13.07.2015 Views

The feminization and informalization of labour - 447Kb ~ 2 ... - SARPN

The feminization and informalization of labour - 447Kb ~ 2 ... - SARPN

The feminization and informalization of labour - 447Kb ~ 2 ... - SARPN

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Section 2Women, work <strong>and</strong>social policyDOGON WOMENLISTEN TO THE RADIOAS THEY WORK.DOUENTZA, MALI


Chapter 5<strong>The</strong> <strong>feminization</strong> <strong>and</strong><strong>informalization</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>labour</strong>Over the past three decades women’s economic activity rateshave been rising in most parts <strong>of</strong> the world, as was shown infigure 1.2 <strong>and</strong> is shown in figure 5.1. <strong>The</strong>re are exceptions tothis general global trend, notably in the transitional economieswhich are part <strong>of</strong> Eastern Europe as well as Central <strong>and</strong> WesternAsia where there have been notable reversals, <strong>and</strong> in the MiddleEast <strong>and</strong> North Africa (MENA) where they remain verylow. 1 But the general trend is towards increasing female visibilityin the economic domain, <strong>and</strong> in some countries women’sactivity rates are nearing men’s. What does the apparent convergencein male <strong>and</strong> female economic activity rates actuallymean? Does it signify the disappearance <strong>of</strong> gender from the<strong>labour</strong> market? In other words, is being a man, or a woman, nolonger a significant attribute as far as one’s entry into the <strong>labour</strong>force, pattern <strong>of</strong> employment, <strong>labour</strong> market status, <strong>and</strong> accessto pay <strong>and</strong> welfare benefits are concerned? Another questionthat arises from the increase in female <strong>labour</strong> force participationis whether this has had an equalizing affect on the genderdivision <strong>of</strong> unpaid domestic <strong>and</strong> care work.<strong>The</strong> evidence explored in chapter 3 suggests that, whilethere have been important changes in women’s work patterns—notablythe increase in work for pay—<strong>labour</strong> marketscontinue to be segmented by gender, as well as by factors suchas race, caste <strong>and</strong> ethnicity which intersect with gender. Labourmarket segmentation does not disappear with modernization<strong>and</strong> growth, as the experience in the Organization for EconomicCo-operation <strong>and</strong> Development (OECD) countries clearly illustrates.As <strong>labour</strong> markets restructure <strong>and</strong> modernize, there areinvariably both changes <strong>and</strong> continuities. However, the recentintensification <strong>of</strong> women’s paid work has been paralleled byprocesses <strong>of</strong> deregulation in the conditions <strong>of</strong> work, as well asoutsourcing <strong>and</strong> fragmentation <strong>of</strong> international supply chains.<strong>The</strong> first key issue concerning women’s participation in the<strong>labour</strong> market is the way in which their employment has toaccommodate their paramount role in the unpaid domestic <strong>and</strong>care economy. Even in industrialized countries where this type<strong>of</strong> work is shifting to institutions other than the family, the paidcare undertaken in hospitals, crèches <strong>and</strong> homes for the elderlyis a small part <strong>of</strong> all care work done in a society. <strong>The</strong> fact that thiswork is almost exclusively performed by women has repercussionsfor female employment; it tends to penalize working women<strong>and</strong> is key to their weak position in terms <strong>of</strong> earnings <strong>and</strong> occupationalstatus. 2 Although many regard caring as a fulfillingoccupation, in households where incomes are low <strong>and</strong> amenitiesfew, women’s caring load can be disproportionately high<strong>and</strong>, where it includes food <strong>and</strong> utility provision, costly. Policyconcerns therefore include the need not only for more <strong>and</strong> betterwork opportunities for women, but to ease their domestic<strong>and</strong> care burden through better provision <strong>of</strong> basic services, <strong>and</strong>to encourage a fairer male–female distribution <strong>of</strong> unpaid work.However, even when women are included in the <strong>labour</strong>market, women <strong>and</strong> men tend to be segregated into differentoccupations (what is <strong>of</strong>ten referred to as horizontal segregation).Women are also more likely than men to be in occupationswith lower pay, poorer working conditions, <strong>and</strong> worseprospects for advancement (vertical segregation). This is one <strong>of</strong>the main reasons why <strong>labour</strong> market segregation is so pernicious.Authoritative research finds that, despite some improvementsPAGE 67


G E N D E R E Q U A L I T Y : S T R I V I N G F O R J U S T I C E I N A N U N E Q U A L W O R L DFigure 5.1 Female economic activity ratesin the Middle East <strong>and</strong> NorthAfrica <strong>and</strong> transitional countries(1980–latest available year)MIDDLE EAST AND NORTH AFRICAAlgeriaBahrainEgyptIran, Islamic Republic <strong>of</strong>IraqJordanKuwaitLybian Arab JamahiriyaMoroccoOccupied Palestinian TerritoriesOmanQatarSaudi ArabiaSyrian Arab RepublicTunisiaUnited Arab EmiratesYemenTRANSITIONALAlbaniaArmeniaAzerbaijanBelarusBosnia <strong>and</strong> HerzegovinaBulgariaCroatiaEstoniaGeorgiaHungaryKazakhstanKyrgyzstanLatviaLithuaniaMacedonia, TFYRPol<strong>and</strong>Republic <strong>of</strong> MoldovaRomaniaRussian FederationSlovakiaSloveniaTajikistanTurkmenistanUkraineUzbekistanSource: ILO 2003.Percentage0 20 40 60 801980 Latest available year (1995-2003)in the 1990s, levels <strong>of</strong> gender segregation in the <strong>labour</strong> marketremain high throughout the world. 3 Women tend to congregatein relatively low-paid <strong>and</strong> low-status work at the bottom<strong>of</strong> the occupational hierarchy, <strong>and</strong> also to have little job security.Reducing gender segregation requires proactive state interventionin areas such as special training for women <strong>and</strong> antidiscriminationlegislation; as well as the promotion <strong>of</strong> womenemployees’ needs <strong>and</strong> rights within authoritative workers’ organizationscapable <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>ing accountability from governments<strong>and</strong> employers.<strong>The</strong> final gender considerations related to women’s workforceparticipation <strong>and</strong> earning are the potential repercussionson their personal relations at work <strong>and</strong> at home. Earning moneyin any amount for the first time may not alter certain characteristics<strong>of</strong> gender subordination, such as women’s dependenceon male protection; but it may reduce their dependence onmale provision, <strong>and</strong> enhance their economic security <strong>and</strong> sayin household decisions. For younger women it could meangreater mobility, the chance to postpone marriage, <strong>and</strong> a bit <strong>of</strong>discretionary income. <strong>The</strong>ir new-found value can also affect howwomen are treated, as well as their feelings <strong>of</strong> self-worth. 4 <strong>The</strong>segains notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing, there are reasons for caution in equatingwomen’s paid work with empowerment. As already noted, womenmay find their total workload increasing without any change incare responsibilities. <strong>The</strong>re are also instances where men reducetheir contribution to the household budget, especially in placeswhere it is common for fathers not to live with their children,as in South Africa <strong>and</strong> some parts <strong>of</strong> the Caribbean. 5NORTH AND SOUTH:CONVERGINGAND COMPETING?<strong>The</strong> global economy, as pointed out in Chapter 2, is operatingsubstantially below capacity <strong>and</strong> levels <strong>of</strong> unemployment arebecoming more severe. Unemployment rates in most OECDcountries are very high, as is open unemployment in developingcountries. This marks a change: typically, developingcountries have had lower open unemployment rates while disguisedunemployment or underemployment has generally beenmore prevalent. <strong>The</strong> change therefore suggests that the problem<strong>of</strong> finding jobs has become so acute that it is now capturedin such data.Another common pattern is the global trend whereby workis becoming increasingly informal <strong>and</strong> casual, although theextent <strong>of</strong> convergence between patterns in North <strong>and</strong> SouthPAGE 68


C H A P T E R 5 – T H E F E M I N I Z A T I O N A N D I N F O R M A L I Z A T I O N O F L A B O U Rshould not be exaggerated. <strong>The</strong> “informal economy” includesboth self-employment in small <strong>and</strong> unregistered enterprises,<strong>and</strong> wage employment without secure contracts, benefits orlegal protection; this economy is growing in importance worldwide,both in its proportion <strong>of</strong> total employment <strong>and</strong> in thenumber <strong>of</strong> informal enterprises. 6 Even in developed economies,fewer workers have secure contracts, <strong>and</strong> many in formalemployment are losing work-related social benefits, such as healthinsurance <strong>and</strong> pension provision. 7 In much <strong>of</strong> sub-SaharanAfrica <strong>and</strong> South Asia, <strong>and</strong> in such Latin American countriesas Bolivia, Ecuador, Peru <strong>and</strong> Mexico, only a fraction <strong>of</strong> theworkforce has ever been engaged in formal employment. But incountries such as Argentina <strong>and</strong> Chile whose <strong>labour</strong> markets hadcome to resemble those <strong>of</strong> the industrialized world, factorieshave closed, public sector employment has been cut, real wageshave fallen, <strong>and</strong> increasing numbers <strong>of</strong> households have becomedependent on the informal <strong>and</strong> unregulated economy. 8This trend was unforeseen. In the 1960s <strong>and</strong> 1970s, it wasassumed that the worldwide development <strong>of</strong> the modern economywould shrink <strong>and</strong> absorb informal activity, as had happenedhistorically in the industrialized countries. <strong>The</strong> subsequentextensive growth <strong>of</strong> the informal economy has reversed suchexpectations; instead, the global economy has shown a tendencyto encourage precarious forms <strong>of</strong> work which do notbring in sufficient earnings to meet subsistence. In spite <strong>of</strong>this deepening phenomenon, work <strong>and</strong> employment currentlyreceive relatively little attention internationally, except,importantly, from the International Labour Organization(ILO); this is even the case within the poverty reduction agenda<strong>of</strong> the last decade. Indeed, employment hardly features inthe Millennium Development Goals.Finally, while the effects <strong>of</strong> global integration on workers inthe South have been regarded, by trade economists at least, aspositive for developing countries, the available evidence is ambiguous.9 For the vast majority <strong>of</strong> developing countries, manufacturingemployment has actually stagnated or declined over the pastdecade, while the growth in manufacturing activities <strong>and</strong> employmenthas been confined to a h<strong>and</strong>ful <strong>of</strong> countries: China, Malaysia,Indonesia, Thail<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Chile. <strong>The</strong> rapid surge in imports associatedwith trade liberalization is responsible for manufacturing’spoor performance elsewhere, as cheap, newly deregulatedimported goods have displaced those made by small-scale,employment-intensive domestic producers unable to compete ininternational markets. Job losses from import competition havebeen significant in some developing countries, <strong>and</strong> has not becompensated for by the opening up <strong>of</strong> export employment. 10Some advocates <strong>of</strong> trade liberalization argue that women inthe South have emerged as winners in the new manufacturingemployment scenario. But the picture is not straightforward.Wherever export-oriented manufacturing industries havegrown (including in China, Malaysia, Bangladesh, Mexico <strong>and</strong>Thail<strong>and</strong>), women have been disproportionately absorbed intotheir workforces. And even though the working conditions <strong>and</strong>terms <strong>of</strong> pay in many <strong>of</strong> these factories are poor by internationalst<strong>and</strong>ards, they are usually better than in the urban <strong>and</strong> rural informaleconomy. However, these positive considerations concerningexp<strong>and</strong>ing female employment opportunities need to be qualified.In the first place, as chapter 3 has shown, as these industrieshave upgraded, matured, <strong>and</strong> needed a higher skilled workforce,there has been a widespread de<strong>feminization</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>labour</strong>. 11<strong>The</strong>re has also been a strong tendency in industries with a largelyfemale workforce, especially garment manufacturing, towardsderegulation <strong>and</strong> subcontracting; this <strong>of</strong>ten leads to the extensiveuse <strong>of</strong> homeworkers, one <strong>of</strong> the most invisible groups in theinformal economy (see below). Finally, jobs that are destroyedas a result <strong>of</strong> import liberalization are not only those occupiedby the male “<strong>labour</strong> aristocracy” in state-owned or state-protectedindustries, but include jobs held by women. <strong>The</strong>se maybe in the state-owned sector as in China, or informal forms <strong>of</strong>work in small-scale <strong>and</strong> <strong>labour</strong>-intensive local enterprises. 12WOMEN’S EMPLOYMENTIN OECD COUNTRIES:CONTINUITY AND CHANGE 13In the OECD countries, women’s <strong>labour</strong> force participation hasbeen rising as industrialization <strong>and</strong> urbanization have drawnwomen into the formal workforce, albeit unevenly across countries.14 In some, women’s employment rates are nearing men’s.PAGE 69


G E N D E R E Q U A L I T Y : S T R I V I N G F O R J U S T I C E I N A N U N E Q U A L W O R L DFigure 5.2 Part-time employment rates in OECD countries, as percentage<strong>of</strong> total employment (2001)Percentage0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70Netherl<strong>and</strong>sAustraliaJapanSwitzerl<strong>and</strong>United Kingdom (1)New Zeal<strong>and</strong>Icel<strong>and</strong>NorwayIrel<strong>and</strong>CanadaSwedenBelgiumGermany (1)DenmarkFranceLuxembourgUnited StatesAustriaItalyFinl<strong>and</strong>PortugalTurkeySpainGreeceAll Male FemaleNote: (1) Data for 2000.Source: ILO 2003.Women are also being drawn into the informal economy wherethis kind <strong>of</strong> activity is significant, most notably in southernEurope. <strong>The</strong> trend <strong>of</strong> going to work is most noticeable amongmothers with young children, the group most likely to dropout <strong>of</strong> employment in the post-Second World War period.However, workforce participation rates are crude indicators <strong>of</strong>working women’s situations. <strong>The</strong>y reveal nothing about theintensity <strong>of</strong> men’s <strong>and</strong> women’s employment (part-time versusfull-time), their relative contribution to paid <strong>and</strong> unpaid work,or about different patterns <strong>of</strong> lifetime participation. <strong>The</strong>sefactors complicate the picture.First, women are under pressure to limit their paid economicactivity. In all these countries caring <strong>and</strong> household workremains predominantly with women, many <strong>of</strong> whom subordinateemployment to family responsibilities. In many countries, some<strong>of</strong> the care burden <strong>of</strong> children, the sick <strong>and</strong> the elderly is shiftingto institutions other than the family, but women still haveto shoulder a time-consuming household load. Thus many workPAGE 70


C H A P T E R 5 – T H E F E M I N I Z A T I O N A N D I N F O R M A L I Z A T I O N O F L A B O U Rpart-time or drop out <strong>of</strong> the <strong>labour</strong> force altogether at far higherrates than men. Even in the Nordic countries where levels <strong>of</strong>formal participation are highest, many mothers <strong>of</strong> young childrentechnically in the <strong>labour</strong> force are actually on parental leave; fewmen take up their parental leave entitlements. Moreover, wherecare work is bought in—nannies, nurses, cleaners, minders—it isusually done by women, <strong>of</strong>ten from racial or ethnic minorities(see chapter 7). It is invariably underpaid relative to “male”occupations involving similar levels <strong>of</strong> competence.Thus the gender division <strong>of</strong> <strong>labour</strong> is not disappearing, butmodernizing, as women enter the <strong>labour</strong> force <strong>and</strong> stay in employmentfor greater portions <strong>of</strong> their lives. It is now sometimesargued that gender difference is increasingly based on time,with men working full-time <strong>and</strong> women working part-time (seefigure 5.2). This has replaced the older gender distinction betweenmen’s participation in paid work <strong>and</strong> women’s full-time domesticity<strong>and</strong> absence from the <strong>labour</strong> market. <strong>The</strong>re is variationin the quality <strong>of</strong> the work women engage in between countries,as well as in the mix <strong>of</strong> paid <strong>and</strong> unpaid work, but the basic patternis the same: men “specialize” in paid work while doing littleat home; women do the bulk <strong>of</strong> unpaid work, increasingly incombination with employment. <strong>The</strong>re are different views overwhether women work more hours overall. <strong>The</strong> evidence suggeststhat certain groups <strong>of</strong> women are hard-pressed, for exampleemployed mothers who work a “second shift” at home. 15According to recent ILO estimates, three categories <strong>of</strong>non-st<strong>and</strong>ard or atypical work comprise 30 per cent <strong>of</strong> overallemployment in 15 European countries, <strong>and</strong> 25 per cent <strong>of</strong> totalemployment in the United States: self-employment, part-timework (in which women predominate), <strong>and</strong> temporary work. 16This cannot be equated with informal work in developingcountries; some <strong>of</strong> it takes place under contract <strong>and</strong> falls underthe scope <strong>of</strong> <strong>labour</strong> legislation. Work <strong>of</strong> this kind may be adeliberate choice by male <strong>and</strong> female workers with resources,skills <strong>and</strong> other options. Part-time <strong>and</strong> temporary workers are<strong>of</strong>ten employed by regular firms <strong>and</strong> institutions. Nevertheless,atypical workers have fewer protections <strong>and</strong> benefits than fulltimeemployees, although there are differences between countries.Part-time workers are more likely to be eligible for benefitsin Europe than in North America or Japan. 17<strong>The</strong>re is also a rising trend <strong>of</strong> irregular, informal <strong>and</strong> hiddenemployment in many industrialized countries. This kind<strong>of</strong> work is usually undertaken by immigrant women <strong>and</strong>men, many <strong>of</strong> whom are undocumented (see chapter 7). It istherefore extremely difficult to obtain reliable figures concerningits extent or the situation <strong>of</strong> women as opposed to menemployees.Finally, it is important to underline the fact that there is stilla substantial earnings gap between men <strong>and</strong> women in OECDcountries, despite an EU policy mindset which assumes thatwomen, like men, work full-time <strong>and</strong> are financially independent.18 This is partly because so many women work part-time;but there are also earnings gaps among full-time workers, astable 5.1 clearly shows. <strong>The</strong>se reflect occupational segregation<strong>and</strong> the fact that “women’s jobs” earn lower wages. Interestingly,younger women seem to have much higher relative earnings,which may indicate progress over time toward gender parity.But it may also reflect the fact that the youngest cohorts havenot yet entered the prime childrearing years, when women areunder greater pressure to scale back on employment in waysthat <strong>of</strong>ten result in lower pay.WOMEN’S EMPLOYMENTIN EASTERN ANDCENTRAL EUROPE:CRISIS AND DECLINE<strong>The</strong> situation with regard to female employment in the formerlycentralized comm<strong>and</strong> economies <strong>of</strong> Eastern <strong>and</strong> Central Europehas undergone more radical shifts, <strong>and</strong> some reversals. Prior to1989, these countries had achieved remarkably high rates <strong>of</strong>female <strong>labour</strong>-force participation, despite gender segregation <strong>of</strong>jobs, modest gender wage gaps, <strong>and</strong> an unchanged distribution<strong>of</strong> household responsibilities. After the socialist regimes collapsed<strong>and</strong> economies were liberalized, there was a radical <strong>and</strong>alarming decline in employment <strong>and</strong> activity rates for bothmen <strong>and</strong> women. During the course <strong>of</strong> economic transformation,around one-third <strong>of</strong> all jobs were lost, leading to widespreadunemployment. At the same time, state welfare systemsPAGE 71


G E N D E R E Q U A L I T Y : S T R I V I N G F O R J U S T I C E I N A N U N E Q U A L W O R L DTable 5.1Women’s average annual income/earnings as a percentage <strong>of</strong> men’s,by age groups for full-time, full-year workers in the mid to late 1990sTotal 15+ 15–24 25–34 35–44 45–54 55–64 65+Austria 74.9 88.1 80.6 73.4 73.4 65.7 53.0Canada 73.1 82.5 78.2 74.8 69.9 62.4 –Denmark 82.8 – – – – – –Finl<strong>and</strong> 77.6 79.5 81.7 74.5 74.7 75.4 –Irel<strong>and</strong> 65.0 – – – – – –Italy 81.2 93.9 88.9 79.7 80.2 80.2 67.8Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 71.2 88.6 86.6 84.1 75.5 77.6 –Norway (1) 71.2 85.1 71.6 73.4 67.7 79.2 –Spain 77.9 77.9 85.9 82.1 73.8 63.9 34.4Sweden 78.7 84.2 80.2 77.4 76.4 76.6 –Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (2) 76.4 95.1 87.2 80.9 69.6 72.3 –United Kingdom (3) 73.8 – – – – – –United States (2) 68.0 87.2 81.1 69.6 63.5 53.5 54.8Notes (1) Youngest age group is 16–24.(2) Median annual income.(3) Average weekly earnings; figure refers to Great Britain.Source: Orl<strong>of</strong>f 2002.were dismantled. As the real value <strong>of</strong> wages declined, socialbenefits were being reduced, pensions lost their value, inequalitiesincreased, <strong>and</strong> poverty became visible <strong>and</strong> deepened.Complicating the economic <strong>and</strong> social crisis, an ideologicalbacklash ensued against the kind <strong>of</strong> “emancipation” fostered byregimes <strong>of</strong> the communist era, with worrying implications forgender equality prospects.In this turbulent <strong>and</strong> traditionalist-resurgent context,questions were raised about women’s ability to maintain theirpresence in the public sphere. By the early 1990s there hadalready been reversals in women’s <strong>labour</strong>-force participation.Women were facing new—or perhaps old but previously disguised—forms<strong>of</strong> discrimination <strong>and</strong> higher rates <strong>of</strong> unemploymentthan men, while benefits for employed mothers werebeing cut. 19 Were these apprehensions <strong>of</strong> women’s loss <strong>of</strong> holdin the <strong>labour</strong> market borne out by subsequent developments?Apart from Slovenia, the three countries in the regionexhibiting the highest level <strong>of</strong> economic prosperity, the moststreamlined progress towards liberal democracy, <strong>and</strong> the quickesttransition into the EU are the Czech Republic, Hungary<strong>and</strong> Pol<strong>and</strong>. However, concern has been expressed about the“male democracies” taking shape in the region, maybe preciselybecause <strong>of</strong> their rapid integration into the globalizingworld. 20Employment <strong>and</strong> activity rates for both men <strong>and</strong> womendeclined sharply after 1990 <strong>and</strong> are very low in two <strong>of</strong> the threecountries (Pol<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Hungary) (see table 5.2). Czech womenhave had most success in staying economically active, probablybecause employment retrenchment in the Czech Republic wasgenerally milder than in the other two countries. 21 Polishwomen, with a higher rate <strong>of</strong> inactivity in 1989 than women inthe other countries, were less likely to be employed or active in2001. <strong>The</strong> low levels <strong>of</strong> economic activity in Hungary are particularlyworrying, especially as far as women with lower qualificationsare concerned (see box 5.1). In addition to the massdisappearance <strong>of</strong> jobs in the early 1990s, high rates <strong>of</strong> inactivityhave been attributed to the legacy <strong>of</strong> an early retirement age,<strong>and</strong> generous maternity/parental leave policies which encouragedmothers (but not fathers) to leave work. Women’s activityrates are well below the EU average (60 per cent), or even thePAGE 72


vke ctV 2009&10varfje ctV dks ysdj ehfM;kesa] [kkldj n`'; ehfM;k esavuko';d fdLe dh ,dmŸkstuk FkhA dbZ yksx ,d fu;ferctV vkSj varfje ctV ds chp varjgh ugÈ dj ldsA nqfu;k Hkj dhvVdysa yxkbZ xbZa fd vkf[kj varfjectV esa D;k gksxkA ge esa ls dqN yksxtks varfje ctV dh lhekvksa ls ifjfprgSa] os tkurs Fks fd ;s lkjh vVdysavkSj vkdka{kk,a vuko';d vkSj HkzkedgSaAvarfje ctV vkadM+ksa ds [ksy lsT;knk dqN ugÈ gksrk D;ksafdblesa ,dkèk eghus ds fy,ljdkj pykus ds fy,,d fufÜpr èkujkf'k ijlaln dh eatwjh Hkj ysuhgksrh gSA dkSy vkSj 'kdèkjds eqrkfcd] ,d varfjectV dk mís'; ys[kkuqnkugksrk gS vkSj blds fy,laln esa cgl dh Hkht:jr ugÈ gksrhA ;gvius pfj= esa gh bruklkekU; gksrk gS fd blscxSj fdlh cgl ds ikfjrfd;k tk ldrk gSA tkfgjgS fd bl varfje ctV ls fujk'kkgksuh gh Fkh vkSj blh ds fy, bl fnucktkj dks èkjk'kk;h gksus ls ugÈ cpk;ktk ldkAftl rjg eueksgu flag us 28Qjojh] 1996 dks ,d varfje ctVis'k fd;k Fkk] Bhd mlh rtZ ij ;gctV Hkh ;wih, ljdkj dh miyfCèk;ksadk xq.kxku gh FkkA Bhd 1996 dsvarfje ctV dh rjg blesa Hkh ljdkjus nksckjk lŸkk esa vkus ij viuhçkFkfedrkvksa dks fxuk;k gSA QdZ flQZ;g jgk fd 1996 ls myV bl ckjfoŸk ea=h ds ikl vius ctV vfHkHkk"k.kekpZ 1&15] 2009 13vkadM+ksa ds [ksy ls T;knkdqN ugÈ gS ;g ctV;'koar flUgkesa de ls de rhu iSjk oSfÜod vkfFkZdeanh ds Hkkjr ij vlj dks lefiZrdjus ds fy, le; jgkA ;g ,dfcYdqy vyx ckr gS fd mudh blJ)katfy dk vkf[kj esa dksbZ urhtkugÈ fudykA;fn eq>s varfje ctV ds bdykSrslcls egRoiw.kZ rRo dks js[kkafdr djusdk dgk tk,] rks eSa dgwaxk fd ;gfiNys lky 28 Qjojh dks ih fpnacje}kjk is'k fd, x, vke ctV dsQtÊokM+s dks mtkxj djrk gSA blesadksbZ nks jk; ugÈ fd ç.ko eq[ktÊ usç.ko eq[ktÊ us vc jktdks"kh; ?kkVs dks c


G E N D E R E Q U A L I T Y : S T R I V I N G F O R J U S T I C E I N A N U N E Q U A L W O R L DBox 5.1Women outside the <strong>labour</strong> market in Hungary<strong>The</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> economic inactivity in Hungary is high <strong>and</strong> on the rise. From 1.5 million women aged 15–64 in 1999, the numberhad gone up to 1.7 million in 2001, from 41 to 48 per cent <strong>of</strong> the age group. (<strong>The</strong> corresponding rates for men were 23 percent in 1999 <strong>and</strong> 34 per cent in 2001.) All age groups are represented, <strong>and</strong> the majority have very low qualifications. <strong>The</strong>declared reasons for women not to be working include seeking education (27 per cent), undertaking childcare (21 per cent),<strong>and</strong> taking early retirement (27 per cent); a quarter give no reason. In 2002, other than those in education or near retirement,the great majority said that they would like to work—far more than the number <strong>of</strong> active job-seekers. Re-entry into the formal<strong>labour</strong> market is not easy however, as many companies have been liquidated <strong>and</strong> former employers are not able to taketheir ex-employees back. Return is particularly difficult for those who have spent a long spell outside the <strong>labour</strong> market. Fewpeople can afford to pay for childcare, care for the sick or elderly, or domestic help. Meanwhile most households need a secondearner. So those women who are able, undertake a variety <strong>of</strong> casual work—gardening, taking care <strong>of</strong> children or olderpeople, cleaning—in their vicinity for a few hours a day or week, bypassing the formal economy. Those engaging in suchwork are poor, live on a pension or childcare assistance, <strong>and</strong> so grasp any opportunity they can. <strong>The</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> pay has little to dowith the <strong>of</strong>ficial minimum wage. <strong>The</strong> segmentation <strong>of</strong> the <strong>labour</strong> market in Hungary is deep, with few passagewaysbetween the unrecognized informal economy <strong>and</strong> the formal workplace.Source: Laky 2004.MIDDLE EAST ANDNORTH AFRICA: STALLEDINDUSTRIALIZATIONAND DIVERSIFICATIONAlthough the MENA region is <strong>of</strong>ten studied as an integratedwhole (due to certain shared cultural, religious <strong>and</strong> historical characteristics,<strong>and</strong> the prevalence <strong>of</strong> oil economies), it includes threedistinct types <strong>of</strong> economy: the oil economies (such as Kuwait <strong>and</strong>Saudi Arabia); the mixed oil economies (such as Algeria, IslamicRepublic <strong>of</strong> Iran, Iraq <strong>and</strong> Tunisia); <strong>and</strong> the non-oil economies(such as Jordan, Morocco <strong>and</strong> Turkey). Women’s <strong>labour</strong>-forceparticipation <strong>and</strong> access to paid employment in the region arelower than those reported for other developing regions, althoughthey have been rising in recent years (see figure 5.1).As part <strong>of</strong> state-directed industrialization during the 1970s<strong>and</strong> 1980s, the formal sector in most countries in MENA waslargely made up <strong>of</strong> government agencies <strong>and</strong> state-owned enterprises.High wages <strong>and</strong> generous social policies for employeeswere made possible by state oil revenues, <strong>and</strong> by the capital <strong>and</strong><strong>labour</strong> flows between countries (for example, remittances <strong>of</strong>workers from non-oil countries working in the oil or mixed-oileconomy countries). At the same time, income taxes wereamong the lowest in the world. A detailed comparative study<strong>of</strong> wage trends has established that the wages <strong>of</strong> manufacturingworkers were higher in most <strong>of</strong> these countries than in Asiancountries such as the Republic <strong>of</strong> Korea, Malaysia <strong>and</strong> thePhilippines. 24<strong>The</strong> political economy <strong>of</strong> oil, however, was a mixed blessing.It weakened accountability mechanisms between the citizens <strong>and</strong>the state, allowing authoritarian states to dominate the economy<strong>and</strong> society. <strong>The</strong>re were also important implications as far asemployment opportunities <strong>and</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> economic diversificationwere concerned. High wages for male workers, large-scale malemigration from the non-oil countries to the oil-rich countries,remittances sent back by (male) migrant workers, <strong>and</strong> the cultural<strong>and</strong> legal sanction given to the “male breadwinner” ideal,all served to suppress women’s employment. In some <strong>labour</strong>sendingcountries, <strong>labour</strong> shortages led to a new dependence <strong>of</strong>the agricultural sector on women workers. But overall, theregion did not exhibit the levels <strong>of</strong> female <strong>labour</strong>-force participationdeveloping in Southeast Asia or parts <strong>of</strong> Latin America.PAGE 74


C H A P T E R 5 – T H E F E M I N I Z A T I O N A N D I N F O R M A L I Z A T I O N O F L A B O U R<strong>The</strong> ILO has recently provided a statistical picture <strong>of</strong> theinformal economy, which helps shed light on the male–femaleshare <strong>of</strong> informal employment, job status <strong>and</strong> incomes earned. 28Some <strong>of</strong> the findings are summarized below.In developing countries• Informal employment comprises one half to three-quarters<strong>of</strong> non-agricultural employment: 48 per cent in NorthAfrica, 51 per cent in Latin America, 65 per cent in Asia,72 per cent in sub-Saharan Africa (table 5.4).• Informal employment tends to be a larger source <strong>of</strong> employmentfor women than for men in all developing regionsexcept North Africa (table 5.4).• Self-employment comprises a greater share <strong>of</strong> informalemployment (outside agriculture) than wage employmentin all developing regions. In most countries this share isgreater for women than for men (table 5.5).• Although women’s <strong>labour</strong> force participation rates are lowerthan men’s, the limited data available point to the importance<strong>of</strong> women in home-based work <strong>and</strong> street vending.• Those who work in the informal economy are generally notcovered by <strong>labour</strong> legislation for social protection <strong>and</strong> earnless, on average, than workers in the formal economy.Women in all parts <strong>of</strong> the world speak <strong>of</strong> the advantages—notably the flexibility—<strong>of</strong> part-time <strong>and</strong> home-based work.But this type <strong>of</strong> <strong>labour</strong> market adaptation is generally onesided,derived from the needs <strong>of</strong> employers to access workerswhose domestic responsibilities would otherwise exclude them. 29Much <strong>of</strong> this work is low-paid <strong>and</strong> insecure. Typically there are nocontractual rights to paid leave, for sickness, maternity or vacation.Nor are pension rights included. <strong>The</strong>re is an assumptionthat a husb<strong>and</strong> or son will provide support for the retired workerin her old age. 30 Even the presumed advantages <strong>of</strong> “flexible”work—accommodation <strong>of</strong> women’s caring responsibilities—maybe less relevant in settings where the potential domestic pool isTable 5.4Informal employment in non-agricultural employment,by sex, different regions <strong>and</strong> selected countries (1994–2000)Region /country Informal employment Women’s informal Men’s informal employmentas percentage <strong>of</strong> employment as percentage as percentage <strong>of</strong> men’snon-agricultural <strong>of</strong> women’s non-agricultural non-agriculturalemployment employment employmentNorth Africa 48 43 49Algeria 43 41 43Egypt 55 46 57Sub-Saharan Africa 72 84 63Chad 74 95 60Kenya 72 83 59South Africa 51 58 44Latin America 51 58 48Bolivia 63 74 55Brazil 60 67 55Chile 36 44 31El Salvador 57 69 46Mexico 55 55 54Asia 65 65 65India 83 86 83Indonesia 78 77 78Thail<strong>and</strong> 51 54 49Syrian Arab Republic 42 35 43Source: ILO 2002b.PAGE 77


G E N D E R E Q U A L I T Y : S T R I V I N G F O R J U S T I C E I N A N U N E Q U A L W O R L DTable 5.5Wage <strong>and</strong> self-employment in the non-agricultural informal sectorby sex, different regions <strong>and</strong> selected countries (1994–2000)Country/region Self-employment as percentage Wage employment as a percentage<strong>of</strong> non-agricultural informal<strong>of</strong> non-agricultural informalemploymentemploymentSource: ILO 2002b.Total Women Men Total Women MenNorth Africa 62 72 60 38 28 40Algeria 67 81 64 33 19 36Egypt 50 67 47 50 33 53Sub-Saharan Africa 70 71 70 30 29 30Chad 93 99 86 7 1 14Kenya 42 33 56 58 67 44South Africa 25 27 23 75 73 77Latin America 60 58 61 40 42 39Bolivia 81 91 71 19 9 29Brazil 41 32 50 59 68 50Chile 52 39 64 48 61 36El Salvador 65 71 57 35 29 43Mexico 54 53 54 46 47 46Asia 59 63 55 41 37 45India 52 57 51 48 43 49Indonesia 63 70 59 37 30 41Thail<strong>and</strong> 66 68 64 34 32 36Syrian Arab Republic 65 57 67 35 43 33wide, paid domestic <strong>labour</strong> is cheap, <strong>and</strong> where many womenare the sole income earners within their households. 31Rural migrants enteringthe urban informal economyA more in-depth gendered analysis <strong>of</strong> the informal economy canbe gained by drawing on a range <strong>of</strong> relevant case studies. Ruralimpoverishment has historically contributed to migration intourban areas <strong>and</strong> continues to do so. Migrants come from all strata<strong>of</strong> society, <strong>and</strong> those who have capital, skills <strong>and</strong> contacts tendto go furthest <strong>and</strong> do best. 32 Women who migrate are <strong>of</strong>ten seenas “associational”, simply accompanying their husb<strong>and</strong>s: in India,for example, even though female migrants predominate, only1 per cent are recorded as migrating for employment. Howeverwives do look for work, returning home if they fail, <strong>and</strong> the manywho stay are migrants in their own right. 33 Women’s patterns <strong>of</strong>migration can also change rapidly depending on workplaceopportunity, as has recently happened in Bangladesh. 34<strong>The</strong> employment <strong>of</strong> young, rural, migrant women in exportorientedmanufacturing industries has been studied extensivelyover the past decade, with conflicting interpretations <strong>of</strong> whatsuch employment means to the women involved. However, amuch larger contingent <strong>of</strong> women can be found on the lowest,least visible rung <strong>of</strong> the informal employment ladder. Manylack the skills <strong>and</strong> connections needed to secure more stablejobs with decent pay. <strong>The</strong>y usually live in slum housing withouteven the most basic amenities, <strong>and</strong> are <strong>of</strong>ten at the mercy<strong>of</strong> local “strongmen”. 35Particularly pertinent in the context <strong>of</strong> an overall concernwith liberalization is a study in Dhaka (Bangladesh) comparingPAGE 78


G E N D E R E Q U A L I T Y : S T R I V I N G F O R J U S T I C E I N A N U N E Q U A L W O R L DBox 5.2Kayaye in Ghana: <strong>The</strong> poor exploiting the very poorCommercial head-loading by girls <strong>and</strong> women known as kayaye is commonplace in large towns <strong>and</strong> city areas in Ghana,where women traders <strong>and</strong> buyers employ these women to move their goods between purchasing points <strong>and</strong> transport facilities.Head-load portering is women’s work in Ghana as elsewhere in Africa, while portering by men involves the use <strong>of</strong>wheeled equipment such as a h<strong>and</strong>-pulled cart or wheelbarrow.<strong>The</strong> female portering trade depends on a network <strong>of</strong> ethnic ties. <strong>The</strong>se facilitate the migration <strong>of</strong> girls from rural areas<strong>and</strong> their incorporation into city life, supplying them with accommodation, working tools <strong>and</strong> access to savings schemes.Most are from northern Ghana, the most economically deprived region in the country; the majority <strong>of</strong> the kayaye in Accra,for example, come from northern Ghana <strong>and</strong> spend six months to a year in the city. <strong>The</strong>y maintain close ties with their families<strong>and</strong> send them part <strong>of</strong> their income. <strong>The</strong>y share accommodation <strong>and</strong> form savings clubs as part <strong>of</strong> their strategy to survive.Kayaye typically live in wooden sheds around the markets. <strong>The</strong>se are used for trading by day, <strong>and</strong> as shelter when thetrading day is over. <strong>The</strong>y pay a fee <strong>and</strong> sleep on cardboard, sacks or on a piece <strong>of</strong> cloth. Only at night can they use the shedsfor sleeping, so they have difficulty storing their belongings <strong>and</strong> caring for their children. Mothers leave their children in thecare <strong>of</strong> girls aged as young as six, who operate as child minders before graduating into porterage themselves. <strong>The</strong> kayayes’housing situation makes them vulnerable to sexual abuse.Kayaye are members <strong>of</strong> a growing urban homeless contingent. After porterage <strong>and</strong> petty trading, commercial sex is thenext most popular activity among females in this category. Kayaye may also engage in commercial sex work at night to augmenttheir meagre earnings. Children as young as ten are involved in commercial sex, for which there is a high dem<strong>and</strong>.Just as these girls are not able to dem<strong>and</strong> fair wages for their services as porters, they are not able to negotiate safe sex orreasonable wages for sex. <strong>The</strong>y rarely have access to reproductive health services, including safe abortions.Source: UNICEF 2002.street vending <strong>and</strong> similar activities. In both countries, theinformal economy is dominated by low-return <strong>and</strong> low-productivityactivities pursued as a means <strong>of</strong> survival.Perpetuation <strong>of</strong> informality to disguisereal employmentIn many parts <strong>of</strong> the world, types <strong>of</strong> employment relationship areemerging that are purposely disguised as something else, or notclearly defined. Recruitment into more secure positions tends tobe selective, drawing on male c<strong>and</strong>idates with their higher educationalqualifications <strong>and</strong> other advantages; successful applicantsfor jobs are also <strong>of</strong>ten from socially privileged or ethnicallyfavoured groups. Women cannot transcend the many biasesagainst them <strong>and</strong> remain locked into the casual workforce.Box 5.3 describes the process <strong>of</strong> <strong>labour</strong> segmentation inagro-processing in south India. In many such situations,although there is clearly an employment relationship, theworker is not covered by <strong>labour</strong> legislation, <strong>and</strong> receives nosocial benefits. In other cases there may be a contract, but therelationship is deliberately disguised as commercial transaction.This is done so that the employer can sidestep <strong>labour</strong>legislation <strong>and</strong> avoid even basic occupational health <strong>and</strong> safetyresponsibilities, not to mention social benefits. A variationis to acknowledge the employment, but to hire the same workeron repeated short-term contracts—“permanent temporarywork”—so that social benefits <strong>and</strong> customary entitlements canbe denied.<strong>The</strong>re are also cases where the employment relationship isambiguous: for example, where dependent workers operate athome on a piece-rate basis rather than attend an organized work-PAGE 80


C H A P T E R 5 – T H E F E M I N I Z A T I O N A N D I N F O R M A L I Z A T I O N O F L A B O U RBox 5.3Stratified markets in south India entrench insecurityIn small south Indian towns dominated by agro-processing activity there are several fault lines in the security <strong>of</strong> <strong>labour</strong>. <strong>The</strong>typical informal unit is tightly controlled by patriarchal male family members who confer or withdraw security at their whim.Workers are selected by origin (local), caste (usually avoiding Scheduled Castes) <strong>and</strong> gender (male). <strong>The</strong>re are a number <strong>of</strong>permanent jobs, highly sought after, in livelihoods ranging from the night watch to accountancy. Contracts are individualized<strong>and</strong> verbal. Payment periods vary, <strong>and</strong> may be confined to yearly disbursement, while dismissal is instant. Some permanentjobs can be part-time, others seasonal. A form <strong>of</strong> occupational welfare is usually extended to this workforce in the form <strong>of</strong>loans <strong>and</strong> gifts <strong>of</strong> cash for medical costs, education <strong>and</strong> marriages. <strong>The</strong>se can be seen as primitive imitations <strong>of</strong> regular stateprotections, but their other purpose is to tie down employees valued by the employer.Meanwhile the casual workforce is entirely at the mercy <strong>of</strong> the employer <strong>and</strong> receives no benefits <strong>of</strong> any kind. Pay is low<strong>and</strong> fluctuating, the job turnover is high <strong>and</strong> security is nonexistent. Labour recruiters belong in the upper category <strong>and</strong>enjoy annual bonuses <strong>and</strong> small loans; but they are encouraged to turn <strong>labour</strong> over fast so as to reduce customary entitlementto annual “gifts” <strong>and</strong> avoid protective obligations. Male casual <strong>labour</strong> is occasionally unionized, but the multiplicity <strong>of</strong>unions leads to the political mediation <strong>of</strong> disputes; the state effectively enforces the <strong>labour</strong> laws, rarely in the workers’ favour.Factory inspectors with huge territories to cover <strong>and</strong> few resources for enforcing the law are <strong>of</strong>ten corruptly implicated withbosses in the evasion <strong>of</strong> laws <strong>and</strong> the erosion <strong>of</strong> <strong>labour</strong> rights.Female casual <strong>labour</strong> is subjected to extremes <strong>of</strong> casualization, negligence <strong>and</strong> harassment <strong>and</strong> to unsafe <strong>and</strong> unsanitaryworking conditions, their wages <strong>of</strong>ten being reported by bosses as “pocket money”. In such firms, work has for decades beensubcontracted, <strong>of</strong>ten exported to rural sites to avoid inspection <strong>and</strong> to pr<strong>of</strong>it from cheap or unwaged family <strong>labour</strong>, from lowrents, <strong>and</strong> from the ease <strong>of</strong> evasion <strong>of</strong> any welfare obligations <strong>and</strong> taxes. Thus capital uses informal practices <strong>and</strong> a selectiveidiom <strong>of</strong> social protection to render the majority <strong>of</strong> the workforce extremely insecure, <strong>and</strong> a small valued minority less insecure.Source: Harriss-White 2000.place. Increasing numbers <strong>of</strong> people work in situations wherebrokers or subcontractors intermediate between the person doingthe work, <strong>and</strong> the firm for which it is being done. <strong>The</strong> worker onlyhas contact with the supplier <strong>of</strong> materials <strong>and</strong> collector <strong>of</strong> thefinished goods. <strong>The</strong> broker himself or herself may be operatingon slim pr<strong>of</strong>it margins, <strong>and</strong> also be vulnerable <strong>and</strong> insecure.After the Asian crisis, the garment industry in the Philippineswas restructured; many women lost their formal jobs, yetremained in the industry. One woman became a <strong>labour</strong> supplierfor the same firm she had previously worked for, organizingwomen she had formerly worked with, to produce the embroideredsmocking on children’s clothes. She is Gloria Bularin, inbox 5.4 below. This illustrates the many-layered nature <strong>of</strong> subcontractedwork. It also shows the exceptionally low wages atthe lower end <strong>of</strong> the chain. Information about the earnings <strong>of</strong>middle-level subcontractors is invariably difficult to obtain.<strong>The</strong> <strong>informalization</strong> process:OutsourcingSince <strong>informalization</strong> <strong>of</strong> employment is growing, it is importantto underst<strong>and</strong> the process which leads to the deconstruction<strong>of</strong> jobs <strong>and</strong> their removal from the protected workplace.<strong>The</strong> increased organization <strong>of</strong> the workplace cannot be guaranteed;on the contrary. Previous assumptions that certainoccupations <strong>and</strong> enterprises were fixed in the formal or informaleconomy have turned out to be misleading; some that wereformal have become informal, <strong>of</strong>ten with the same worker inplace. Textile, clothing, leather <strong>and</strong> footwear industries inSouth Africa, protected <strong>and</strong> subsidized under the old apartheidregime, show these characteristics, according to a study documentingthe impacts <strong>of</strong> <strong>labour</strong> retrenchment <strong>and</strong> the introduction<strong>of</strong> subcontracting <strong>and</strong> other “flexible” <strong>labour</strong> practices inPAGE 81


G E N D E R E Q U A L I T Y : S T R I V I N G F O R J U S T I C E I N A N U N E Q U A L W O R L DBox 5.4Subcontracting <strong>and</strong> pricing in clothing, the PhilippinesAngono in the Philippines is a town well known for its embroidery work. Dem<strong>and</strong> comes from Carol’s, a major local retailer<strong>of</strong> children’s wear. In this domestic chain <strong>of</strong> production, baby dresses with h<strong>and</strong> embroidery sell for between US$6.86 <strong>and</strong>US$9.80. Diana Juan is a supplier to Carol’s. She has live-in workers doing the straight sewing, <strong>and</strong> subcontracts the h<strong>and</strong>embroidery through Marisol Ugarte, who gets US$0.03 a line. Marisol Ugarte subcontracts to Gloria Bularin at US$0.02 perline. Gloria Bularin in turn organizes homeworkers, who she pays US$0.01 to US$0.015 per line.Source: Doane et al. 2003, cited in Lund 2004.the context <strong>of</strong> liberalization. 44 With the lowering <strong>of</strong> trade barriers,imports began to flood the economy. By the late 1990s,both employment <strong>and</strong> production in the footwear industrybegan to decline, with the clothing, leather <strong>and</strong> textile sectorslater following suit. Restructuring <strong>and</strong> “rationalization” inthese <strong>labour</strong>-intensive industries resulted in massive job losses.As far as women are concerned, the negative employmenteffects stem from the increasing <strong>informalization</strong> <strong>of</strong> the workplace.“Rationalization” is achieved through job rotation, outsourcing<strong>and</strong> subcontracting. Some retrenched workers havebeen encouraged to buy their equipment <strong>and</strong> set up in homebasedproduction. At the same time, growing numbers <strong>of</strong>women evicted from these clothing <strong>and</strong> textile industries areending up in street trading <strong>and</strong> other survival activities in theinformal economy. Despite <strong>of</strong>ficial commitment to aid small<strong>and</strong> medium-sized enterprises, there is no access to state support,at least from the central government. 45In many countries, the phenomenon <strong>of</strong> homeworkers isgrowing; most <strong>of</strong> them are women. Millions <strong>of</strong> these subcontractedemployees, working on a piece-rate basis, feed productivepr<strong>of</strong>it-making output from their homes into the more formalmanufacturing companies or their intermediaries. <strong>The</strong>payment they receive is extremely low, <strong>and</strong> they may have towork extremely long hours or at night to make enough moneyto survive; many also use their children as subsidiary workers.<strong>The</strong>se areas are untouched by <strong>labour</strong> laws <strong>and</strong> social welfare.<strong>The</strong> fact that homeworkers are dispersed raises special challengesfor collective action, but to change the conditions underwhich they work they need to bargain for more regular work orders,higher piece rates <strong>and</strong> more prompt payment (see box 5.5).Many female homeworkers process products in the globalvalue chain, while others work on articles destined for thedomestic market. In the garments industry workforce alone,the percentage <strong>of</strong> homeworkers in the mid-1990s was estimatedat 38 per cent in Thail<strong>and</strong>, between 25–39 per cent in thePhilippines, 30 per cent in one region <strong>of</strong> Mexico, between30–60 per cent in Chile <strong>and</strong> 45 per cent in Venezuela. 46 Veryrecent research indicates that some <strong>of</strong> this “s<strong>of</strong>t” employmentis facing a crisis as textile <strong>and</strong> garment exports face growingcompetition in world markets, <strong>and</strong> companies try to cut costsstill further.Informalization <strong>and</strong> public-sectorretrenchmentIn many low-income countries, public-sector workers have alsobeen crowding into the informal economy, even when theyhave managed to maintain their jobs despite public-sectorretrenchment. <strong>The</strong> civil service reforms <strong>of</strong> the early 1990s<strong>of</strong>ten entailed radical downsizing; today more emphasis isplaced on “new public management” reforms which seek tochange the incentive structures <strong>and</strong> outsource some <strong>of</strong> thefunctions <strong>of</strong> the public administration (see chapter 11). 47Cameroon is a case in point. Like many other Africancountries, Cameroon underwent an economic recession in thePAGE 82


C H A P T E R 5 – T H E F E M I N I Z A T I O N A N D I N F O R M A L I Z A T I O N O F L A B O U RBox 5.5Homeworkers <strong>and</strong> the self-employed<strong>The</strong> problems <strong>and</strong> constraints faced by self-employed home-based workers <strong>and</strong> homeworkers are quite different, althoughboth typically lack bargaining power <strong>and</strong> have to provide their own social protection. Homeworkers are <strong>of</strong>ten forced by circumstancesto work for low wages without secure contracts or fringe benefits <strong>and</strong> to cover some production costs ... Mostself-employed home-based workers, except high-end pr<strong>of</strong>essionals, face limited access to <strong>and</strong>/or competition in relevantmarkets. To improve their situation homeworkers need to strengthen their capacity to bargain for regular work orders, higherpiece rates, <strong>and</strong> overdue back pay (a common problem faced by homeworkers worldwide); while home-based self-employedneed better access to financial markets <strong>and</strong> enhanced capacity to compete in product markets. In effect, homeworkers <strong>of</strong>tenface problems <strong>of</strong> exploitation while the self-employed <strong>of</strong>ten face problems <strong>of</strong> exclusion. <strong>The</strong> strategies to address problems<strong>of</strong> exploitation in <strong>labour</strong> markets-such as collective bargaining for higher wages-are different than the strategies to addressproblems <strong>of</strong> exclusion in capital <strong>and</strong> product markets—such as providing access to financial, marketing, <strong>and</strong> business services.Source: ILO 2002b.mid-1980s, <strong>and</strong> subsequently embarked on a structural adjustmentprogramme. One target <strong>of</strong> the reforms was the civil service.In addition to downsizing <strong>of</strong> the public sector throughretrenchments <strong>and</strong> retirements (in 1995/96 alone, seven ministriesfired significant numbers <strong>of</strong> workers), the terms <strong>and</strong> conditions<strong>of</strong> service for public employees were drastically trimmed.Within three years, civil servants experienced salary cuts <strong>of</strong> upto 60 per cent, <strong>and</strong> payments fell heavily into arrears. As inmany other African countries, civil servants forced to compensatefor loss <strong>of</strong> earnings <strong>and</strong> falling living st<strong>and</strong>ards began tomake forays into the informal economy, along diverse lines(see box 5.6). 48Women <strong>and</strong> men are not evenly placed within the publicservice. Women generally tend to have a minimal presence inadministrative <strong>and</strong> managerial positions; they also tend to clusterwithin services such as health <strong>and</strong> education. Reliable statisticsshowing how women <strong>and</strong> men have fared comparatively interms <strong>of</strong> retrenchment from the public sector are difficult t<strong>of</strong>ind; much depends on where the staff cuts have been made.But public-sector reforms also generate downward pressures onwages <strong>and</strong> working conditions, <strong>and</strong> these are likely to have fallenparticularly on lower-level staff. <strong>The</strong>se pressures are affectingwomen health workers <strong>and</strong> their interactions with women healthusers, as explored in chapter 8.<strong>The</strong> case <strong>of</strong> ChinaIn China where women have been intensively employed in stateownedenterprises, the process <strong>of</strong> industrial restructuring hasdealt a heavy blow to their employment prospects <strong>and</strong> security.China is <strong>of</strong>ten cited as threatening jobs prospects in other parts<strong>of</strong> the world, with its dynamic export-oriented industries attractingmillions <strong>of</strong> young rural migrants each year: 48 per cent <strong>of</strong> allmigrant workers in China are women (figures for 2000).<strong>The</strong> view <strong>of</strong> China as the “workshop <strong>of</strong> the world” is onesided.Often overlooked are the huge inequalities—class,regional, rural/urban, age, gender—stemming from a quartercentury<strong>of</strong> market reform which has drastically restructured theeconomy <strong>and</strong> workforce. <strong>The</strong> privatization <strong>of</strong> industry has dealta severe blow to permanent state workers’ entitlements, shatteringtheir prized employment <strong>and</strong> livelihood security. Workersin collective enterprises, which previously functioned as statesubsidiaries, also suffered huge lay<strong>of</strong>fs. In 1993 the <strong>of</strong>ficial unionfound that women workers accounted for 37 per cent <strong>of</strong> all stateworkers but 60 per cent <strong>of</strong> those laid <strong>of</strong>f <strong>and</strong> unemployed. By1999 women accounted for 45 per cent <strong>of</strong> all laid-<strong>of</strong>f workers. 49Informal work, termed “flexible employment” by someChinese researchers, has become a major source <strong>of</strong> income forthe unemployed. <strong>The</strong> availability <strong>of</strong> such employment variesPAGE 83


G E N D E R E Q U A L I T Y : S T R I V I N G F O R J U S T I C E I N A N U N E Q U A L W O R L DBox 5.6Straddling strategies by teachers <strong>and</strong> health workers in the South WestProvince <strong>of</strong> CameroonBefore the economic crisis, teachers were among the best-paid civil servants in Cameroon. Once the reforms began to bite,teachers began to supplement their falling wages with informal activities. <strong>The</strong>y now comprise the largest number <strong>of</strong> formalemployees working as newcomer entrants into the informal economy: 67 out <strong>of</strong> 75 <strong>of</strong> the teachers interviewed in a studyundertook such activities. Health workers are now joining them, as are clerical staff.<strong>The</strong>se public-sector workers use their position, equipment <strong>and</strong> time in the regular workplace to undertake other pr<strong>of</strong>itmakingwork on an informal basis. <strong>The</strong> different ways they do this depend on the existing job <strong>and</strong> to a considerable extenton gender. In the case <strong>of</strong> teachers, while men, <strong>and</strong> a few women, provided supplementary private tuition for individual studentsor classes, <strong>and</strong> sold reproductions <strong>of</strong> lecture notes to secondary <strong>and</strong> high-school students, women teachers mostlyundertook petty trading in food. <strong>The</strong>y sold meals at lunch time <strong>and</strong> a variety <strong>of</strong> snacks, as well as non-food items. <strong>The</strong> capitalbase <strong>of</strong> such trade is very small.Nurses, like teachers, were involved in informal activities related to their formal work. From being a secretive sporadicactivity, private practice or “PP” became widespread <strong>and</strong> open after general <strong>and</strong> hospital strikes <strong>of</strong> the early 1990s failed toobtain improved working conditions <strong>and</strong> salaries. PP commonly involves minor consultations <strong>and</strong> drug sales to patients outsidethe hospital, sales <strong>of</strong> drugs within hospital premises during working hours, home-care nursing, or a combination <strong>of</strong>informal health care <strong>and</strong> petty trading.Source: Agbaw 2000, cited in Tsikata 2004.across cities <strong>and</strong> regions, but the Ministry <strong>of</strong> Labour has estimatedthat <strong>of</strong> 25 million unemployed <strong>and</strong> laid-<strong>of</strong>f workers nationwide,15 million have found jobs in the informal economy. 50Those with financial means have opened up private or familybusinesses such as restaurants, salons or neighbourhood stores.At the other end <strong>of</strong> the spectrum, especially in the northeast“rust belt” where economic growth has been sluggish, casualwork only is available. Men work as day <strong>labour</strong>ers in construction,help out in private enterprises or trade on the street.Unemployed women workers sometimes turn to prostitution.In one study in three northeastern cities, <strong>of</strong> more than 100 sexworkers, 74 per cent were former state-owned-enterprise workers,<strong>and</strong> most (92 per cent) had become sex workers after seekingalternative employment for over four years. 51<strong>The</strong>re are no clear patterns <strong>of</strong> gender disparity in the reemployment<strong>of</strong> laid-<strong>of</strong>f workers. Qualitative studies have <strong>of</strong>fereddivergent interpretations. One study in Wuhan finds thatfemale laid-<strong>of</strong>f workers have a better chance starting a serviceorientedbusiness than male counterparts; these are more averseto service roles but have more success in finding positions inestablished companies. 52 Another study in three cities finds thatage discrimination is at least as serious as sex discrimination.Almost every interviewee aged over 30 cited this rather thangender as a major obstacle to finding re-employment. This situationis compounded by the cohort experience <strong>of</strong> the over-30s asthe unlucky generation sent out to the countryside during theCultural Revolution <strong>and</strong> deprived <strong>of</strong> a sound education. 53Another issue <strong>of</strong>ten overlooked in discussions about Chinais the sharp increase in <strong>labour</strong> conflicts. <strong>The</strong>re has been a proliferation<strong>of</strong> conventional <strong>and</strong> irregular <strong>labour</strong> activism, frompetitions, <strong>labour</strong> arbitration <strong>and</strong> litigation, through protests,marches <strong>and</strong> road blockages. <strong>The</strong> state has responded withmeasured mixes <strong>of</strong> concession <strong>and</strong> repression. Economic <strong>and</strong>livelihood dem<strong>and</strong>s are recognized <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong>ten partially answeredby swift financial compensation doled out by the central orprovincial government. However political dem<strong>and</strong>s such as forthe removal <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficials <strong>and</strong> cross-factory actions are relentlesslysuppressed <strong>and</strong> harshly punished. <strong>The</strong>re is only one legal unionPAGE 84


C H A P T E R 5 – T H E F E M I N I Z A T I O N A N D I N F O R M A L I Z A T I O N O F L A B O U Rin China, the All China Federation <strong>of</strong> Trade Unions (ACFTU).Independent unions are illegal, <strong>and</strong> attempts at formingautonomous unions have been designated as treason or subversion.However, even where trade unions <strong>and</strong> NGOs are legal<strong>and</strong> tolerated, the organization <strong>of</strong> women workers in the informaleconomy presents formidable challenges.ORGANIZATIONS OFINFORMAL WORKERSOne <strong>of</strong> the promising developments <strong>of</strong> the 1990s was the emergence<strong>of</strong> new forms <strong>of</strong> organizing among women workers in theinformal economy, both domestically <strong>and</strong> internationally. <strong>The</strong>Self Employed Women’s Association (SEWA), in Gujarat, India,with 700,000 members, is one <strong>of</strong> the oldest <strong>and</strong> best-known;many others have emerged over the past decade, some takingSEWA as their model, as did the South African Self-EmployedWomen’s Union (SEWU), formed in 1993. <strong>The</strong>se organizationsinclude street vendors, home-based workers <strong>and</strong> small agriculturalproducers. Other women’s associations—some independently<strong>and</strong> some as part <strong>of</strong> national trade union federations—havefocused on organizing domestic workers; these remain a highlyvulnerable section <strong>of</strong> the female workforce in many countries,both developed <strong>and</strong> developing.Historically, women workers have found it very difficult tovoice their concerns from within male-dominated trade unions.In the 19th <strong>and</strong> early 20th century industrial revolution, tradeunions were hostile to women workers’ presence in the industrialworkforce; they used protective legislation <strong>and</strong> the construct <strong>of</strong>the “family wage” to relegate women to the sphere <strong>of</strong> unpaidwork in the home. 54 <strong>The</strong> picture has changed dramatically downthe years, largely through women’s efforts to reform workplaceprocedures, goals <strong>and</strong> cultures, both from within mainstreamtrade unions <strong>and</strong> by building independent trade unions. However,women’s attempts to secure gender justice <strong>and</strong> paritywithin <strong>labour</strong> organizations are <strong>of</strong>ten resisted or sidelined.Responsiveness to women workers has been equally problematicin the developing world. Even where an explicit commitmentto women workers’ rights has been made, it is rarelyrecognized that women workers may have different prioritiesfrom male workers: childcare support, for example, may be moreimportant to them than a minimum wage. 55 An illustration <strong>of</strong>“gender blindness” comes from an electronics factory in India.Women workers organized to make certain dem<strong>and</strong>s: a companybus so as to avoid sexual harassment on public transport,especially late in the evening <strong>and</strong> uniforms, to reduce the hierarchies<strong>and</strong> problems arising from the fact that women in thisfactory came from different socioeconomic backgrounds. <strong>The</strong>sedem<strong>and</strong>s were agreed by management, but the male workerswere dismissive: “Girls do not know how to raise dem<strong>and</strong>s.<strong>The</strong>y fall into the trap laid by management. <strong>The</strong>y ask for generalfacilities while the real issue is wages … now the girls havea bus, uniforms so they are just happy with that. <strong>The</strong>y don’t askfor wages.” 56<strong>The</strong> attitude <strong>of</strong> Indian trade unions to informal workers ingeneral has been described as “indifference, rising almost toenmity”, underpinned by “fear that pressure from below wouldlead to the gradual erosion <strong>of</strong> the rights gained during a longstruggle by protected <strong>labour</strong>”. 57 Homeworkers have been seen byunions as “outlaws” or “scab <strong>labour</strong>”, undercutting the organizedworkplace. <strong>The</strong>se fears are underst<strong>and</strong>able, especially in economieswhere the formal regulated workforce is no more than10 per cent <strong>of</strong> the total workforce. However, this demonstratesthat the culture <strong>and</strong> procedures <strong>of</strong> the trade union movement,primarily a champion <strong>of</strong> male workers in the formal sector, arebiased towards male preoccupations <strong>and</strong> are out <strong>of</strong> tune withthe lives <strong>of</strong> predominantly informally working women. 58 Notsurprisingly, women have tended to create a “separate space”,either within mainstream trade unions or independently, wheretheir concerns can receive a better hearing.Today, there are many women workers’ organizations <strong>of</strong> differentorigins <strong>and</strong> types. Some are independent organizationsthat have arisen outside the framework <strong>of</strong> the traditional tradeunion movement; others are independent within establishedtrade union structures; yet others are part <strong>of</strong> unions originatingin the formal economy but organizing informal workers. <strong>The</strong>ycover a great variety <strong>of</strong> industrial sectors <strong>and</strong> services, as well asagriculture <strong>and</strong> rural occupations. In some developing countries,however, NGOs have taken up the needs <strong>and</strong> rights <strong>of</strong>PAGE 85


G E N D E R E Q U A L I T Y : S T R I V I N G F O R J U S T I C E I N A N U N E Q U A L W O R L Dwomen workers. Some <strong>of</strong>fer affordable services, such as childcarefacilities, low-cost residences <strong>and</strong> legal support. New kinds<strong>of</strong> <strong>labour</strong> organizations are also emerging that base themselveswithin the community, <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong>fer a much wider range <strong>of</strong> supportservices than do traditional trade unions. 59Many <strong>of</strong> these new trade unions, as well as NGOs <strong>and</strong> community-basedorganizations (CBOs) responding to women workers’rights, face major difficulties in exp<strong>and</strong>ing their reach <strong>and</strong> becomingsustainable. SEWU’s main challenge, for example, remains itspersistent inability to become financially self-sufficient: after10 years, its paid-up membership remains less than 5,000, whilemore than 10,000 members have allowed their membership tolapse by non-payment <strong>of</strong> dues. This is a problem shared by otherunions <strong>of</strong> vulnerable workers in South Africa <strong>and</strong> elsewhere.NGOs have greater flexibility because they are not membership-basedorganizations <strong>and</strong> seldom have a single constituency;but this also raises questions about their accountability, whichis not usually democratic <strong>and</strong> is rarely transparent to their beneficiaries.Both trade unions <strong>and</strong> NGOs face challenges inalliance-building to broaden the scope <strong>and</strong> reach <strong>of</strong> their efforts.While there is wide scope for trade unions <strong>and</strong> NGOs to supporteach others’ aims—<strong>and</strong> there are some exemplary cases <strong>of</strong>collaboration—relations between them have <strong>of</strong>ten sufferedfrom tensions <strong>and</strong> rivalries rooted in ideological <strong>and</strong> organizationaldifferences. 60Despite such caveats these developments are promising.Only through collective action have workers historically regulatedtheir wages <strong>and</strong> working conditions, <strong>and</strong> eliminated theworst forms <strong>of</strong> exploitation; they were responsible, in effect, forthe formalization <strong>of</strong> the workplace. But the stresses <strong>of</strong> the lastcouple <strong>of</strong> decades have other ramifications. Not only have newunion <strong>and</strong> NGO workers’ champions emerged, but the tradeunion movement has itself suffered a major shake-up. Olderorganizations have seen their membership <strong>and</strong> influence decline<strong>and</strong> been forced to adjust to new realities in the world <strong>of</strong> work.<strong>The</strong> General Agricultural Workers’ Union (GAWU) <strong>of</strong>Ghana is a case in point. It exp<strong>and</strong>ed its membership to nonwagedworkers <strong>and</strong> subsistence farmers after structural adjustmentcaused its membership to drop from 130,000 to 30,000. Anotherexample is the Ug<strong>and</strong>a Public Employees Union (UPEU). Inthe 1990s, membership dropped from 108,000 to 700 as a result<strong>of</strong> public sector reforms. <strong>The</strong> union then transformed its outlook<strong>and</strong> scope: it revised the concept <strong>of</strong> “public employee” from thenarrow meaning <strong>of</strong> “civil servant” to a much broader concept<strong>of</strong> engagement in serving the public, including such groups asstreet vendors. As a result <strong>of</strong> this change <strong>and</strong> an organizationaldrive, its membership grew to 17,000 by 1999. 61International campaigns <strong>and</strong> alliancesIn recent years the issue <strong>of</strong> <strong>labour</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ards has become divisivein view <strong>of</strong> proposals being made for its enforcement throughinternational trade agreements <strong>and</strong> trade sanctions. <strong>The</strong>re are,underst<strong>and</strong>ably, concerns among Southern governments <strong>and</strong>civil-society groups about protectionist motives lurking behindsuch proposals. More to the point, it is not just the traded sectorsthat require <strong>labour</strong>-market regulation.While transnational alliances between trade unions <strong>and</strong>NGOs have been effective in campaigning for workers’ rights,these campaigns have been limited to workers in traded goods visibleto Northern consumers. <strong>The</strong> direct benefits are <strong>of</strong>ten limitedto workers with jobs dependent on multinational companies<strong>and</strong> their subcontractors, who are <strong>of</strong>ten among the more privileged<strong>and</strong> best-paid members <strong>of</strong> the workforce. 62 Where a muchlarger proportion <strong>of</strong> the workforce operates in the informaleconomy in far worse conditions, they are beyond the reach <strong>of</strong> suchcampaigns. However, the different segments <strong>of</strong> the workforcedo not necessarily live in isolation from each other. Successfulcampaigns <strong>and</strong> organizations affecting one segment are likelyto have ripple effects on power relations elsewhere. <strong>The</strong> femaleworking class is less segmented than sometimes appears, <strong>and</strong>changes in one part are likely to have implications in others.For women with virtually no assets <strong>and</strong> who work in the informaleconomy, collective action through democratic organizationalroutes presents the only practicable avenue for regulatingor improving their working conditions. <strong>The</strong> idea that the formalization<strong>of</strong> property rights constitutes the solution to theproblems <strong>of</strong> the informal economy is a complete misconceptionas far as working women are concerned (see box 5.7).PAGE 86


C H A P T E R 5 – T H E F E M I N I Z A T I O N A N D I N F O R M A L I Z A T I O N O F L A B O U RBox 5.7“Property rights” are no panacea for the informal economy<strong>The</strong> influential work <strong>of</strong> Hern<strong>and</strong>o de Soto has paved the way for a particular policy perspective on the informal economy. 63According to de Soto the transition <strong>of</strong> informal into formal work is constrained by a deficient framework <strong>of</strong> property rights.Allegedly, lack <strong>of</strong> legal recognition for some forms <strong>of</strong> property constrains access to institutional sources <strong>of</strong> credit. A similarperspective informed the World Commission on the Social Dimensions <strong>of</strong> Globalization. Its report sees the legalization <strong>of</strong> defacto property rights as:a vital step in the transformation <strong>of</strong> the informal economy. To achieve this, governments need to:identify the people <strong>and</strong> assets concerned; identify the practices <strong>and</strong> customs which govern the ownership,use <strong>and</strong> transfer <strong>of</strong> these assets, so as to root property law in the prevailing social context;<strong>and</strong> identify administrative, bureaucratic <strong>and</strong> legal bottlenecks <strong>and</strong> obstacles to market access. 64<strong>The</strong> axiomatic underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> such a position is that the informal economy is inherently vibrant, flexible <strong>and</strong> dynamic,<strong>and</strong> that it can effectively compete with larger units in the formal sector once constraints—such as lack <strong>of</strong> access to credit—are removed. This ignores a number <strong>of</strong> the informal economy’s key features, <strong>and</strong> the problems faced by its many <strong>and</strong> variedpractitioners.<strong>The</strong> size <strong>of</strong> its units—typically individuals <strong>and</strong> households—is critical in many ways. For example, market access is fundamentallydependent not on legal status, but on output. Larger size allows organizational economies <strong>of</strong> scale. Increasedaccess to markets by small units usually requires some degree <strong>of</strong> co-operation between them; alternatively, they might makearrangements with a larger unit or obtain public intervention through marketing bodies. As for credit, access is typicallymore difficult for all small units, even in the formal sector, not only because <strong>of</strong> the lack <strong>of</strong> collateral <strong>and</strong> high administrativecosts, but because they are perceived to be inherently more risk-prone.Looking at the issue <strong>of</strong> property rights itself, there are problems <strong>and</strong> risks associated with the establishment <strong>of</strong> rights,such as regulated tenure <strong>and</strong> ownership <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong>. <strong>The</strong> evidence from sub-Saharan Africa shows that the customary rights <strong>of</strong>women, <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> other marginal groups, are <strong>of</strong>ten lost in the process <strong>of</strong> titling <strong>and</strong> registration. A large number <strong>of</strong> workers inthe informal economy anyway have no “property” to be registered; they are engaged in informal activities only becausethey cannot find work in the formal sector. Most women workers are in this category.Finally, <strong>and</strong> perhaps most crucially, it is a mistake to assume that all informal activity is effectively self-employment <strong>and</strong>that employer–worker relationships do not exist. As already demonstrated, a main attraction <strong>of</strong> the informal economy foremployers is precisely the absence <strong>of</strong> <strong>labour</strong> regulation, allowing lower <strong>labour</strong> costs <strong>and</strong> greater exploitation <strong>of</strong> workers.Increasingly, formal sector organizations depend on units <strong>of</strong> the informal sector to undertake production by means <strong>of</strong> subcontracting;the line between the two sectors has thus become much harder to draw. This means that the most basic differencebetween formal <strong>and</strong> informal parts <strong>of</strong> the economy is not the access to credit or markets, but the absence <strong>of</strong> regulation<strong>and</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> protection for workers in the informal economy, as well as the latter’s lack <strong>of</strong> voice <strong>and</strong> political influence.Source: Ghosh 2004b.PAGE 87


G E N D E R E Q U A L I T Y : S T R I V I N G F O R J U S T I C E I N A N U N E Q U A L W O R L DNotes1 Figure 5.1 includes countries in the MENA region for which data wereavailable. Because <strong>of</strong> certain shared characteristics, including culture,religion, history, <strong>and</strong> the prevalence <strong>of</strong> oil economies, the MENA regionis considered an appropriate site for regional analysis, not only by internationalorganizations such as the World Bank but also by scholarlyorganizations such as the Middle East Studies Association.2 Elson 1999.3 Anker et al. 2003; Anker 1998.4 Kabeer 1995.5 Elson 1999; Folbre 1994.6 ILO 2002b.7 St<strong>and</strong>ing 1999.8 Pearson 2004.9 Ghosh 2003a.10 Ghosh 2003a.11 UN 1999.12 Ghosh 2003a.13 This section draws heavily on Orl<strong>of</strong>f 2002.14 Orl<strong>of</strong>f 2002.15 Hochschild 1989.16 ILO 2002b.17 ILO 2002b:27.18 Lewis <strong>and</strong> Giullari 2004.19 Einhorn 1993.20 Eisenstein 1993.21 Fodor 2004b.22 Heinen <strong>and</strong> Portet 2002.23 Pearson 2004.24 Karshenas 2001 cited in Moghadam 2004.25 Moghadam 2004.26 Harriss-White 2000.27 ILO 2002b.28 ILO 2002b.29 Elson 1999.30 Elson 1999.31 Pape 2000 cited in Tsikata 2004.32 Breman 1996.33 Jackson <strong>and</strong> Rao 2004.34 Kabeer <strong>and</strong> Mahmud 2004.35 Roy 2003.36 Kabeer <strong>and</strong> Mahmud 2004:tables 7 <strong>and</strong> 8.37 Kabeer <strong>and</strong> Mahmud 2004.38 Kabeer 2004.39 Rogerson 1997 cited in Tsikata 2004.40 Tsikata 2004; Hart 2004.41 Davis 2004:22 cited in Tsikata 2004.42 Tokam 2002.43 Beneria <strong>and</strong> Floro 2004.44 Deedat 2003; see also Hart 2004.45 Lund et al. 2000.46 Chen et al. 1999.47 Bangura 1994, 2000.48 Agbaw 2000, cited in Tsikata 2004.49 Chang 1995; China Employment Report 2002 cited in Lee 2004.50 Institute for Labour Studies <strong>of</strong> the Ministry <strong>of</strong> Labour <strong>and</strong> SocialSecurity <strong>of</strong> China 2002, cited in Lee 2004.51 Huang <strong>and</strong> Wuanming 2003, cited in Lee 2004.52 Tsui 2002, cited in Lee 2004.53 Cook <strong>and</strong> Jolly 2001.54 Hartman 1979; Gallin <strong>and</strong> Horn 2004.55 Chhachhi <strong>and</strong> Pittin 1996; Rowbotham <strong>and</strong> Mitter 1994.56 Chhachhi <strong>and</strong> Pittin 1996:115–16.57 Breman 1996:247.58 Mitter 1994.59 Kabeer 2004.60 Eade 2004.61 Gallin 2004.62 Anner <strong>and</strong> Evans 2004; UNRISD 2004.63 De Soto 2000.64 ILO 2004e: 61.PAGE 88

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!