

4 m u m<br />

,c CE<br />

a";<br />

Low<br />

*I:<br />

W c I<br />

fflm<br />

UlWW<br />

mam<br />

aJ<br />

+J*<br />

EUI<br />

fflc<br />

ma!<br />

3 E<br />

C+JQ<br />

4 ffl..4<br />

w a<br />

4 2; 4 3 w<br />

04 I oc4<br />

w m- w 3 u<br />

U<br />

WLn W W UJ ul w w W<br />

mm m m m m m m m m m<br />

I 1 1 I<br />

?... .<br />

. . -... ...<br />

I I 1 I I I<br />

-I<br />

I 1 Ị 1 1 I 1 I I<br />

-... . - ,.- . . ...... .<br />

I I<br />

ffl<br />

U <br />

C<br />

.,3 2<br />

0<br />

m C 0<br />

d<br />

U<br />

m u w<br />

0) w<br />

4 m w<br />

u<br />

x a m ffl<br />

m C E GI<br />

u m d d<br />

X<br />

a eo 4<br />

C 04<br />

m<br />

"d a<br />

+Ja<br />

m m<br />

d<br />

wo 0<br />

VI C4J 0<br />

w f f l In<br />

ffl<br />

E m 40) N<br />

o w ou X v)<br />

wc<br />

m<br />

H 0 . m +J 0<br />

- w c3 4J<br />

U *E 00<br />

4<br />

5 0":<br />

c<br />

ul 0<br />

.- "3<br />

4 d<br />

Ud<br />

:a.<br />

0 ucc<br />

u fflh woo<br />

w "34<br />

rnm<br />

rl mc<br />

m .a.rl<br />

w a<br />

a x 4<br />

m<br />

c<br />

.d<br />

X<br />

m<br />

wo<br />

a cffl<br />

H id<br />

rl<br />

m<br />

w<br />

a<br />

w<br />

a<br />

": N m !n W r- N m<br />

m<br />

a<br />

w<br />

0 <br />

V


- 238 -<br />

0 010 a<br />

rl 4 * ,.3<br />

m<br />

I]" 5<br />

.c 0<br />

uc u<br />

,.3 0 m<br />

3 ,.3 - m<br />

u ca u<br />

ru ow<br />

m<br />

45434 a <br />

a ou 4 <br />

m mw u w<br />

%a 3% <br />

ma m<br />

-'Q c w 4<br />

m<br />

0<br />

a<br />

ua4<br />

wouwo<br />

u<br />

u<br />

3u-i<br />

w .. a<br />

C c a ,"3 m a ma<br />

0 0 4 m m m mcm<br />

3 3 4 u c u 3 u<br />

m 0.3-<br />

5<br />

a 5 0 a<br />

u hm4 4- E a ma<br />

ffl a CI "1. 4 0 d O<br />

C a 4.3 <strong>for</strong>: 04x4<br />

m w msaul. w u mu<br />

LI a au c m c c<br />

h u mw m 3 m 3<br />

'Q'Q m a 5 o a a<br />

10 nln E.3 cu .3miffl<br />

C N > m s 3s 3<br />

m w s.3 4 4 m m<br />

1<br />

m<br />

ouamo 4c4c<br />

I ,.3<br />

w<br />

m o m 0<br />

m 3 mu 4 C d C d<br />

u c m-u c a cl+J*U<br />

m n m m w 4 m 4 m<br />

R I "4ca mrl mrl<br />

m m o m w<br />

w<br />

am am<br />

4 I aEa 3 .3<br />

3 m u - 4 4 0 4 m4 m<br />

3<br />

u<br />

C c l o m m owow<br />

a.3- u a3 wrlwrl<br />

0<br />

a, <br />

w<br />

W Ị<br />

. -<br />

.-.<br />

I<br />

I<br />

W<br />

m<br />

-I .<br />

0<br />

u<br />

u-i<br />

0 a<br />

m<br />

C<br />

0<br />

.ḍ ,<br />

u <br />

a <br />

4 D 3 3<br />

0 .3<br />

w 4<br />

3<br />

a<br />

u m<br />

c m<br />

m m am<br />

4 a -3<br />

ria<br />

m<br />

a . 3 s<br />

3 ma<br />

4 m 4 .3 4 a,<br />

co<br />

a wx<br />

c m<br />

% tu<br />

m m<br />

c an<br />

v <br />

"3 a m<br />

m w 4<br />

a u w<br />

rl "3c<br />

U Eo<br />

x -3 4<br />

w<br />

-+m<br />

a<br />

orl<br />

0 i a<br />

N m w<br />

* +I.<br />

2 u.3m<br />

m ~ c<br />

0 s.30<br />

- u rl ,"..I<br />

(R u<br />

am m<br />

rl 4-4<br />

m .rl o<br />

a, a c a<br />

a "14<br />

w arc0<br />

a auu <br />

. .<br />

N O


~<br />

- 239 -<br />

4<br />

04 m '"i<br />

wow a,<br />

w 4<br />

m<br />

uo<br />

m c m 5 a 001 C U<br />

C a cu<br />

ufflrlww m m "1. ..-I m a ,<br />

uu I fflh w w 41 8 a ; c4<br />

m w m m 4 4 0- 4 m o<br />

4 Lo VI w w a a 3 w m a E 3<br />

u v l m 4 ffl 10 40 W WID m 44<br />

c mr: u 4 aal 4 wm ala<br />

w w rl a 41 ala<br />

Ea a2 2 m m ma - m a<br />

wLl 0 c c c4 +J c - w<br />

E* m w m m l C<br />

Z'<br />

w 5 hod 0 CJ 4 3x 0 l a<br />

4 U w E h I: r: r u3 w 0 2 z::: <br />

u4 uc 4c 4 ua -b<br />

I O 0 c 0, 0 0 % a a 0 10<br />

mw- 33 u u wo 0 w a u - m<br />

cc W 2.J uw<br />

0 or: c w a l u l x xu w 4ffl<br />

5 w u m a w w 5 ala<br />

Ytt2 a a mu u w rl a uc<br />

cw 3 3; a w 4 aa<br />

w o<br />

al u1<br />

Or( w alulwn oal W E m a<br />

w baa ffl ffl4rlP Ur: uo ul4<br />

a fflw c ffl m 4 m m a 5 u m u m a 4<br />

w m m wmwal m w m rl w m w o<br />

451 w 4 w 4 h- Ew m m 4 h 4 W<br />

4 c- 4 m u>Iu ulw .,3a 3u 0 .I<br />

3 m 1 m c c cowo u c mc co a 01<br />

u -.om rlw rl- m m alm 3- b C<br />

cw Er: 55 ffl4 rlrl 03<br />

dm 4 3 u wL'al4wrl 301 4 u .- a m 4 m 4<br />

EaJEwrla 0 m 4 E m<br />

ul'i?@h o303ao rlal 5a- O E 0 3 fflr:<br />

u I w m4 uouo 3 i 4 4 am- w o uoau<br />

m- m c o c c 3 m m 0-4 I 4 c c m<br />

0 rlu 3 >I* haw w a--r uw 3 howw<br />

u 4uu c rl rlcm h C a ~ m a rtnam<br />

0-4 ffl w c c c c I m u ala- I<br />

4u.3 3 3 u m u w 4 - 4 3 3r: - w-4 ow 5Z42'<br />

ow 5 x c 3 > 3 3 0 1 or: 0 u h' x 5 33041<br />

w m n m 3 w 3 ww- a3 E ulP ww 3 alw m-<br />

m o .C x m<br />

Q! .r( alo m u 4<br />

ffl u E.4 u 0 0<br />

a VI m ou W fflw Uh<br />

0 0 0 Ul 4 o m e m C om a0 4<br />

,,3 rl 3<br />

c >I 0 c E 0.,3<br />

n<br />

4<br />

C<br />

u .rl 4 rt .rlm "30 ".IC w u<br />

z w C w 2 m r l m a d u x u 0 !-'"A<br />

14: a m c P 0 rl .,3 x h U uw m at3 4 m<br />

.,3 a 0 3 U..3 u w u w 5 cuu .a0<br />

Lo u 0 rl w c4 4 rl4 Pa 0.3 u fflu a<br />

a rl r: 3 woa w rl m oc "3U c c w<br />

W u rl -4 ffl3 h m 4 m u m a 0.,3a<br />

E4 z m h a 5u a, 2 oc a a c w.3<br />

4<br />

2 5 4 "3 mrt a w 4,3 u u.3auuh<br />

u<br />

U C V I . -4.0 w c c rl .3 .3 5 01)<br />

X C 5 01 0 0 . x c w .3 .3 .3 w .3 al a uuuu w<br />

Lo 4 C m -^ a m ocm w E O E ;; fflYP.34 ffl<br />

2 w 4 a m m u .3 c "3 l c.3alu ma<br />

0 u4auluc<br />

2 2:<br />

w 4.J 0 xw w u m r<br />

4 m C u m u .3 wffl al4u m rl c cco<br />

ffl a 0 m (u QJ U 4 .3 aw.4 b cfflE Crl m m<br />

5 u a ffl uc 4 UCI rloc 3 m . w w m m rl +! a .,A I)<br />

m ..3 0 C ffl aw W u,uffl oal .,3a I] u w u<br />

W w 0 0 55 a 00 a a w w .winma, "31) uc w o a<br />

e 0 m .* E d a ffl4 wo offloow4 +I% Cmi.3 E<br />

w U "3 a C ma wu a, u 4 5 c m m 4 * w .<br />

al 4 I: U C E U mmm mmm u4 04 c ffl"3I:O x ffl<br />

a 3.3 m a c cccu 30 .*Y uuo w c<br />

5 2 a E U rlrl &"".3 ,rlaJ.dCrlrl C P a cm aa-10<br />

w x,rl<br />

U U w >I .A cam m a w w m m 00<br />

C a mrl w 22 w m c cx c E.*..I uc UP m c 3 m u<br />

H w Url "3 aa 0 w alwwauu I U 0 m ou a<br />

ffl 0 u 0 uc 4.a a aomw crl rlrl 4 u<br />

w w P 2: w m .3 al e x xu xrl aa . o m 10 m m vlrl h.3<br />

0 ffl W w m 0 23 a o w alcwwfflfflmc w + w r m 4 u<br />

C . ffl a c m a w m .,A m s m . rl u ac ffl 4 VI<br />

.3 or 44 arl rlui .rtUrl m i r l srlu a LI w m.3 m c<br />

VI w c a<br />

w a0 a o m 4 e m m m m LO m u m a m m um.3 a warm u 3<br />

a x .3 u m 0 0 m w r l w u a l w a l w w w m a E<br />

ffl w u U n<br />

VI w a aaam a'naaaaw am rlE<br />

ffl 0 .,3<br />

rlE xal w w w o w c m c w w w w L - m o . .<br />

U e a 4 I) m 4 m ma aaa ua.36 m a a ha CI "3U.- N<br />

u "3 00 W 4 U<br />

rl U O ffl E aw .* w w<br />

2 ea rr: 4 a4 "3 ram P u a a; wm e m m<br />

w<br />

C<br />

w<br />

CI<br />

m 4 QJ '3 w w 'c1 c . . . . .. . a.<br />

4 m<br />

m<br />

C<br />

x<br />

N


~ ~ ~ ~<br />

uo <br />

Cc,<br />

m <br />

CLI<br />

mo<br />

Ed<br />

44<br />

w a<br />

a <br />

W<br />

.-w<br />

-3<br />

m<br />

mffl<br />

0 Iffl<br />

i -4<br />

a<br />

-ffl<br />

0,<br />

C 43<br />

0 wu<br />

"4 u -4<br />

u w i<br />

,.3 m o<br />

a<br />

z W<br />

m<br />

m 4<br />

4 a0<br />

H<br />

fflw<br />

ffl<br />

W<br />

4m<br />

C<br />

C<br />

m<br />

ffl3<br />

w 4<br />

m<br />

-3 w<br />

w<br />

UZ<br />

u 311<br />

m i m<br />

a<br />

oww<br />

awm<br />

w<br />

> 4 2'<br />

,,.I 04 1<br />

u w m-<br />

U<br />

w<br />

W ww w w W<br />

" " m<br />

w I t I I I<br />

...- - .- r_<br />

1 1 I<br />

...- ... .<br />

I<br />

. I<br />

- 240 ­<br />

m<br />

C <br />

.A<br />

u <br />

m-<br />

w 3 w<br />

0 E X E<br />

ou ow0<br />

C u u<br />

4 cmc .<br />

-0 4Crlffl<br />

w -4 .3 LI<br />

m 4 .-a c m<br />

a w a " 4 w<br />

-I<br />

mi x<br />

I W 1 u m<br />

-0 -CUw<br />

4 l.3C<br />

4.3 c- a4<br />

wa ow<br />

UZF 4 m E 3<br />

w u w w m o<br />

mm url<br />

wa: x<br />

am m 4 w i<br />

w w wc<br />

4s a340<br />

4 4 w w 4 3<br />

aw acmm<br />

crm uw m o w w<br />

m 4 duw!<br />

mc fflwxh;;<br />

mo maia<br />

2 3 w u m<br />

4 w u c<br />

04 ,3aJww<br />

m a i C Q<br />

wuw o m m<br />

4 am a w EW<br />

m l 444<br />

4ur 13 u QJ 3<br />

om1 oca0<br />

w4-w.3: 3<br />

m <br />

w<br />

mrl 0<br />

c3<br />

C<br />

.3 4<br />

u 4<br />

m 3 mo<br />

3 w -3w m<br />

xc 4<br />

0 cm<br />

0 occ<br />

fflu -3.3 0<br />

C .+I LI.3<br />

..<br />

m m w u<br />

0 u . il:m<br />

W 4 0 g mud<br />

. w a .<br />

wua m<br />

I mro 1. rlcm<br />

c I<br />

m i<br />

- m<br />

w 4<br />

4 1 0 4 m<br />

w<br />

u<br />

.<br />

u mw<br />

w 4c 4 m u<br />

w u w 4 xw w u m<br />

w 44 w uuuu cw<br />

m wa<br />

uo m w m.3 m 3% 40<br />

4 m<br />

w c o<br />

W w 3 x 5 u m u<br />

w w w u W E<br />

C mw c w m w m 4 4<br />

4 wm 4 9 w E 3 mo<br />

.n .3 m m<br />

I .-Q I ow "4<br />

m mo ffl m a,.*<br />

m 2' ; m wffl u 4<br />

m o .d<br />

W E' C mw w<br />

ffl m d c m m 4wfflw<br />

E co E ua u ow c u uu u<br />

U c c .3 c .3 cau3<br />

C guy: o m m o w ow mw<br />

,.I i4m.4 s c cn c uo40<br />

01 -3 w a 4u 4<br />

4 4.4- 4 L'wu 4% 4u cu<br />

0 OLIl 0 o w x o w ococ<br />

w w a-w w 4 ww 4 w "3u .4<br />

I ...- .-- -I<br />

..- c<br />

I I I I I<br />

- ..- ..- - I r<br />

W W w w W W W W W W<br />

CO m m m m m m m CU m<br />

1 1 I I<br />

I I<br />

.I<br />

.<br />

-<br />

I Ị<br />

...-<br />

u .-a<br />

w<br />

0 <br />

w<br />

m <br />

4 "3 4 fflrl<br />

. u cc w<br />

w i w u m x<br />

m w om m c W 2 cu ,Q<br />

c 4 ,.rl m m<br />

. Q O i C u 0 mc<br />

ow 4 uu u<br />

w m .4 3 0 4 0 m U E m<br />

-3 C C U C<br />

u w CU c w i 4 C U E<br />

c m u a- w w C"3 mu x u m 0 ..I ,.4 mc<br />

a wffl uw C u a9 am U w w 4<br />

.4 4 4u "3 c 0.4 EU .4 E $ . E x 30<br />

umo w mc m m url 00 i ffl U m u c3<br />

.3 ww w a; I;I<br />

4 m -3 u4 0 rw w C c -3 H O<br />

W i m i rt .3 Q a a eo3 "3 a m<br />

waffl 3 0 w 3 w m a m w o c C w c<br />

4 4 w 4c offl U c '3 uo u .4mm u 0 . c co<br />

u i wx c w cu a uca c ua m m c<br />

4s u c.4 4 .C m a O E a<br />

w w 4 m ,.3 0 0 - u w 4 m E d 0 2 ffla u<br />

03 4 i ,,4 w 41 U 4 ac w wuu u m i c<br />

0 4 0 uw m 09 mo * 0 xu m -3 m<br />

c h w fflw a u..4 c . PI<br />

-<br />

uu c 3u w a w 0, ffla 4<br />

0 4 m wu 3 i offl a 3u c x w u w 3 cn 4<br />

344 3cc + w fflw .4 a u xwc E C m a<br />

u m w c m ,,rl w w u.3 m w m 03 ow u<br />

(40 E m 4 .wo ac i3 ;% 2% 8 r l u 4 u i w<br />

a3 0 w<br />

& m u .A w a C W . 4 w<br />

$44 Emmarlw zz m w m s icffl H O f f l 4 m 0<br />

x m m . O C m r l m E X E a mal 4 4 .A m m c w w c<br />

w.3 4 m u.3 wm.4 o w o wa m o ..i "3 U C 4 W 3 c<br />

U U C 4300 U m 5.4 aw m u u - c 0 u i 0<br />

xwwo w w u w c * x U m u o a .wmu w.3.30u 3<br />

m aa-i ow c 4 a.3 LO m w u3 a c i w m ac m E m i r : a m<br />

u VI mu c . 4 3 w m wuu w a E O wuamoer UaOhE 3<br />

a c eru 3u w c 4 m4au w i<br />

rlrlrlu Zrl wzi2,.2i 2 m C rlu ffl wrlurl wu 4 x u<br />

m m m 3 sui: w m s m m 4 mu w m u c u w m u m > x w r l w x<br />

0 w ww m . r l u 4 w m a w a xw 3 m w a ..+ "-1wa3 cwu01 w<br />

aaaffl CE 404XELLm u.4 E w aw m E3aW4.J H ca:<br />

w w w c w'.rl o a w m ow c 4 c.4 4 wwm -3 .4 0 aJ 3 r l m<br />

aa 4 3 ClumauUa"3 w mcl a awm C l W s 4 E w m 4 u u m<br />

u w i m 0)<br />

32 . . camah a<br />

40. . .<br />

er u- c, c"<br />

m w c 4 c<br />

2a.d-rrm<br />

a,<br />

a<br />

~<br />

U<br />

Lo<br />

w<br />

c . a.<br />

s U u m d U ,I) cn m<br />

E<br />

s


~<br />

- 241 ­<br />

w u<br />

oc<br />

W<br />

fflE<br />

.. w4J<br />

c4 uu<br />

ooc c m<br />

"4w 0 m c<br />

u 4 r l w<br />

m mu m<br />

r l c m a ou<br />

ffl 44 uc<br />

.rl 4 10<br />

mw 3 542<br />

ffl or: m .4 0 a, r(4Jw 3.4 u<br />

rl mrl 4 m<br />

ww .ac<br />

a *a w u w<br />

m cu c m<br />

C a m m w cw<br />

0 4w E-+ 0<br />

.* 4 m uu<br />

u w o uffl4<br />

"4 uuo m.4 m<br />

ffl w c cxw<br />

C m w 4 w w x<br />

m<br />

co<br />

4 a m 4 wmw<br />

E+ WEl. OUC<br />

c 4 a Cil<br />

W D@ l.3<br />

C .4 aa m o c<br />

m f f l w w u<br />

** c h U<br />

ffl ffl w ma m a<br />

w 0 W "3 w w r l<br />

+J<br />

fflufflu >w11<br />

m m a I "4m .4<br />

0 wwfflw ucu<br />

?io00 uwu<br />

0 4ffl4 a, a a<br />

> U+J m u w row<br />

"4 ocwc waw<br />

w -4rl.4<br />

+J<br />

w fflw<br />

U<br />

W W W W W W<br />

w m m m m m<br />

m<br />

W - I I I I<br />

-I<br />

-I<br />

.- .-. .-<br />

I<br />

..- .- ,. . - .<br />

I I I I<br />

C 111 .<br />

om .a<br />

._I ... -4,<br />

* c4<br />

u m m 4 ooc<br />

m 3 w ,4w 0<br />

r l m a u -4<br />

ffl4 g : 0 m mu<br />

0 4 w<br />

cmr: 2 m C" r i c m<br />

+JW ffl .4ri<br />

muffla c -4 ..44 Lo<br />

Grl4Wr: 0 3 *. m w .'4<br />

+J 3cu "4 ffl or: m<br />

"4 w a .rl u ffl4 r t u w<br />

3 ~ 1 4 ~ m 3 w m m mrl<br />

m o 4J rl wm ow<br />

wawr:ffl cw uw a,<br />

m u m w w e "I m C+J<br />

I 4 ffl.4 NI a m m<br />

- w w 3 2 ;$ m - 4a<br />

I url c4 407<br />

r w a w u wo "40 m 0 0<br />

m 4 m m +Jw c uuu<br />

4 I O 23 4J 4 w c<br />

wfflrl-4 wc mu c m a 4<br />

u c m ~ u '4 c-4c co<br />

w 0.4- a E -4 m m .,r(<br />

m . 4 ~ w CUI 3-4 m W E 4<br />

uwam m- w r l w ffl4a<br />

3 ac I c n m w<br />

w n w m - cc 0 w affl<br />

c .rl I w o o r ḷ w<br />

44..w... 22 (Do0 .,ID<br />

m u a m m u I.O aa m<br />

wcwic w m 0. c w w<br />

ou-0 Ulrl -m m 04<br />

wvl a 5<br />

2 ","I mw I me? 4.4<br />

maa w<br />

o 0 C E m c mo wocu<br />

u w 4 C"4.'4rl w H cu r l 4 m c 4 u w c u r l r l I -4 m+J a<br />

.rlwcw.+ m muu fflcmo<br />

I . 43mc, w ffl.3 .4 w 4<br />

4 x u ~ m u u m "4E 4 rlu<br />

o m a w w.co m c x.4 o m m c<br />

wu.3n4uww p1 wrl w ,4ffl "4<br />

... .- .- .<br />

.<br />

W W W W<br />

m m m m<br />

I I I I<br />

I I<br />

- ... - I I<br />

C<br />

ffl<br />

0 w<br />

"4 C<br />

ffl 4J 4<br />

w m N<br />

4 4Jr: m<br />

a4 a a 24 fflu D<br />

u m W m 4 wa m<br />

..Iu .4 0 m 4ffl E a<br />

ac w k E 0 w<br />

cw .3 rl 0 w 4 w .4<br />

wl. u .4 a wo ow<br />

a 4 m<br />

4w ffl 4<br />

xw w k 2 +J fflrl<br />

WE U 4J w u .4 e m<br />

0 w 0 4 W 43<br />

w u w . 0 w W w 50-<br />

oc offl 0 cw 4 4J<br />

"3 w C 04 CJ w 4<br />

C c4 0 C .40 l.0<br />

03 OCI "4 . 0 u x w<br />

"40 4 .4 urn .I m x m 4<br />

Url Url ma, U ~m u oa<br />

m m .A N 4 m "4u wc<br />

w<br />

C 4 .<br />

.A u w w<br />

4 "4 mu W<br />

m 3 m c . C<br />

E -mw 0 m<br />

4JW 0<br />

u u) 4.4 0<br />

C coffl -<br />

m P<br />

r: C .E: Ea2<br />

U m 4Jw w<br />

l. U Orl.(JP<br />

w r: a m-dc<br />

E CI W E aE m<br />

4 w a "4-4<br />

0 m a ffl url .<br />

u W cffl<br />

ffl u 0.4 E c<br />

m. W tnr: 4 0 0 0<br />

C V 4 w4J a44 u<br />

.3c 4 w u<br />

*a 4 wwuv, m<br />

NW NU 4 0 N C m mru 0 +bo w 4<br />

.40 .r( m :,n "4 ::e roo 10 rl w c 4 E O<br />

U W 00 w 4 wffl w c "rlfflwoa<br />

::C l. Or( E- -f+J PIX 4 0 u ffl xu 4<br />

00 04 E w 0 m a m a o . "rl ._I<br />

u w m c o<br />

E "4 E O m c E a -I u 40ffl c4J a. c u a-4 u<br />

m u m 4 C m .cc Lo .4 a c o u wc wxx<br />

m +I 43 u m nrl rl 0 43 40 4<br />

"<br />

w m -m<br />

4u l.c m u 4 c . 3.4 m r v .+ uw<br />

m .rl m o w m offlffl m n u a gg u ac Ea<br />

W r l wu w E w w m o m 0 rlc o m u-iwoc<br />

x.4 x F2 I 4 4 ur: 0110 00 Nu n o m<br />

1 1 1 IC o m F. -39 . 4 w a4 XCJ "3c u-u c<br />

m m . m o m mw m u u w 4 fflwu w r l w ffla 4ffl<br />

Jzm -4 D 0 -4.4 .4 ac rt m~ 04c a<br />

rlwc rlu rlc r i m rlwa url r l m a r l m c .rl E m ou<br />

m 4.4 m a m .rl m c m c c m m a 0 m u 04 3 cr:<br />

w f f l wrl WrO w w w w w a w w u 0-4 Ti 0 3 4u a, ffl<br />

a4 3 a4 a m aa aaa m a aaffl aa u a 00fflE4<br />

woo wo w 4 wx wxx w wc.rl PI m m x rtwwuw<br />

awe aa a m aw a w w 4a a m a LGCJ a w ri x4 ffl c<br />

w m ~1 w w u<br />

c ffl4u b "<br />

. ~ m c c m<br />

11 0 a w w $; a U a 0 u -4"4 a


~ ~<br />

m a c<br />

4 .rl 0 0 a, c m<br />

o a<br />

m ou<br />

,"rl W C 4 a<br />

3 u<br />

4 4 0 3 -3<br />

u m<br />

a ".a 4 ,.A<br />

u m<br />

a4<br />

mu mou e a<br />

OCI<br />

a4a ,.3wm .rl<br />

2l C<br />

w m m 4<br />

a. u C .-0<br />

uwu c m m<br />

rl h:<br />

m mrl<br />

m<br />

-<br />

,2.5.;<br />

ma m<br />

uu<br />

caw 0 C<br />

ou4w u o m<br />

am u4PI .3 a wu<br />

E C<br />

uau m u u 4<br />

5oz rlr:<br />

oca C um<br />

a,<br />

Ucll m u a , m 4 .rl a, m a<br />

rl u . 3 m u .-Iu 0 E ca,<br />

m g i m w m d c 4u u alc<br />

a . w a a n "3 o m<br />

m rlc<br />

0 w 4 a 4c<br />

C ua 0 m o<br />

m oa 'r7 a0<br />

0 .34u w 4 u c ..I m"3 W a u<br />

3<br />

a m um<br />

o CLIU m w m<br />

u (u34 m 4 c rl a3<br />

m c<br />

3 440 auo a04 a 4 "3<br />

m u 0,3 c .3 ,3.3a,ao 0 m 4<br />

C<br />

Iu4 4 w 4<br />

m u s v 4 w ea,<br />

m<br />

x a a,ca<br />

a m u u<br />

O S<br />

4<br />

m a u m<br />

r l m 4 c .3 uw<br />

E+ ualm<br />

umwa,.3 2 u m m<br />

r t c a m ~ l o m 4 a u ,"A UWL<br />

a c 4.3 0 a,*<br />

WWCCffl u<br />

C m44u m au<br />

4 GI m "4.rl<br />

m<br />

. d m 4 m w m<br />

wrl 4 m<br />

W u a arl *- 4 u m a<br />

c m-<br />

c t<br />

m m c<br />

m 4<br />

m 4 u m a u a c w co 8 4 mw<br />

w ow uc m W c al .3uuo.3 rl<br />

11 wmox uou m c "3u rl *UO<br />

I wrlaua r l a o u m m dum <br />

8<br />

m-m .+a a rl c m r l u r l w m<br />

m i w r l m o m o m u m mm h.3 mrl<br />

a, w- m'" 4 a4 ~ ~ 3 m. a 3 w c<br />

3 u mu4urlu L'u4rlm rlaJ h a ,<br />

3<br />

x o o c o c m c owwnw W 4 o o a<br />

u<br />

w u r l 3w,.3 m.3 u m a o r l au w u o<br />

U<br />

a,<br />

W W W W P<br />

m m m m m<br />

w t I I I<br />

.- . .- 7<br />

t<br />

r . -I<br />

. I Ị<br />

a <br />

w<br />

4<br />

4<br />

w<br />

Iu<br />

m <br />

c <br />

m<br />

4<br />

c1 <br />

m <br />

u <br />

w<br />

.rl<br />

m <br />

4<br />

0 <br />

w<br />

u <br />

c <br />

2u <br />

m<br />

w<br />

rl<br />

a 4 w<br />

2 04 0 w u<br />

mw oc 3 rl<br />

m s r l a, W W m m w<br />

wurln t n ~ C c ..eu<br />

rl .3 .3 WuU .da,om<br />

93301 uu 0 4u-Ia<br />

4 c m m u 4 m u<br />

c14.3 uc aauu<br />

4 E W h ma, u u m c<br />

a, "a *-W C uu 4 w<br />

W E C 4 0 C W E<br />

mu a m w om 2 w u<br />

cu ""ut +J m E O U<br />

m m a , c m m rruu m<br />

4 ca m a h m a 00 c<br />

c1wm.o rl .n w m h w<br />

E (Uc) a4 a m C d<br />

mu u c a m m c a, a0<br />

c w m w w m a , m au<br />

3u4aE h 4 u k m<br />

awa, um 0 uaJ 4<br />

a m w w u w a, w ua 0<br />

m o m r l c<br />

OWd.3<br />

xwc ea0 u m a 4<br />

m a m m w 4 2 o a<br />

4w<br />

m 4u m -3 hm3<br />

um C E* m4u C u rlc w<br />

I 0 a a, .3 .3 a+ ma<br />

rl- 4 mw 4ua h m aha, m<br />

m i u 4 ouw ala m a r l E<br />

"3. ma, m 4 8 a<br />

0 4wcw u m rl m 4 m<br />

WO w m o r l 4 u rl m u 4<br />

au c c 3 n m x c m rl crl 0<br />

m w m u m w ma, a GI m w<br />

4 m4 au hum *'h0 4a.3 m<br />

F 0 uLU0 a r o m a wuc<br />

u "3 3 u3aI3uurlri 3 u w m<br />

-3 4 ~ o x m c a r o l m w ~a, a, a4<br />

314 C u W L l O c a a a L ca mu<br />

.<br />

ṭ.<br />

W<br />

m<br />

I<br />

m<br />

m<br />

C<br />

a w 0 c<br />

a, U 3 JJ<br />

3 m u ..i C<br />

.rl rl m 3 .3<br />

4 a 4<br />

m ora w 0 a,<br />

ai2 4<br />

U<br />

0 m 2 m<br />

u W a 0 rl<br />

Eh c U a<br />

C 0.1, m<br />

0 04 0 2<br />

ca, a, N<br />

4 a rl a<br />

0 a 2 c<br />

w 4 4 m m<br />

o a <br />

a 4<br />

ow C 0<br />

u<br />

.3<br />

u a a, w a<br />

4% a -<br />

w<br />

3u -I x W<br />

4<br />

01 s m U U<br />

.3 u C<br />

4 a a, X u<br />

On0 m 4 m .rl<br />

c u . a +a w<br />

r l C h 22 a, 0<br />

CGICI m w w m 4<br />

m e .334 50 4 cu u.<br />

m ua W C W e4 a 0 C h<br />

w 0 w 3 a oa -4 a, aJu<br />

a cu a o u rl mm E C<br />

m w4 ale m m m u w<br />

m "34 moa m u .3 w 3 m b<br />

W (UW W C U m QJ4 in<br />

4a rima a m a, mu 4a W E<br />

r l o O W 4 c4 01 uu a<br />

m ww 4rln un 2 a0 C u m .A m<br />

o a,m hmm r l m .-I 45 -4<br />

.rl m 4 w c m m m w<br />

u c m . d ~ m QE a, aJm x<br />

m m a aou au a a m m<br />

c ea, 0 4 c a,.* a,&<br />

3<br />

LI um zw.3 a 3 2 aa<br />

a,<br />

u <br />

c .<br />

c ( - N m -s m W<br />

4<br />

0 <br />

.3<br />

h 4<br />

w a<br />

m<br />

rl "A cc<br />

ha .3 0<br />

a<br />

.nEi 2 ax<br />

wmw .3m<br />

4 ffl xu<br />

am c m<br />

c m 1 4 .<br />

u m 4 . coc<br />

a um ow0<br />

4 . 0) I 3 .3<br />

u m m m uuu<br />

mu o m.dm<br />

w c a 4a4<br />

X.dW 4 aJw 0,<br />

mmnna c4c<br />

uc3a Qua,<br />

m m<br />

u o mx >1<br />

w c m ww4<br />

"3x "3u 0 .A a,<br />

m m c a3<br />

u.3u c 00<br />

a Ew OErl<br />

c w 4 "3 .r(<br />

m e a m u a m<br />

c uu m e<br />

ow a4 x m o<br />

.iuaao m u<br />

u m i w u-<br />

m u 4 m m<br />

xmmoa! h44<br />

ma,.?wu wva,<br />

. a, "3ww<br />

h m m r l r l m m<br />

4wmwa arc<br />

w . 3 0 r l ~ ~ m<br />

wc4ao .344<br />

m ~ m 4 u (ouu<br />

c<br />

m<br />

4 .<br />

h m ,n<br />

m<br />

h<br />

u <br />

"3<br />

4<br />

0<br />

c<br />

"3<br />

E<br />

w<br />

0 <br />

w<br />

m a <br />

0 <br />

m<br />

u <br />

C<br />

a,<br />

s <br />

a,<br />

4<br />

a <br />

0 <br />

u <br />

a,<br />

rl<br />

a <br />

4 .<br />

m<br />

m u<br />

C<br />

a,a<br />

m o <br />

00 <br />

am<br />

E '3<br />

Ha<br />

J<br />

Q<br />

I


~<br />

- 243 -<br />

m<br />

4 C<br />

m m 0<br />

al aJ 4<br />

rl h 4JUW<br />

a<br />

a am<br />

I. 4 a, C 01 ua, E'<br />

03a 0 x a I<br />

wwc<br />

a, aJm<br />

4 2<br />

..,cm c r c m<br />

w -a .4 WI.0<br />

m mww h mo z<br />

aJ I ~ N a Iwm 0<br />

rl r_. I "4 - c w<br />

a I - C P m I P.4<br />

a: - 1 " u -ma a<br />

-01 c I C aJ<br />

C 4 u- a, I.- .4 "4<br />

0 wow1 a aJ I .A I.<br />

.4 *#I.- a, u- I.<br />

u 4 U W m m<br />

.-I m 4 a J 4 a~ m ou U<br />

m OEaJ VaJ uc<br />

C mrl o u +I m a J m<br />

m c4uw om C hE u<br />

4 -iacm ua ..rlm(u .4<br />

E+ h ."4 hrl aJ a<br />

a m a hu awu m<br />

a c 0 .'4 rl c 503 I.<br />

C wdum ao m m U<br />

m ut- 14E U 4<br />

cah 01 mu cmo a<br />

m a, r l m U aJ aJu aJ<br />

al amac m m ah m<br />

u aJ4Jao aJc m u a<br />

m u c m.4 rl a, U O C C<br />

n (UO u a w c m<br />

aaau<br />

a<br />

41. aoa<br />

0 a14 a aJ m<br />

3<br />

I.uaa<br />

c<br />

3u 4uLl<br />

4.J<br />

,.rl<br />

OaJOaJ mw 003<br />

.A<br />

u<br />

luv3a cm w w a<br />

3<br />

U<br />

aJ<br />

W W W W<br />

W<br />

m<br />

m m<br />

w<br />

I<br />

I<br />

- I<br />

r ,.-<br />

Ị<br />

I<br />

,.<br />

I ,.-<br />

W<br />

X<br />

u u m<br />

m m u u X<br />

u w w m m<br />

mmI. 0 U<br />

aJaJwI. 0<br />

rlu 0 C<br />

w a cw h<br />

0 m<br />

044 .rl m m 4<br />

Q U a,<br />

ua<br />

al<br />

aJrl a "4 e C<br />

c aJzn u m u a,<br />

a, .rl m .A $ w rl aJ .4<br />

Ew Eo a 0 m "4 3 0<br />

h4 W C<br />

mrlua u u m<br />

4 m W rl h a,<br />

aaaa 4 a m C<br />

E 4 aJ 4 0 C rl rl<br />

0 C PI m m<br />

F: .? w : 4 a C<br />

4 hC a a a,<br />

ccu 0 m m u C a<br />

I.LI.4 C aJaJ m aJ 0<br />

0 "4a rlx C 4 <br />

3 3"4aJ am .4 m 3.<br />

0 IC,. c w 44J W C U aaJ<br />

mm cpm m uo 4 0 4 1<br />

u.*u aJ m XI: "4 E OI. 0<br />

m crl m m aJaJ mu m U "4 um<br />

WaJ aJ0 a um<br />

rlEU a m aJ E<br />

m rl 1.c<br />

mu<br />

arlu c I. (Uu 4a 2 4 C<br />

I.,+ m m uc m m 0 ac 0<br />

mu ma, "4 h aJ. W 3 4 0 "4<br />

muoh a uu om 4 4 J C .4 .rl .A m<br />

c m aJ4 x m 4 . w a a c -4 X mu "4<br />

uc .4cau m aJa 40 m W U 3<br />

ha0 $0 E x E W 0<br />

aJ ow w<br />

u Cc, w alrl 4<br />

uc 4aJ 4 u u rl aJc .,4 rl Url e,<br />

m.45 4u ml: u 4 m 4 m mo<br />

rl uam art rl aJu eo aJ aJ rlu<br />

axmuu<br />

m<br />

Ewrl a0 m "4 2 a a C<br />

m m m c m .* 0 w u '4 a u .4 ai WW .4<br />

au44 al mmu a m w m rl Lo a: a0 .I.<br />

m 4<br />

C<br />

aJ<br />

a a; 2 . . w m e Lll ; 4 U U m au aa, w m<br />

m<br />

u<br />

C rl 0<br />

a m C<br />

C 2 C "4<br />

m u 0 rl<br />

m .4 0<br />

h a l u 0<br />

rl ~ r l m<br />

04 c m u a<br />

30) rima e<br />

0a wars m<br />

Erl .I. rl IU 3<br />

ala, m<br />

I. ma a a a<br />

w ac al w aJ<br />

oc I.aJ a a<br />

.. ..<br />

. e<br />

.<br />

N<br />

m


~<br />

I 245<br />

-<br />

m \\ m\m m-r m I -rrlrl -r P-r<br />

0 m " rlNP NN m I - r m ~m mm<br />

m 0 m VI mN<br />

m I I I. u: ",?<br />

I m l <br />

rl N d m W<br />

m I m<br />

3<br />

..<br />

I<br />

~<br />

I<br />

P \\<br />

m m NN<br />

m<br />

m 3.<br />

rl<br />

m<br />

d <br />

d<br />

ml<br />

4 ..<br />

I<br />

m<br />

01<br />

H m<br />

0<br />

rl<br />

-I<br />

P<br />

G m<br />

u rl 10<br />

m 0<br />

d<br />

d<br />

I<br />

I<br />

\\<br />

NN<br />

.. . ... c -r rl-rm VIN 3. W "N<br />

. I<br />

ulmmmm mi\o-r.v) m m ~ m VI VIVId<br />

mrl-r rl m mwom mrl rl m -r!nm<br />

mm<br />

m~ N rlrl rl rl VI ID<br />

N m<br />

N 0 do<br />

W<br />

C, rlr.<br />

m I I o 1<br />

m<br />

m<br />

m<br />

0<br />

<br />

u <br />

u, \\<br />

m "<br />

% u,<br />

m<br />

rl<br />

-2<br />

I<br />

E2<br />

Ov) -r \\<br />

W W N "<br />

W 2 ,<br />

an<br />

m<br />

m<br />

rl<br />

m<br />

I<br />

~~.. .a . V .....<br />

.a . ..C . mu.<br />

.a*. xn . . @ m .<br />

.. X . .cm. . m u .<br />

.. ...<br />

. Orl . m . Ud.<br />

- ..<br />

I)<br />

. cm. .F ...A . .U V V . ..d .<br />

. hY. .3..<br />

0" .A". ...<br />

m . 4E.. U ..a, .U ..d<br />

. .5 .5 . .<br />

u.l 0<br />

5 C <br />

V<br />

U<br />

m <br />

m<br />

0 <br />

U<br />

8<br />

. d5.<br />

. . Val.<br />

*.-I<br />

I IP-ru, P*\l I I IO** 0 40<br />

I 1 m VI m i I I im m c) Pm<br />

3rl m I C I<br />

m<br />

............... ..... ..-. . m ..c- . .u .U . O U .CO ..d m ...d.d . .00 .E ...<br />

.U5<br />

.....<br />

.drl ..d<br />

*I ..ma . m . .UW .rl<br />

111 . . m 4 tu .. .. .U a ..cu .au>;c ..d 4 .TiEAlOU.<br />

.W . . U ::&ut .... .m04.rl.rt . V . . . c..<br />

.'UUVUE.<br />

2,<br />

. : :g03:;: . cm1.i.<br />

. V . . U .VU.d .a. . .an.. .w.dond.<br />

-A . . old ."..I.. .r Y.2 . . <br />

.v .. d.. .L)a:.i .d.. <br />

.cam m ..I ...c-n . m .. ..dN 40 ...<br />

.mu@c n .. . V m .3. . mw-vc..d u m u m m . . . ~ c m . o . . ma VOU. .am,*rlhm .%m+,o.rl -4.. x n m u u ~ .<br />

. m 5 2 a4.d .m v 0.dm .rl .. m.d c m n ...<br />

.C u m 5 .avrlu .a,.<br />

..~)'ov~u.<br />

. u~o..+v.~(...<br />

~ m m m. u r n . ....<br />

m<br />

459-370 0 - 84 - 10


~ ~ ~<br />

~~<br />

- 246<br />

Wrl DO w w o mt W* e* m m mrl<br />

3 W m mm N p.w rl N r l Nm<br />

t.rl ri mN<br />

n .<br />

-2'" .. L<br />

4 rl rl Nrl N<br />

..<br />

*U WZ mw wrl I',p.N<br />

n %S mm<br />

mm I mmw<br />

I) Wm WW<br />

n <br />

'or(. 2-2 . .<br />

4 rl Nrl rl N <br />

m<br />

m<br />

O<br />

* mm mw o mrl mr e* e* Wm m a<br />

P *N p.N N VlV) rl p.0 W O<br />

tnm<br />

m n <br />

m<br />

U ..<br />

4 P wọ rl ".rt . .<br />

U 4 ri (-4 rl r( N <br />

* <br />

4<br />

.. <br />

rlp. *U -A* mm 1 Nrl<br />

r- mm NLII I WO<br />

m 111 m em<br />

2" .<br />

m <br />

rl


- 247 -<br />

.. Y<br />

m I U )<br />

0 w I N<br />

m m<br />

m<br />

3 m r - 0<br />

VI<br />

..<br />

VI<br />

I<br />

I W<br />

m 1 - S<br />

m 2<br />

rl<br />

m<br />

-S<br />

I<br />

..<br />

o o O<br />

V I N I m<br />

- 0 1 VI<br />

m . .,<br />

rl w r - c m<br />

..<br />

I<br />

m I r­<br />

r- o w I P<br />

m<br />

m<br />

0)<br />

e.1. ....<br />

.U X .rl.<br />

m .u .m . m .<br />

. w .u .u .<br />

0. . .O.<br />

u .al .".U.<br />

.u . C .n a, .m<br />

u . U :%:$: .E.<br />

E:al O . .u . u . w .<br />

~ 1 a l . m . .a.<br />

alu .LI .m .u .<br />

u m<br />

I<br />

m. . m .<br />

rl Inn 0)<br />

m<br />

N<br />

I I<br />

..<br />

m m I O<br />

W * N I N<br />

m U) 0)<br />

m . ? .<br />

rl Nrl 0<br />

rl<br />

I<br />

d<br />

I<br />

.. * a .<br />

. . .a. .LI. .a. .u . . .<br />

n <br />

-0. . .<br />

m u :ij:.2 :E:<br />

a .5,<br />

a.o .., .<br />

X .<br />

xu .u .O m .<br />

mo. .&.u.<br />

b U . 5 . . .<br />

.al .rl .aJ.<br />

$5 :% :g :% *<br />

m~oamoaluG<br />

u.rluau u ou<br />

xm m m u m a m<br />

84 nluLIu<br />

&,""" E8a<br />

UaJUrlurtU LI<br />

oomomoalo<br />

0) 1u alualu ou<br />

ua !a E ;<br />

S 2 a " a z<br />

2 <br />

m<br />

...... I. v:<br />

U)<br />

mu) NVI wo I mul FP m 8 8 P<br />

PO PU) om I Prl P W rl m<br />

mm mo NW rlN NP<br />

U)r( Nm Wrt U) m<br />

I rtw 0 I I<br />

I om -40 0<br />

I rlo om 0<br />

mop. m~<br />

....<br />

m<br />

NU) -0<br />

3 1 P<br />

I<br />

I-N mm 00 LllN 10 ** rl<br />

I r-m mo -~omm 0 W<br />

- ~ mm a<br />

W rlm mo m<br />

I I 1 U) I<br />

:9 .... 0.<br />

I mN I mm o ** VI<br />

I I I mw I I om W m<br />

NO) 0-.. op. rl<br />

I. l<br />

VI PU) N<br />

m<br />

I<br />

.. .I<br />

I rlN I wm 0 *I o<br />

I I I mw I I om rl I W<br />

1 0 ctm I 0.<br />

m NU) 3<br />

I rl I<br />

... . ... ...<br />

1 .<br />

* u. 4. . w E . .al ..I. .c rl. .*( 3: ... ..<br />

. w . w <br />

.a .I) .*( . :<br />

CI. . . w <br />

. ..m<br />

...... ..<br />

.aJ .A .... 4. ...D .<br />

m . ..<br />

.n<br />

.. ...<br />

.m .^ z : ::& :<br />

.*I 0-. . . O .'Ct .u a. ..w<br />

.al .PI m . ..*I .<br />

.u ." ...<br />

.to ... ... a,: ::.$ : <br />

C -1 .":. ..... N . 0 . ..n .u .w ....<br />

1..5<br />

m. .m<br />

1..<br />

3. .C<br />

0. .O<br />

x ..*<br />

al .JJ<br />

. . m .. 1


- 248 -<br />

I l l o m m t NC c r- *VI<br />

I 1 0 1 N N o~ c ~ r tl<br />

m m w <br />

rl 0 m mm <br />

I imi m<br />

I imi<br />

w.<br />

I <br />

I lrll '-4 rl <br />

1 1 1 <br />

1 1 1 <br />

I l l <br />

I I ..I <br />

I l l <br />

1 1 1 <br />

I IC1 N O L O Pv) Q r l r l W N m<br />

I imi<br />

,.(<br />

I t m i<br />

I<br />

I 1 4 1 N N N<br />

I l l<br />

I l l<br />

- mv)*<br />

I l l o c m N c rl* o c *o u1 mo* <br />

I I ~ NI<br />

N U I m w rlrl "de<br />

I i m i<br />

m tn o. mm<br />

I 1 0 1 1<br />

NU:<br />

I 1 4 1 N 4 <br />

I l l <br />

1 1 1 <br />

i m i I <br />

I U I ..I<br />

i m i I <br />

1 0 1 I <br />

O Q u1 0 rl* W W Lrl W NrlC<br />

GI"ImI ~ m ; l m w e.4 r­<br />

cirlimi<br />

N<br />

0 1 mimi "u: I<br />

m % ::<br />

,..+IV l r l l N rl rl <br />

r l i m i I <br />

rll*ll I <br />

..iIf',I I<br />

E l 1 - 1<br />

MI I I<br />

- 1 I I<br />

0.<br />

N<br />

1 1 1 o o m m VI * x m v) r m m r-me<br />

rl. m I<br />

.<br />

I l l<br />

I I ..I<br />

I l l<br />

1 1 1<br />

1 1 1 m -, N o o L I m *N m ~ r l i<br />

I 1 1 0 1 N l t V I N I m rl w o wmi<br />

i m i r-<br />

I I ~ I<br />

NO.<br />

I I d 1<br />

d rl<br />

1 1 1<br />

1 1 1<br />

I l l<br />

I l l<br />

I<br />

: ...... 1 I<br />

I I I I I I .<br />

I I . .<br />

.CI<br />

I<br />

.a.c<br />

I I<br />

I<br />

I<br />

.E.@<br />

I .m .E<br />

I I .*.a<br />

I I . .a.u <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I I <br />

I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

1 I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I I<br />

I 0.<br />

W<br />

i ~ mm w e rlrl<br />

wm m p.0 mm<br />

2: 99<br />

e m<br />

I<br />

mm<br />

m<br />

om c rlv) mm<br />

t m N vlrl rtw<br />

ym, w r ( ~2:<br />

t m v)m<br />

N<br />

I<br />

..<br />

W<br />

E<br />

. O .m . m..<br />

.*I .u .ai..<br />

0 ..a .al<br />

.C..<br />

h <br />

.1 .C ."4..<br />

.rl .C( . . m<br />

. ..<br />

. v .urn. ., . *<br />

$ ::l:bd::"::<br />

... m . ' o . .<br />

'ow. .'o .'ob. .u..<br />

um. .c .m . . m . .<br />

m r l d a mrlu alrl .3rl .<br />

3dmm'om~4umalomal<br />

om acl4 a em ,CIS SCI<br />

m u'o m 2'o.d u'o m 1) m<br />

rl U .4.4rl "4" k4 54<br />

.4 U.4 011 a.rl.4<br />

I<br />

N<br />

I<br />

wm t mm mu,<br />

NP. o WN mu)<br />

LDW NN m t<br />

..<br />

40 NO<br />

N<br />

I<br />

N<br />

I<br />

rl mN Ylrl<br />

m o m mm rlc<br />

v) WN NUI<br />

rlm.<br />

m 2s<br />

I<br />

I<br />

f I a; P.0 w*<br />

rl<br />

*N Y I N<br />

rlrl mrl<br />

... .m ." .,i....<br />

............ ....<br />

.m. .C .C(<br />

.. .U c ...m ......<br />

0 .a .rl .4 .. * . m . .<br />

%! :: :K ::%::<br />

N ... .d..<br />

-4 ...c . .n<br />

.. ..<br />

c <br />

. m ..s..<br />

gl :: ::O::<br />

u ...<br />

0 <br />

:5 .....<br />

.al ..E..<br />

.u ..0..<br />

m <br />

.O ..4..<br />

la .. .E ..C(..<br />

3 <br />

. m . .<br />

:: :a ..N..<br />

*I<br />

a 1 1<br />

m <br />

.*l<br />

...4...<br />

E:.<br />

1 <br />

. m . .<br />

p9<br />

.3 .m..<br />

w 0 <br />

.a . U..<br />

.a ..0..<br />

.. ."#-I ...<br />

.. C .C . .a . .<br />

CI R'o c.4 >&a 3rl E2 2 g,<br />

.r( 05 urturl o'o urlv u<br />

4'0 c o m c m u c o m co<br />

m*Iuumu uuuuu<br />

z.2 L? 2% 2m <br />

a~ a <br />

al<br />

z <br />

z<br />

d


~~<br />

- 249 -<br />

NC m- 1"O om of. 10<br />

Cln om mom 01 WN r l ~<br />

Ṇ W N IN" 1-<br />

.. 0-..<br />

I .-I<br />

I 1<br />

rl Nln rlrl -1<br />

rl<br />

rl<br />

mrl<br />

OC<br />

"'=<br />

rl 0<br />

rl<br />

rlo mm<br />

Wrl VN<br />

I" OP<br />

I .I<br />

rlo<br />

wm<br />

II<br />

- 0<br />

rl<br />

Wrl OO mom W­<br />

rlrl om W W N NO<br />

erḷ<br />

rlm I N CI<br />

I<br />

N- N-<br />

Y) rlrl<br />

rl<br />

oo).<br />

PO Vlrlm 011<br />

W- 11Y)rl 00<br />

lrlN mm<br />

I<br />

N<br />

I I -0 In<br />

I 1 mW IN *<br />

I<br />

Wln<br />

m<br />

WI­<br />

P<br />

.... ..<br />

.... .$:: :: ..<br />

".I.. u.. .. 3:: :: ..<br />

....... . ..In.. ..<br />

..<br />

<br />

.I ..<br />

....<br />

...... ....<br />

..m c<br />

.. . m . . m . m. .m.. .u. .C. .....<br />

.c . m. . m . .O<br />

.o . .a.<br />

...<br />

..4 .ai..<br />

. . . U . . X . .u<br />

.m.. . . m . . m .E::<br />

.O<br />

.u..m.. ..u ."..<br />

.e. .C..U..O .C..<br />

.a. ....I. C. .rl ..,.I. .<br />

.m. .rl. . m . .a ...<br />

. m . .rl. .I).X .u<br />

."::<br />

.rl<br />

... .<br />

. m . .<br />

.u..<br />

...<br />

.W . .<br />

. O . .<br />

...<br />

.. al m...<br />

u...<br />

.o..<br />

m ... .*..


0 <br />

m <br />

m <br />

4<br />

m <br />

m <br />

m <br />

rl<br />

.I <br />

- 250 -<br />

ON V I O O N W W m v1 m *<br />

mu) P mm m 0 u)N m u)<br />

m rl m<br />

c, 2: .<br />

rl -re rl m N<br />

I<br />

. ... . .<br />

.-I<br />

PP W P W m m (3<br />

N 1 -mi-- m r l m<br />

O N N<br />

N rl -?- rl 0<br />

I<br />

I <br />

~<br />

m <br />

rl<br />

.. <br />

P<br />

m <br />

rl<br />

.. <br />

W<br />

m <br />

rl<br />

.. <br />

u)m P-rl P N W m - S - 3 0 P U<br />

N-? Ot-m m oe m 0 m N<br />

WWrl W mo N P W.<br />

.- 1 ...<br />

N W 4 mu) m<br />

I l l o u ) ~ ~ e P m - 0 m m m r l *<br />

1 1 1 u) W N rl u) O N P m o N u)<br />

I .<br />

.. c, ?r*<br />

W m m ọ rlrl m .<br />

NP rl vu) m m<br />

I<br />

m rlm rl m u ) r l<br />

..<br />

m. 2<br />

PN w m o o m m rN Nl<br />

O m ~ W W *<br />

N I l l m rlm N P rl m<br />

rl-i 3 rl<br />

I <br />

.. ... . .<br />

... . . . . . m . . . <br />

.. ..- N .<br />

.<br />

.. ..rl . .o<br />

. <br />

.e .C. .U<br />

. , .<br />

.o .d .a. .e .<br />

.U .'O<br />

... . . ."<br />

.E.. .O<br />

.O ..A . .E<br />

... . .<br />

1..<br />

.3 .o. .U .m<br />

.'p ... .? .w .w. ..Y<br />

... .... . .m . . .<br />

.<br />

U ...<br />

0 ...<br />

u<br />

...... ..<br />

..<br />

..


- 251 -<br />

~ ~<br />

.<br />

0 <br />

01<br />

m <br />

rl<br />

..<br />

cn <br />

m <br />

cn<br />

rl rlrl rlrl<br />

m" ..<br />

m<br />

al<br />

* *rl<br />

m w<br />

-i m t - m<br />

m cn ., .<br />

u rl rlul<br />

a <br />

.I<br />

4<br />

..<br />

.<br />

rl<br />

rl<br />

Nu) mm c * ** mm c<br />

rlN rl W N<br />

Nd<br />

o w<br />

-N<br />

-0 * ** dN<br />

ON m*<br />

Nrl<br />

Nrl<br />

t-W WO 8 * ** r.0 wm L<br />

m,i rl 40 t-m<br />

44 Nrl mm<br />

rl<br />

P<br />

m<br />

cn <br />

rl<br />

cnm o m~<br />

m o e m mls<br />

LOm<br />

rl<br />

rl wp<br />

rl<br />

rlw mu) c * ** NU)<br />

wm<br />

mw *e ** c<br />

W N W N mrl<br />

m u )<br />

W rid<br />

m w c n<br />

cn <br />

3 rl<br />

.. . .<br />

Y : :<br />

2 . .<br />

j. .<br />

i :.. :<br />

......<br />

..al.. ..m..<br />

...<br />

. m . Lil ..".. j ..cl.. c . ..* ....<br />

al ..si.. E v r . U . . u m m . . m c . . ....<br />

00...0.. zs.*c*- e . 0 . . . *<br />

Hal. .n. .....<br />

me irl c * ** eo) 0.s<br />

mm mcn m*<br />

NN<br />

NN<br />

* * .... ....<br />

.E..<br />

. m . .o..<br />

.a. ..,*..<br />

.u. .u .. . .<br />

...<br />

*<br />

.O. . m . .<br />

.n. . . . s..<br />

. m . .<br />

...<br />

.a .5<br />

.5. .C. .u .<br />

.u..<br />

. O .<br />

.C<br />

.c . m<br />

5<br />

. O . c . . m . . m . .w . .<br />

.a!.<br />

m<br />

.rl .m .a. .al..<br />

.." . O .rl .a. .U..<br />

m . . O<br />

. : : G :::<br />

. 2 .al<br />

.U .al .c.<br />

. wm<br />

.....<br />

. O .<br />

.u .m<br />

al .u c .a. .u. .C 5 :@: .%. .. .a.al<br />

~<br />

.O .rl<br />

.E<br />

.O .m<br />

..*<br />

.u u . a. . .u<br />

.u .c<br />

. . v i<br />

.O<br />

:C ..* . .N<br />

.u<br />

.'o .o .5. .Ja<br />

.d . m<br />

..*<br />

. O .m<br />

.a. .a<br />

.u .". .C .E<br />

.a<br />

.a . u . . <br />

.rl ..... .a.<br />

.*..c<br />

.O. .o a .w<br />

:&<br />

. m .O<br />

m<br />

.rl .<br />

. .a,.<br />

u. .rl . m<br />

..* 4.. .c<br />

..u<br />

.... m . 0 . .C .a<br />

.Pi<br />

.w<br />

r O <br />

.C..N<br />

.O . ..,d<br />

.-*..u<br />

.u. .U . m . .O .<br />

:.: : : % :<br />

.u . .<br />

.U. .5..<br />

. O . . C . .<br />

:%:<br />

. : m : :<br />

. w . .<br />

.C. .C..<br />

.u . .*I..<br />

.C3 .mrl.<br />

alomalcmal<br />

u E au a~ au<br />

m v m w u m<br />

u .s.rl" x .,*u<br />

tLm.5gal.?I&<br />

"rim urlv u<br />

o m c o m c o<br />

UaJHUrlUU<br />

3:: <br />

a<br />

a <br />

VI<br />

a. . W . U <br />

u .u ala.<br />

.a .UC.<br />

x .Id . 0 .<br />

.am. .u .ua.<br />

m u .al .oa.<br />

al . . U .wo.<br />

..4c..a. u .<br />

vo. .al.a<br />

I*. .5 .alu..<br />

.dC.<br />

"...rl.u .<br />

mu..<br />

a m . .u .sa.<br />

au. .o . Y O .<br />

V1.M. .w. u .<br />

4.. .rim.<br />

u.rlrl .m .m.rl<br />

.rln mal 0 al.*m 6<br />

w m a u r l u u u<br />

.rl~vm a m a15 m<br />

u @Ti u LI u aal "<br />

g'.5 &C &";rl x,<br />

VIdV u 0 L4rl-I u<br />

m E ou o mrl o<br />

u a l ~ u . c u a l m u<br />

@a m ai<br />

.rl al tr<br />

52 + a<br />

0


~~ ~~ ~<br />

- 252 -<br />

* W 0 0 0 o w m *<br />

3 N 0 9 m r l N O 0<br />

v) N 9<br />

.<br />

r(<br />

n -! '", I I<br />

-4 N m rl LO<br />

..<br />

m - 4 N m 0 0 0 o m rl c<br />

n Ptn m c t- m o NO) m<br />

D Ṇ<br />

c," . " N rḷ m rl<br />

n<br />

I<br />

-I rl 4.4 d N m rl -4<br />

I I<br />

..<br />

w m rl 0 0 0 0 0 0 m *<br />

D IY " 0 m 0 m o ~m Lo<br />

I) m<br />

. . .<br />

-4 rl<br />

n -!<br />

0.. . I<br />

-I rl rl rl LV N rl *<br />

I I<br />

..<br />

o t.01 mm t n m " 0 0 0 0 0 0 Lo *<br />

0 rl 4 0 N-4 -4<br />

mm m. e d In m 9 4<br />

N.<br />

15 9 N W rlm m * m<br />

m<br />

I-! .<br />

D) I<br />

rl rl- rl N N m<br />

I<br />

..<br />

9 or- om m o m 0 0 0 0 m I<br />

1D N rlC t-9 0 0 0 0 N r l m 0 I<br />

ltn m w m c cn rl N <br />

m 9<br />

I I <br />

rl <br />

.. C <br />

.c .<br />

0 :E . . .O<br />

. .<br />

.* .O X . <br />

51 ..I m a .m .X .<br />

.u .U. .51<br />

Y .m . . .C :3 :~ :>, ::<br />

U .0 .u. .al<br />

.C<br />

.U .a U u .o .*<br />

.I<br />

.rl :E: :5 .O *I .v C ... v .rl .O .u . m .w 0 . C . 3<br />

al .m .U .rl .a<br />

.u<br />

, .... .<br />

u . O . U . .a<br />

.bo.<br />

. .a .-n ..* .UU . .<br />

..rl 0 .v .a .v<br />

d *&I.. .C .a .U .m .v<br />

m . m . x .m .U .U. .PI<br />

U .u .. m . .c. .m ." .* . C . . . . u .a .m .o . m a.O .<br />

.a.. .^. .E .U .w.<br />

9 .E.. .e. c .o .P .m .m<br />

. V .4.. .al. 0l.U .3.a<br />

.".. .rl . -rl .C .m .al.. .a. al .-I :S :c .m 2 .a.. . Y . Y . .rl .u . O 4 . X . m . . 0 .w .= ..* .d . .<br />

.o.. U .I:. w .o<br />

2 ... al .a.<br />

E .v . . u ..* .<br />

C . rl .U.<br />

Y . m . .<br />

... 2 .O.. .U. .....<br />

4 .U * .d..<br />

U . m . . m . .<br />

.a.<br />

8<br />

.*..<br />

.m. .o..<br />

.a. .u..<br />

w .U. .P..<br />

0 . ..a..<br />

.u. .m..<br />

C 0 . . ..<br />

0 .w.. L . .<br />

.* . ..m..<br />

m .url .ad.<br />

a 04 m al.4 m al<br />

rl uv sua au<br />

m aa m.*v m<br />

: u u-rl u m..* u<br />

al<br />

&O.2 23.2 &<br />

d U>,VUUVU<br />

maowco co<br />

a CV.*HV UUV<br />

al<br />

aa v<br />

sru 2<br />

c<br />

8 <br />

.<br />

I


~<br />

253 -<br />

8 I * m "8 8 ""<br />

0 I IO) rl m-rl<br />

m I m<br />

m<br />

0-4 <br />

..<br />

8 I Qd " C * (DONCU<br />

m I NN rl NQrl<br />

I d m<br />

m<br />

I<br />

rl<br />

..<br />

* I (Dm<br />

I Nrl<br />

m<br />

Id<br />

0) I<br />

rl<br />

..<br />

8 I N W mmU 8 mQNm<br />

P I NO rl rlmrl<br />

Id<br />

m<br />

m<br />

I<br />

rl<br />

..<br />

I Cm mm* 8<br />

(D I IO rl<br />

N<br />

m<br />

d<br />

.. ..<br />

........ .I<br />

. 0 . . .m.. .u.. .m.. .. .C .I><br />

........ . C . . . O . . . . ."A ..<br />

.... ."....<br />

.+I.... . 0 . . .,-I..<br />

... .,-I..<br />

0 . .. 0 . . .<br />

u. m . ..<br />

. v . . u. . . ul. .u. 0 . .o. .. ..<br />

<br />

....<br />

......


....<br />

SZZZZ<br />

WP I o m<br />

p-8 mm<br />

m-8 I<br />

I<br />

-<br />

254 -'<br />

mrlwmm <br />

OIONO<br />

Nmrlrlm <br />

..I I.<br />

mm<br />

NN<br />

I<br />

m<br />

.a.<br />

um tu<br />

00 c<br />

0<br />

.......<br />

m.....<br />

ti::::: ..<br />

..... A . . . . .<br />

al.....<br />

u . . . . .<br />

al.....<br />

e;.....<br />

2:: ...<br />

" 2 . V .<br />

...<br />

i<br />

0 <br />

3<br />

.....<br />

.....<br />

...<br />

... . .L)<br />

... .W<br />

...<br />

1 . .<br />

1 . .<br />

w . ..A<br />

L). .m<br />

a*.<br />

.r(rl .a<br />

almalc<br />

uaum<br />

ala m<br />

e;,4 Y al<br />

i<br />

3.5 8.;.<br />

e<br />

m a uu 3<br />

lacom<br />

H U W<br />

a <br />

W<br />

i ..<br />

0<br />

a: m<br />

$4<br />

P, a, al<br />

U U<br />

\\, \\ 0 0<br />

XrlNm -8- z z


- 255 -<br />

APP~IXc<br />

The attached tables summarize some highlights of the tax systems<br />

of several major U.S. trading partners. <br />

The tables should be read with caution, as many of the features<br />

which determine the impact or burden of a tax cannot be accurately<br />

presented in such a summary <strong>for</strong>m. For example, it requires a great<br />

deal of in<strong>for</strong>mation to define the base of an income tax; but without<br />

doing so, little can be learned from a comparison of tax rates. Even<br />

if one could measure the base <strong>and</strong> rate <strong>for</strong> a selected pattern of income<br />

ant3 deductions, it is difficult to select income levels which<br />

represent comparable living st<strong>and</strong>ards in different countries <strong>and</strong> lines<br />

of activity.<br />

For such reasons, the tables select certain aspects of <strong>for</strong>eign tax <br />

systems which can be more easily compared in a summary fashion, seek­<br />

ing to minimize both complex qualifications <strong>and</strong> inaccuracy. The <strong>for</strong>­<br />

eign countries included in the comparison are France, Germany, the <br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Sweden, the United Kingdom, Japan <strong>and</strong> Canada. <br />

Level <strong>and</strong> Composition of <strong>Tax</strong>es <br />

Part I of the table illustrates the share of tax revenues in total <br />

domestic production in the respective countries <strong>and</strong> the extent to <br />

which each country relies on different types of taxes. <br />

The figures shown include taxes imposed at all levels of government.<br />

Part I shows that the share of tax revenues in domestic<br />

production varies substantially among the countries compared. Japan<br />

<strong>and</strong> the United States are at the lower end of the scale with ratios of<br />

27 <strong>and</strong> 30 percent, respectively. In Canada, Germany, <strong>and</strong> the United<br />

Kingdom, the ratios fall between 35 <strong>and</strong> 40 percent. And in France,<br />

the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> Sweden the ratios are roughly 45 to 50 percent.<br />

The composition of tax revenues varies even more markedly. Japan,<br />

with the lowest ratio of taxes to output, relies more heavily than any<br />

of the other countries on the corporate income tax as a source of tax<br />

revenues. Corporate income taxes account <strong>for</strong> 20 percent of total tax<br />

revenues in Japan, compared to only 3 percent in Sweden, which has the<br />

highest ratio of taxes to output. Total income taxes (not including<br />

social security taxes) account <strong>for</strong> about 45 percent of tax revenues in<br />

the United States, Japan, Canada, <strong>and</strong> Sweden; but except in Japan, 36<br />

to 40 percent of the total are individual income taxes with corporate<br />

income taxes contributing only 3 to 8 percent.<br />

France relies relatively little on income taxation. Social security<br />

taxes <strong>and</strong> sales taxes account <strong>for</strong> more than 75 percent of total


- 256 -<br />

French tax revenues. Social security taxes are also particularly high<br />

in Germany <strong>and</strong> the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. <br />

Sales taxes are more important in all of the other countries than<br />

in the United States or Japan. However, even if sales taxes were ignored,<br />

only in Canada would the tax/output ratio fall below that in<br />

the United States; the other countries which have higher ratios than<br />

the United States would continue to do so. This suggests that sales<br />

taxes are often an additional source of revenue rather than a<br />

substitute <strong>for</strong> other taxes.<br />

Individual Income <strong>Tax</strong>es <br />

Part I1 summarizes some features of individual income taxes. <br />

Unlike Part I, it describes only national level taxes. Part I1 shows <br />

that the marginal rates of individual income tax in the United States <br />

are relatively low under current law <strong>and</strong> the top rate will be even <br />

lower under avproposed broad-based income tax. Recognizing that <br />

nominal rates of tax can present a misleading picture, section B in­<br />

dicates the average tax rate of a "typical" taxpayer in each of the <br />

countries, based on 1982 data. The typical taxpayer is defined as the <br />

taxpayer with the median income level <strong>for</strong> that country at that time. <br />

The U.S. tax burden ranks 4th in the group of seven countries, with an <br />

average tax rate that is higher than that in three of the other <br />

countries, but lower than that in the other four. <br />

Five of the seven <strong>for</strong>eign countries surveyed provide some infla­<br />

tion adjustment <strong>for</strong> the tax threshold <strong>and</strong> bracket rates in the <br />

personal income tax. Beginning in 1985, the United States will be in <br />

line with that practice as well. <br />

Corporate Income <strong>Tax</strong> <br />

As shown in Part 111, five of the seven countries provide tax<br />

relief <strong>for</strong> dividends paid from income that is subject to tax at the<br />

corporate level. The proposed U.S. system will also bring our<br />

practice into line with other countries on this point.<br />

Part 111 also summarizes corporate tax rates at the national level <br />

<strong>and</strong> provisions <strong>for</strong> capital cost recovery. The proposed reduction in <br />

the U.S. corporate tax rate will bring that rate below that in any of <br />

the other seven countries. (Sweden also has a low national rate but <br />

imposes a substantial local corporate income tax.) <br />

The proposed U.S. system will provide more protection against<br />

inflation-induced mismeasurement of income than that of our other<br />

trading partners. Our treatment o f capital cost recovery in general<br />

will be more in line with the practice of other countries, with<br />

respect to both equipment <strong>and</strong> structures, under the proposed system<br />

than it is under present law.<br />

Part 111 further illustrates that the proposed adoption of a per-<br />

country limitation on the <strong>for</strong>eign tax credit would be consistent with


- 257 -<br />

the typical practice of other countries that employ a <strong>for</strong>eign tax <br />

credit. <br />

Sales <strong>Tax</strong>es <br />

Finally, Part IV of the table gives some details on the rates <strong>and</strong> <br />

bases of value added taxes imposed in the five European countries con­<br />

sidered. The United States, Canada <strong>and</strong> Japan do not have a national <br />

value added tax. However, Canada imposes a Federal general sales tax <br />

at the manufacturers’ level, <strong>and</strong> there are provincial sales taxes at <br />

the retail level. Many U.S. states also impose general sales taxes. <br />

The table does not attempt to give a comprehensive picture of the <br />

scope of value added taxes, but simply points out that, even within <br />

the European Economic Community, it has been difficult to st<strong>and</strong>ardize <br />

the treatment of different transactions.


- 258 ­<br />

o m m m n r l m o ~ ~ <br />

dd4dAdASd <br />

0- m N N <br />

rl <br />

om m ID o ID ID m m<br />

d 4 d 2-i e: 4 m' d<br />

ON WNrt<br />

rl<br />

N<br />

m. m . m . "1 . m . N . N . m . *<br />

~ o r l m w ~ d m<br />

mrl rl<br />

....<br />

~ 2 y y y m m ~ ~ ~<br />

o N m m m m m m<br />

Orl *dN N<br />

rl<br />

I2<br />

m


Vw<br />

e <br />

m<br />

w<br />

u) <br />

- 259 -<br />

m<br />

2<br />

A<br />

u<br />

w<br />

0 <br />

P<br />

wI<br />

Y<br />

0 8<br />

rt<br />

w<br />

0 <br />

W<br />

w<br />

0 <br />

m<br />

%<br />

N<br />

m<br />

wI<br />

W<br />

dp<br />

1 <br />

..F<br />

I<br />

'9<br />

0 <br />

w 0 <br />

m<br />

3<br />

g<br />

Y<br />

m <br />

m<br />

2<br />

Y<br />

1<br />

e<br />

.3<br />

w<br />

N <br />

c <br />

w I<br />

W<br />

3 <br />

Y a<br />

6<br />

21<br />

w<br />

W<br />

Ln<br />

dPdp<br />

??<br />

N<br />

mm<br />

N 3<br />

8<br />

u<br />

8<br />

21<br />

w<br />

m<br />

W<br />

w<br />

m<br />

dP<br />

* .I 0 1<br />

u<br />

Y<br />

a<br />

6 $<br />

21 21<br />

mw*<br />

r.?<br />

mI<br />

r(<br />

i <br />

mw 0 3<br />

m ww<br />

w m9<br />

rt or-<br />

3 3<br />

u'<br />

d


u<br />

- 260 -<br />

h<br />

i XdP<br />

0<br />

U m 8 h2 0 %<br />

'c El<br />

u 63<br />

r, 3<br />

5 w d<br />

8 m 8<br />

m<br />

hi<br />

1 63<br />

'c<br />

u El<br />

'c El<br />

Y "* u<br />

dP<br />

0<br />

i<br />

hi<br />

m 888 8 63<br />

U<br />

8 0 888 8 XG e<br />

x<br />

bY<br />

'c<br />

u El<br />

<br />

hi <br />

F3 <br />

v1-(<br />

Lo<br />

8 0 $88 8 $<br />

c<br />

dP<br />

LY u<br />

0<br />

3 X5 hi<br />

x<br />

0 d<br />

'C<br />

,.i 0<br />

%<br />

0 <br />

Lo $ 8<br />

d"<br />

0<br />

m 8 22 hi<br />

'h 3<br />

3<br />

8<br />

h <br />

0<br />

d<br />

3<br />

m <br />

u <br />

1U <br />

Y Lo<br />

2<br />

w 3<br />

0<br />

m' u' d


X<br />

m<br />

- 261 -<br />

0<br />

c<br />

3 m m


~<br />

!A I I<br />

rll I<br />

- 262 -<br />

VI<br />

r <br />

W<br />

E-<br />

VI<br />

w l n<br />

* v m<br />

VI<br />

.I.<br />

m Im<br />

X N<br />

a .<br />

h<br />

c<br />

m<br />

VI<br />

W<br />

u <br />

a <br />

E-<br />

z <br />

3 <br />

0<br />

U<br />

h<br />

N<br />

i<br />

m iln<br />

z i t<br />

W<br />

a <br />

w<br />

h<br />

h<br />

u <br />

ha<br />

oa <br />

C<br />

VI ".I<br />

*u <br />

U C <br />

W O<br />

CI.0<br />

(0 <br />

C v 1m <br />

u] r l l .<br />

a: I: W<br />

U<br />

0 a<br />

w h i5<br />

U x<br />

W m<br />

4<br />

w 3<br />

v1<br />

m<br />

h 2<br />

0 u w F, ln m u I % I I I IWdP I W<br />

C ... u l E u l l C l l l l l n O l 0<br />

..I.<br />

z .I mmu, ( U O O I ~ I I I u,P<br />

0 u rlm<br />

: . a *VIE: z<br />

P<br />

a TI<br />

2<br />

C<br />

m<br />

i3<br />

vi<br />

U m<br />

u<br />

>I m<br />

U<br />

a<br />

E: ..<br />

ul<br />

i3 m<br />

VI X<br />

m <br />

LI<br />

a <br />

m<br />

a <br />

m <br />

W <br />

5<br />

3<br />

L?<br />

2 a: m m<br />

P<br />

U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE : 1984 0 - 459-370

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!